Questions for Review 1. In this chapter we looked at two models of the short-run aggregate supply curve. Both models attempt to explain why, in the short run, output might deviate from its long-run “natural rate”—the level of output that is consistent with the full employment of labor and capital. Both models result in an aggregate supply function in which output deviates from its natural rate Y when the price level deviates from the expected price level: Y = Y + α(P – EP). The first model is the sticky-price model. The market imperfection in this model is that prices in the goods market do not adjust immediately to changes in demand conditions—the goods market does not clear instantaneously. If the demand for a firm’s goods falls, some respond by reducing output, not prices. The second model is the imperfect-information model. This model assumes that there is imperfect information about prices, in that some suppliers of goods confuse changes in the price level with changes in relative prices. If a producer observes the nominal price of the firm’s good rising, the producer attributes some of the rise to an increase in relative price, even if it is purely a general price increase. As a result, the producer increases production. In both models, there is a discrepancy between what is really happening and what firms think is happening. In the sticky-price model, some firms expect prices to be at one level and they end up at another level. In the imperfectinformation model, some firms expect the relative price of their output has changed when it really has not. 2. In this chapter, we argued that in the short run, the supply of output depends on the natural rate of output and on the difference between the price level and the expected price level. This relationship is expressed in the aggregate-supply equation: Y = Y + α(P – EP). The Phillips curve is an alternative way to express aggregate supply. It provides a simple way to express the tradeoff between inflation and unemployment implied by the short-run aggregate supply curve. The Phillips curve posits that inflation π depends on the expected inflation rate Eπ, on cyclical unemployment u – un , and on supply shocks v: π = Eπ – β(u – un ) + v. Both equations tell us the same information in a different way: both imply a connection between real economic activity and unexpected changes in prices. In addition, both the Phillips curve and the short-run aggregate supply curve show that inflation and unemployment move in opposite directions. 3. Inflation is inertial because of the way people form expectations. It is plausible to assume that people’s expectations of inflation depend on recently observed inflation. These expectations then influence the wages and prices that people set. For example, if prices have been rising quickly, people will expect them to continue to rise quickly. These expectations will be built into the contracts people set, so that actual wages and prices will rise quickly. In addition, both the Phillips curve and the short-run aggregate supply curve show that inflation and unemployment move in opposite directions. 144 C H A P T E R 13 Aggregate Supply and the Short-Run Tradeoff Between Inflation and Unemployment Chapter 13 Aggregate Supply 145 4. Demand-pull inflation results from high aggregate demand: the increase in demand “pulls” prices and output up. Cost-push inflation comes from adverse supply shocks that push up the cost of production—for example, the increases in oil prices in the midand late-1970s. The Phillips curve tells us that inflation depends on expected inflation, the difference between unemployment and its natural rate, and a shock v: π = Eπ – β(u – un ) + v. The term “ – β(u – un )” is the demand-pull inflation, since if unemployment is below its natural rate (u < un ), inflation rises. The supply shock v is the cost-push inflation. 5. The Phillips curve relates the inflation rate to the expected inflation rate and to the difference between unemployment and its natural rate. So one way to reduce inflation is to have a recession, raising unemployment above its natural rate. It is possible to bring inflation down without a recession, however, if we can costlessly reduce expected inflation. According to the rational-expectations approach, people optimally use all of the information available to them in forming their expectations. So to reduce expected inflation, we require, first, that the plan to reduce inflation be announced before people form expectations (e.g., before they form wage agreements and price contracts); and second, that those setting wages and prices believe that the announced plan will be carried out. If both requirements are met, then expected inflation will fall immediately and without cost, and this in turn will bring down actual inflation. 6. One way in which a recession might raise the natural rate of unemployment is by affecting the process of job search, increasing the amount of frictional unemployment. For example, workers who are unemployed lose valuable job skills. This reduces their ability to find jobs after the recession ends because they are less desirable to firms. Also, after a long period of unemployment, individuals may lose some of their desire to work, and hence search less hard. Second, a recession may affect the process that determines wages, increasing wait unemployment. Wage negotiations may give a greater voice to “insiders,” those who actually have jobs. Those who become unemployed become “outsiders.” If the smaller group of insiders cares more about high real wages and less about high employment, then the recession may permanently push real wages above the equilibrium level and raise the amount of wait unemployment. This permanent impact of a recession on the natural rate of unemployment is called hysteresis. Problems and Applications 1. In this question, we examine two special cases of the sticky-price model developed in this chapter. In the sticky-price model, all firms have a desired price p that depends on the overall level of prices P as well as the level of aggregate demand Y – Y. We wrote this as p = P + a(Y – Y). There are two types of firms. A proportion (1 – s) of the firms have flexible prices and set prices using the above equation. The remaining proportion s of the firms have sticky prices—they announce their prices in advance based on the economic conditions that they expect in the future. We assume that these firms expect output to be at its natural rate, so (EY – Y) = 0. Hence, these firms set their prices equal to the expected price level: p = EP. The overall price level is a weighted average of the prices set by the two types of firms: P = sEP + (1 – s)[P + a(Y – Y)]. Rearranging: P = EP + [a(1 – s)/s](Y – Y). a. If no firms have flexible prices, then s = 1. The above equation tells us that P = EP. That is, the aggregate price level is fixed at the expected price level: the aggregate supply curve is horizontal in the short run, as assumed in Chapter 9. b. If desired relative prices do not depend at all on the level of output, then a = 0 in the equation for the price level. Once again, we find P = EP: the aggregate supply curve is horizontal in the short run, as assumed in Chapter 9. 2. The economy has the Phillips curve: π = π–1 –0.5(u – 0.06). a. The natural rate of unemployment is the rate at which the inflation rate does not deviate from the expected inflation rate. Here, the expected inflation rate is just last period’s actual inflation rate. Setting the inflation rate equal to last period’s inflation rate, that is, π = π–1, we find that u = 0.06. Thus, the natural rate of unemployment is 6 percent. b. In the short run (that is, in a single period) the expected inflation rate is fixed at the level of inflation in the previous period, π–1. Hence, the short-run relationship between inflation and unemployment is just the graph of the Phillips curve: it has a slope of –0.5, and it passes through the point where π = π–1 and u = 0.06. This is shown in Figure 13–1. In the long run, expected inflation equals actual inflation, so that π = π–1, and output and unemployment equal their natural rates. The longrun Phillips curve thus is vertical at an unemployment rate of 6 percent. 146 Answers to Textbook Questions and Problems LRPC SRPC u0.06 Unemployment π Inflation 0.5 π−1 π Figure 13–1 c. To reduce inflation, the Phillips curve tells us that unemployment must be above its natural rate of 6 percent for some period of time. We can write the Phillips curve in the form π – π–1 = 0.5(u – 0.06). Since we want inflation to fall by 5 percentage points, we want π – π–1 = –0.05. Plugging this into the left-hand side of the above equation, we find –0.05 = –0.5(u – 0.06). We can now solve this for u: u = 0.16. Hence, we need 10 percentage points of cyclical unemployment above the natural rate of 6 percent. Okun’s law says that a change of 1 percentage point in unemployment translates into a change of 2 percentage points in GDP. Hence, an increase in unemployment of 10 percentage points corresponds to a fall in output of 20 percentage points. The sacrifice ratio is the percentage of a year’s GDP that must be forgone to reduce inflation by 1 percentage point. Dividing the 20 percentage-point decrease in GDP by the 5 percentage-point decrease in inflation, we find that the sacrifice ratio is 20/5 = 4. d. One scenario is to have very high unemployment for a short period of time. For example, we could have 16 percent unemployment for a single year. Alternatively, we could have a small amount of cyclical unemployment spread out over a long period of time. For example, we could have 8 percent unemployment for 5 years. Both of these plans would bring the inflation rate down from 10 percent to 5 percent, although at different speeds. 3. The cost of reducing inflation comes from the cost of changing people’s expectations about inflation. If expectations can be changed costlessly, then reducing inflation is also costless. Algebraically, the Phillips curve tells us that π = Eπ – β(u – un ) + v. If the government can lower expected inflation Eπ to the desired level of inflation, then there is no need for unemployment to rise above its natural rate. According to the rational-expectations approach, people form expectations about inflation using all of the information that is available to them. This includes information about current policies in effect. If everyone believes that the government is committed to reducing inflation, then expected inflation will immediately fall. In terms of the Phillips curve, Eπ falls immediately with little or no cost to the economy. That is, the sacrifice ratio will be very small. On the other hand, if people do not believe that the government will carry out its intentions, then Eπ remains high. Expectations will not adjust because people are skeptical that the government will follow through on its plans. Thus, according to the rational-expectations approach, the cost of reducing inflation depends on how resolute and credible the government is. An important issue is how the government can make its commitment to reducing inflation more credible. One possibility, for example, is to appoint people who have a reputation as inflation fighters. A second possibility is to have Congress pass a law requiring the Federal Reserve to lower inflation. Of course, people might expect the Fed to ignore this law, or expect Congress to change the law later. A third possibility is to pass a constitutional amendment limiting monetary growth. People might rationally believe that a constitutional amendment is relatively difficult to change. Chapter 13 Aggregate Supply 147 148 Answers to Textbook Questions and Problems 4. a. Beginning in long-run equilibrium, where output is at the natural level, if the Federal Reserve increases the money supply, this will cause the economy to go through an expansionary phase. Starting with the IS-LM model in Figure 13-2A, an increase in the money supply will shift the LM curve to the right, resulting in a lower interest rate and higher level of output at point B. In the long run, the price level will rise, real-money balances will decline, and the LM curve will shift back to its original position. There is no long-run change in the real interest rate or the level of output. Moving to the AD-AS model in Figure 13-2B, an increase in the money supply will shift the AD curve to the right, resulting in a higher level of output and a higher price level at point B. In the long run, expected inflation will rise, shifting the SRAS curve upward. The economy ends up at point C with output back at its natural level and the price level at a higher level. Moving to the Phillips curve graph in Figure 13-2C, the economy starts at point A, where unemployment is at the natural rate. The increase in the money supply pushes output above its natural level, and as a result, the unemployment rate falls below its natural level. This causes a movement along the short-run Phillips curve to point B, where inflation is higher and unemployment is lower. In the long run, expected inflation will rise, causing the Phillips curve to shift upward. The economy ends up at point C with higher inflation and no change in the unemployment rate. The economy moves through this expansionary cycle because the increase in the money supply does not immediately cause expected inflation to rise. Chapter 13 Aggregate Supply 149 IS Y A = C r A. IS–LM Model Realinterestrate Y Y1 B Output, income LM1 = LM3 LM2 AD1 Y A P B. AD–AS Model Pricelevel Y Y1 B Output, income SRAS2 r r1 LRAS SRAS1 AD2 P2 P1 C SRPC1 U A π C. Phillips Curve Inflationrate UC B Unemployment rate LRPC SRPC2 π1 C Ur π2 π3 Figure 13–2 b. Beginning in long-run equilibrium with output at its natural level, if the Federal Reserve increases the money supply and people immediately expect inflation to rise, then nothing changes except for the price level and the inflation rate. In the IS-LM model, the increase in the money supply will cause the price level to rise at the same rate as the money supply such that there is no change in real balances. The economy stays at point A, as illustrated in Figure 13-3A. Moving to the ADAS model, the increase in the money supply shifts the AD curve to the right, but at the same time, the increase in expected inflation shifts the SRAS curve up and to the left. The economy remains at the natural level of output and the price level is higher, as illustrated in Figure 13-3B. Moving to the Phillips curve, the immediate increase in expected inflation shifts the short-run Phillips curve upward, causing the inflation rate to rise with no change in the unemployment rate, as illustrated in Figure 13-3C. When the money supply increases and the public immediately expects higher inflation, the economy does not move through an expansionary cycle. 150 Answers to Textbook Questions and Problems Chapter 13 Aggregate Supply 151 IS Y A r Realinterestrate Y Output, income LM r SRPC1 U A π Inflationrate B Unemployment rate LRPC SRPC2 π1 Ur π2 IS Y A P Pricelevel Y Output, income LRAS P1 P2 B SRAS2 SRAS1 A. IS–LM Model B. AD–AS Model C. Phillips Curve Figure 13–3 5. In this question we consider several implications of rational expectations—the assumption that people optimally use all of the information available to them in forming their expectations—for the model of sticky prices that we considered in this chapter. This model implies an aggregate supply curve in which output varies from its natural rate only if the price level varies from its expected level: Y = Y + α(P – EP). Based on this model, monetary policy can affect real GDP only by affecting (P – EP)— that is, causing an unexpected change in the price level. a. Only unanticipated changes in the money supply can affect real GDP. Since people take into account all of the information available to them, they already take into account the effects of anticipated changes in money when they form their expectations of the price level EP. For example, if people expect the money supply to increase by 10 percent and it actually does increase by 10 percent, then there is no effect on output since there is no price surprise—(P – EP) = 0. On the other hand, suppose the Fed increases the money supply more than expected, so that prices increase by 15 percent when people expect them to increase by only 10 percent. Since P > EP, output rises. But it is only the unanticipated part of money growth that increases output. b. The Fed often tries to stabilize the economy by offsetting shocks to output and unemployment. For example, it might increase the money supply during recessions in an attempt to stimulate the economy, and it might reduce the money supply during booms in an attempt to slow it down. The Fed can only do this by surprising people about the price level: during a recession, they want prices to be higher than expected, and during booms, they want prices to be lower than expected. If people have rational expectations, however, they will expect the Fed to respond this way. So if the economy is in a boom, people expect the Fed to reduce the money supply; in a recession, people expect the Fed to increase the money supply. In either case, it is impossible for the Fed to cause (P – EP) to vary systematically from zero. Since people take into account the systematic, anticipated movements in money, the effect on output of systematic, active policy is exactly the same as a policy of keeping the money supply constant, assuming the Fed chooses the level of the money supply at the same time people set prices so everyone has the same information. c. If the Fed sets the money supply after people set wages and prices, then the Fed can use monetary policy systematically to stabilize output. The assumption of rational expectations means that people use all of the information available to them in forming expectations about the price level. This includes information about the state of the economy and information about how the Fed will respond to this state. This does not mean that people know what the state of the economy will be, nor do they know exactly how the Fed will act: they simply make their best guess. As time passes, the Fed learns information about the economy that was unknown to those setting wages and prices. At this point, since contracts have already set these wages and prices, people are stuck with their expectations EP. The Fed can then use monetary policy to affect the actual price level P, and hence can affect output systematically. 6. In this model, the natural rate of unemployment is an average of the unemployment rates in the past two years. Hence, if a recession raises the unemployment rate in some year, then the natural rate of unemployment rises as well. This means that the model exhibits hysteresis: short-term cyclical unemployment affects the long-term natural rate of unemployment. a. The natural rate of unemployment might depend on recent unemployment for at least two reasons, suggested by the theory of hysteresis. First, recent unemployment rates might affect the level of frictional unemployment. Unemployed work- 152 Answers to Textbook Questions and Problems ers lose job skills and find it harder to get jobs; also, unemployed workers might lose some of their desire to work, and hence search less hard for a job. Second, recent unemployment rates might affect the level of structural unemployment. If labor negotiations give a greater voice to “insiders” than “outsiders,” then the insiders might push for high wages at the expense of jobs. This will be especially true in industries in which negotiations take place between firms and unions. b. If the Fed seeks to reduce inflation permanently by 1 percentage point, then the Phillips curve tells us that in the first period we require π1 – π0 = –1 = –0.5(u1 – un 1), or (u1 – un 1) = 2. That is, we require an unemployment rate 2 percentage points above the original natural rate u . Next period, however, the natural rate will rise as a result of the cyclical unemployment. The new natural rate u will be u = 0.5[u1 + u0] = 0.5[(un 1 + 2) + un 1] = un 1 + 1. Hence, the natural rate of unemployment rises by 1 percentage point. If the Fed wants to keep inflation at its new level, then unemployment in period 2 must equal the new natural rate u . Hence, u2 = un 1 + 1. In every subsequent period, it remains true that the unemployment rate must equal the natural rate. This natural rate never returns to its original level: we can show this by deriving the sequence of unemployment rates: u3 = (1/2)u2 + (1/2)u1 = u + 1.5 u4 = (1/2)u3 + (1/2)u2 = u + 1.25 u5 = (1/2)u4 + (1/2)u3 = u + 1.375. Unemployment always remains above its original natural rate. In fact, we can show that it is always at least 1 percent above its original natural rate. Thus, to reduce inflation by 1 percentage point, unemployment rises above its original level by 2 percentage points in the first year, and by 1 or more percentage points in every year after that. c. Because unemployment is always higher than it started, output is always lower than it would have been. Hence, the sacrifice ratio is infinite. d. Without hysteresis, we found that there was a short-run tradeoff but no long-run tradeoff between inflation and unemployment. With hysteresis, we find that there is a long-run tradeoff between inflation and unemployment: to reduce inflation, unemployment must rise permanently. 7. a. The natural level of output is determined by the production function, Y = F(K, L). If a tax cut raises work effort, it increases L and, thus, increases the natural rate of output. b. The tax cut shifts the aggregate demand curve outward for the normal reason that disposable income and, hence, consumption rise. It shifts the long-run aggregate supply curve outward because the natural rate of output rises. The effect of the tax cut on the short-run aggregate supply (SRAS) curve depends on which model you use. The labor supply curve shifts outward because workers are willing to supply more labor at any given real wage while the labor demand curve is unchanged. In the sticky-price model the quantity of labor is demand-determined, so the SRAS curve does not move. By contrast, the imperChapter 13 Aggregate Supply 153 fect-information model assumes that the labor market is always in equilibrium, so the greater supply of labor leads to higher employment immediately: the SRAS shifts out. c. If you are using the sticky-price model, the short-run analysis is the same as the conventional model without the labor-supply effect. That is, output and prices both rise because aggregate demand rises while short-run aggregate supply is unchanged. If you use the imperfect-information model, short-run aggregate supply shifts outward, so that the tax cut is more expansionary and less inflationary than the conventional model. Figure 13–4 shows the effects in both models. Point A is the original equilibrium, point SW is the new equilibrium in the sticky-price model, and point II is the new equilibrium in the imperfect-information model. d. In the normal model, where the tax cut does not lead to a shift of labor supply that increases the natural level of output, the long-run price level will be higher as a result of the tax cut and output will return to the same natural level. The tax cut led to a rightward shift of the aggregate demand curve in the short run. In the long run, the short-run aggregate supply curve will shift up and to the left as the expected price level rises. In the alternative model, where the tax cut leads to an increase in the natural level of output, the long-run results depend on whether the horizontal shift in the aggregate demand curve is larger, smaller, or the same as the horizontal shift in the long-run aggregate supply curve. If the two shift horizontally by the same amount, then the price level is unaffected in the long run. If the shift in aggregate demand is greater than the shift in the long-run aggregate supply curve, then the price level will be higher in the long run. 8. In this quote, Alan Blinder argues that in low-inflation countries like the United States, the benefits of reducing inflation are small whereas the costs are large. That is, menu costs, shoeleather costs, and tax distortions simply do not add up to much, so eliminating inflation offers only small benefits. By contrast, the costs in terms of unemployment and lost output that are associated with lowering inflation are easily quantifiable and very large. The basic policy implication of these beliefs about the relative benefits and costs of reducing inflation is that policymakers should not tighten policy in order to lower inflation rates that are already relatively low. The statement leaves two other issues ambiguous. First, should policymakers concern themselves with rising inflation? Second, should policymakers concern themselves with making inflation more predictable around the level it has inherited? Blinder may feel that these issues should have little weight relative to output stabilization. 154 Answers to Textbook Questions and Problems LRAS1 LRAS2 SRAS1 SRASImp. Info AD2 AD1 Y A SW II P , SRASSP Figure 13–4 9. From the BLS web site (www.bls.gov), there are various ways to get the CPI data. For the years 2004–2008, I obtained the following for “all urban consumers”: Year 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 Overall CPI 3.8 2.8 3.2 3.4 2.7 CPI excluding food and energy 2.3 2.3 2.5 2.2 1.8 The overall CPI was clearly more volatile than the CPI excluding food and energy. The difference reflects shocks to the price of food and energy—especially energy prices, which are highly variable. When energy prices, say, go down, the total CPI will rise less than the CPI excluding food and energy. This represents a supply shock, which shifts the aggregate supply curve and Phillips curve downward. More Problems and Applications to Chapter 13 1. a. The classical large open economy model (from the Appendix to Chapter 5) is similar to special case 2 in the text, except that it allows the interest rate to deviate from the world interest rate. That is, this is the special case where EP = P, L(i,Y) = (1/V)Y, and CF = CF(r-r*), with a non-infinitely elastic international capital flow. Because capital flows do not respond overwhelmingly to any differences between the domestic and world interest rates, these rates can, in fact, vary in this case. b. The Keynesian cross model of Chapter 10 is the special case where (i) the economy is closed, so that CF(r-r*) = 0 ; (ii) I(r) = I, so that investment is given exogenously; and (iii) α is infinite, so that the short-run aggregate-supply curve is horizontal. In this special case, output depends solely on the demand for goods and services. c. The IS-LM model for the large open economy (from the appendix to Chapter 12) is the special case where α is infinite and CF = CF(r-r*) is not infinitely elastic. In this case, the short-run aggregate supply curve is horizontal, and capital flows do not respond too much to differences between the domestic and world interest rates. Chapter 13 Aggregate Supply 155