Working Paper No. 432 An estimated DSGE model of energy, costs and inflation in the United Kingdom Stephen Millard July 2011 Working Paper No. 432 An estimated DSGE model of energy, costs and inflation in the United Kingdom Stephen Millard(1) Abstract In this paper, I estimate a dynamic stochastic general equilibrium (DSGE) model of the United Kingdom. The basic building blocks of the model are standard in the literature. The main complication is that there are three consumption goods: non-energy output, petrol and utilities; given relative prices and their overall wealth, consumers choose how much of each of these goods to consume in order to maximise their utility. Each of the consumption goods is produced according to a sector-specific production function and sticky prices in each sector imply sector-specific New Keynesian Phillips Curves. I show how this model, once estimated, could form a useful additional input within a policymaker’s ‘suite of models’ by considering its implications for the responses of various macroeconomic variables to different economic shocks and by decomposing recent movements of energy and non-energy output and inflation into the proportions caused by each of the shocks. Key words: Dynamic stochastic general equilibrium model, energy prices and inflation. JEL classification: E13, E31. (1) Bank of England. Email: stephen.millard@bankofengland.co.uk The views expressed in this paper are those of the author, and not necessarily those of the Bank of England. I am grateful to Maria Barriel and Ryland Thomas for putting together the data set used to estimate the model and for helpful discussions about the model itself. I am also grateful to Neal Hatch, Simon Price and seminar participants at the Bank of England for useful comments. This paper was finalised on 25 March 2011. The Bank of England’s working paper series is externally refereed. Information on the Bank’s working paper series can be found at www.bankofengland.co.uk/publications/workingpapers/index.htm Publications Group, Bank of England, Threadneedle Street, London, EC2R 8AH Telephone +44 (0)20 7601 4030 Fax +44 (0)20 7601 3298 email mapublications@bankofengland.co.uk © Bank of England 2011 ISSN 1749-9135 (on-line) Working Paper No. 432 July 2011 2 Contents Summary 3 1 Introduction 5 2 The model 6 2.1 Households 7 2.2 Non energy producing firms 9 2.3 Value-added sector 10 2.4 Petrol producers 10 2.5 Utilities producers 11 2.6 Monetary and fiscal policy 12 2.7 Foreign sector 12 2.8 Market clearing 13 2.9 Shock processes 13 3 Estimation 14 3.1 Data 14 3.2 Priors 15 3.3 Estimation results 17 3.4 Effects of including/excluding energy 21 4 Impulse response functions 22 4.1 How does energy affect the responses of variables to shocks? 23 4.2 The effects of a rise in energy prices 31 5 Using the model to decompose movements in output and inflation 33 6 Conclusions 38 References 39 Working Paper No. 432 July 2011 3 Summary The job of monetary policy makers is to set monetary policy so as to achieve their goal of low and stable inflation. In order to carry this out, it is important to understand what drives inflation and how changes in monetary policy feed through the economy into inflation. But no single model can capture all aspects of reality. This is why many central banks have used, and continue to use, a variety of macroeconomic models to help in their understanding of inflation. The main purpose of this paper is to estimate a model of the United Kingdom that, unusually, includes an energy sector. It could in principle be used as another input within a policymaker’s ‘suite of models’. The standard model of inflation suggests that it is driven by lagged and future expected inflation and movements in costs. One important cost for most producers is the cost of energy. So, inflation will be affected by movements in energy prices. In addition, to the extent that consumers use energy themselves, movements in energy prices will have a direct, and immediate, effect on consumer price inflation, which is not necessarily captured by standard models. The novelty of this paper, relative to previous work, is that the model takes seriously the effects of movements in energy and other costs on inflation. The goal is to produce a macroeconomic model that can be used to analyse quantitatively the effects on inflation of many temporary shocks, including but not limited to energy prices as well as how monetary policy can respond to such shocks. Furthermore, estimating the model enables us to evaluate how these shocks have evolved over time and the implications of this for explaining movements in output and inflation. The basic building blocks of the model are standard. The main complication is that there are three consumption goods: non-energy output, petrol and utilities (which can be thought of as a combination of gas and electricity). Each of these consumption goods is produced using different combinations of five inputs: labour, capital, imported (non-energy) intermediates, oil and gas. The prices set by the producers of these goods are sticky. Demand for oil and gas over and above what we produce has to be met from abroad. The central bank affects aggregate demand via movements in interest rates. How this level of aggregate demand translates into demand for each of the goods is determined by consumers’ preferences and relative prices. Finally, the model adds a government that ‘eats up’ some of the non-energy good and levies taxes as well as a specific duty on petrol. The estimates suggest, not surprisingly, that petrol prices are highly flexible, utility prices are quite flexible, while non-energy prices, on the other hand, are very sticky. The relative stickiness of prices in the three sectors are in line with survey and other evidence for the United Kingdom. In terms of the shocks, the estimates suggest that the productivity shock is fairly persistent but the others much less so; the model is able to explain persistence in the data without having to resort to extremely persistent shocks. The estimated standard deviation of monetary policy shocks is very low, not altogether surprising given that the model was estimated over the inflation-targeting period. But, the domestic demand and investment-specific technology shocks are highly volatile over this period. Finally, the estimates suggest that the Working Paper No. 432 July 2011 4 model including energy prices is better able to explain UK macroeconomic data than an otherwise identical model that does not include energy prices. Given these estimates, it is possible for the model’s user to apply the model quantitatively to UK policy issues. The paper has shown how this could be done by examining the effects of many different shocks on inflation and by decomposing recent movements in output and inflation into those parts caused by each of the model’s structural shocks. It found that the fall in gross nonenergy output from 2008 Q2 to 2009 Q3 was driven by three shocks: to productivity, to world demand and to the domestic risk premium, proxying the effects of the recent financial crisis. The risk premium shock also put downwards pressure on inflation during this period while the productivity shock was putting upwards pressure on inflation. The world demand shock, by contrast, was much less important in explaining the behaviour of inflation over this period. Working Paper No. 432 July 2011 5 1 Introduction The job of monetary policy makers is to set monetary policy – by which I typically mean interest rates, though currently many central banks are operating directly on bank reserves through quantitative easing – so as to achieve their goal of low and stable inflation. But in order to carry out this job, it is important to understand what drives inflation and how changes in monetary policy feed through the economy into inflation. This is why many central banks have used, and continue to use, a variety of macroeconomic models to help in their understanding of inflation. The main purpose of this paper is to estimate a dynamic stochastic general equilibrium (DSGE) model of the United Kingdom that could be used as another input within a policymakers ‘suite of models’. Previous authors have estimated DSGE models for the United Kingdom, eg, Di Cecio and Nelson (2007), Harrison and Oomen (2010), Kamber and Millard (2010) and Faccini et al (2011). The standard model of inflation – as embodied in the models estimated by all of these authors – is based around the ‘New Keynesian Phillips Curve’ (NKPC), which suggests that inflation is driven by lagged and future expected inflation and real marginal cost. Typically in these models, real marginal cost will be equivalent to real unit labour costs (the ‘labour share’), although, as shown by Faccini et al and Kamber and Millard, this is not the case in models where hiring and firing costs are important and real marginal cost has to be amended accordingly. But importantly for this paper, when labour and energy are complementary inputs to production, real marginal cost will also be affected by movements in energy prices. Hence, given NKPC theory, movements in energy prices will be important for inflation. In addition, to the extent that consumers use energy themselves, movements in energy prices will have a direct effect on consumer price inflation, which is not necessarily captured by the NKPC. This effect was clearly seen recently in the United Kingdom as the rise in oil prices from $75 a barrel in 2007 Q3 to $121 a barrel in 2008 Q2 was associated with a rise in CPI inflation from 1.8% in 2007 Q3 to 4.8% in 2008 Q3. So, the novelty of this paper, relative to those of Di Cecio and Nelson (2007), Harrison and Oomen (2010), Kamber and Millard (2010) and Faccini et al (2011) is that the goal is to estimate a model that takes seriously the effects of movements in all the elements within firms’ costs – labour, capital, imported intermediates and energy – on inflation, and that can be used to analyse how a central bank should respond to movements in energy prices in order to achieve its inflation target. There is a large literature that seeks to understand the effects of movements in energy prices on output and inflation.1 1 See Blanchard and Gali (2007) for a review of the relevant empirical literature. Most of this literature uses a structural VAR approach in which shocks to oil prices have typically been identified as in Rotemberg and Woodford (1996). The idea is that the nominal price of oil is determined by the worldwide demand and supply of oil and, so, can be thought of as exogenous to output and inflation (and other variables) within any given economy. This implies that, to examine the effects of an exogenous oil price shock, all the researcher needs to do is to run a VAR and calculate the impulse response functions based on Working Paper No. 432 July 2011 6 the oil price being ordered first in the VAR. An alternative approach to identifying oil price shocks has been to consider specific dates on which the oil price moved in a dramatic (that is, ‘exogenous and unforeseeable’) way. Hamilton (1985) came up with a list of dates on which such ‘oil shocks’ had happened and this list was extended by Hoover and Perez (1994) who used monthly data. Most recently, Cavallo and Wu (2006) develop measures of exogenous oil-price shocks for the period 1984 to 2006 based on market commentary (specifically that found in Oil Daily and Oil and Gas Journal) on daily oil price fluctuations. They then regress output and inflation on these measures to find out how they respond to oil price shocks. All of these empirical approaches find that oil shocks have large effects on output and inflation. But, constructing a model in which oil has large effects has proven to be difficult. Hamilton (2008), for example, shows that given the share of energy in production in the United States and the elasticity of output with respect to a change in energy use, movements in oil prices can only explain a small fraction of the falls in GDP typically seen after oil price rises. Kim and Loungani (1992) and Dhawan and Jeske (2008) show the same thing in DSGE models. Against this, Rotemberg and Woodford (1996) argue that under imperfect competition with countercyclical desired mark-ups it is possible to generate falls in output in line with the empirical results. In this paper, I take a DSGE model and estimate it using UK data. The model itself is not original: it is that developed in Harrison et al (2011) to analyse the effects of the large rise in oil prices between 2003 and 2008 on UK inflation. But, the emphasis in the two papers is different. Harrison et al are interested in analysing the effects of energy theoretically, with a particular emphasis on the implications of permanent energy price shocks for economies with declining stocks of natural resources, such as the United Kingdom. In contrast, the goal of this work is to produce a macroeconomic model that can be used to analyse quantitatively the effects of many temporary shocks, including but not limited to energy prices, on inflation as well as how monetary policy can respond to such shocks. Furthermore, estimating the model enables us to evaluate how these shocks have evolved over time and the implications of this for explaining movements in output and inflation. The rest of the paper is structured as follows. Section 2 lays out the model of Harrison et al (2011). Section 3 discusses the data and the estimation procedure and presents the estimation results. Section 4 discusses the implications of the estimates for the responses of macroeconomic variables to the shocks in the model and Section 5 shows the evolution of these shocks over time and decomposes recent movements in output and inflation among them. Section 6 concludes. 2 The model The basic building blocks of the Harrison et al (2011) model are standard in the literature. The main complication is that there are three consumption goods: non-energy output, petrol and utilities (which can be thought of as a combination of gas and electricity). This approach is similar to that of Kim and Loungani (1992) and Dhawan and Jeske (2008), who allow for consumption of energy and non-energy; the current model goes further by splitting energy into Working Paper No. 432 July 2011 7 petrol and utilities. The central bank operates a Taylor rule that affects aggregate demand via an IS curve. How this level of aggregate demand translates into demand for each of the goods is determined by preferences and relative prices. Wage inflation depends on total hours worked in a ‘Phillips Curve’ relationship. Each of the consumption goods is produced according to a sector-specific production function and sticky prices in each sector imply sector-specific New Keynesian Phillips Curves (NKPCs). The production functions themselves involve different combinations of five inputs: labour, capital, imported (non-energy) intermediates, oil and gas.2 At the margin, demand for oil and gas has to be met by reducing our net exports of these goods (increasing our net imports). Finally, the model adds a government that ‘eats up’ some of the non-energy good and levies taxes as well as a specific duty on petrol. This model incorporates nominal rigidities in the goods and labour markets and real rigidities such as habit formation in consumption, investment adjustment cost and variable capital utilisation. In what follows, I just present the log-linear equilibrium conditions; a detailed derivation can be found in the technical appendix to Harrison et al 2.1 Households Households consume the three final goods and supply differentiated labour to the firms. They are also assumed to own the capital stock and make decisions about capital accumulation and utilisation. This assumption, now standard in the business cycle literature, is done in order to simplify the firms’ decision problem. The following set of equation determines the household’s choice of consumption, capital accumulation and utilisation: ( ) ( ) ( ) ( )         +      −−− −+ − −+ + −+ − = 1++− tbtctt chab c tt chab t chab chab t EicEcc ,,11 1 1 11 ˆ 11 1 ˆ 11 1 ˆ ε β π σψ σ σψσψ σψ (1) ( ) ( ) tinvtkt z z tkk tt z k tk z k tkk z k tbtctt wEk kEkkEi ,1,2 11,, ˆ 1 ˆ ˆ 1 ˆ1 1 1ˆ1 1 1 1 ε χδ χ εχ χδ χ χ χδ ε χε χδ ε ε β π + +− +− +− +      + +− + −      ++ +− =        +      −−− +− +−1+ (2) tztk zw ˆˆ , φ= (3) where c is consumption, i is the nominal interest rate, πc is the inflation rate of consumer prices, εb is best thought of as a risk premium shock, wk is the rental rate for capital, εinv is an investment-specific technology shock, z is the capital utilisation rate and k is the capital stock.3 2 This represents a difference to the approach of Kim and Loungani (1992) and Dhawan and Jeske (2008) who assume that energy – petrol and utilities in the current model – is not produced but rather is directly imported. Variables without time subscripts refer to their steady-state values and ‘hatted’ variables represent log deviation from trend. In terms of the parameters, ψhab represents the degree of habit formation in consumption, σc is the intertemporal elasticity of substitution, β is the discount rate, χk scales the costs of adjusting the capital stock, χz scales the effect of capital 3 The investment-specific technology shock reduces the costs of adjusting the capital stock and so means that a given level of investment will add more to the capital stock. Working Paper No. 432 July 2011 8 utilisation on the depreciation rate, δ is the steady-state depreciation rate and φz is the inverse elasticity of the capital utilisation cost function. Equation (1) is the consumption Euler equation. Consumption depends on past consumption due to external habit formation. As a result, the elasticity of consumption to the interest rate depends not only on the elasticity of substitution but also on the degree of habit formation parameter. Equation (2) is the capital accumulation equation in which lagged capital appears due to the assumption of capital adjustment costs.4 Aggregate consumption is composed of consumption of petrol, utilities and ‘non-energy’. Consumption of ‘energy’ will be given by: Equation (3) determines capacity utilisation as a function of the rental rate of capital. ( ) tPptUptE ccc ,,, ˆˆ1ˆ ψψ +−= (4) and, hence, aggregate consumption will be given by: ( ) teetnet ccc ,, ˆˆ1ˆ ψψ +−= (5) Relative prices will be given by: tU p tE ep tn e tU cccp ,,,, ˆ 1 ˆ 11 ˆ 1 ˆ σσσσ −         −+= (6) and tP p tU p tPtU ccpp ,,,, ˆ 1 ˆ 1 ˆˆ σσ +−=− (7) Households also have the option of holding either foreign or domestic bonds but trade in foreign bonds incurs quadratic costs. This results in the UIP condition: trftfbftttt bissE ,,1 1 1 ˆˆ εχ β +−              −−−=−+ (8) where s is the nominal exchange rate, χbf is a parameter determining the cost of holding foreign bonds and εrf is a shock to world real interest rates. As a normalisation, I denote foreign bond holdings as a proportion of non-energy output and I assume, without loss of generality, that the supply of domestic government bonds is zero in all periods; that is, the government balances its budget via lump-sum taxes on consumers. 4 Note that, following Harrison and Oomen (2010), I assume capital adjustment costs rather than the investment adjustment costs, more often used in the literature. Although this formulation is much more intuitive than the more standard formulation, it means that the model is unable to capture the hump-shaped dynamics of investment. Working Paper No. 432 July 2011 9 Each household is a monopoly supplier of differentiated labour. Thus, they set their wages as a mark-up over their marginal rate of substitution between leisure and consumption (percentage deviation denoted by mrs), subject to nominal wage stickiness and partial indexation of wages to inflation. Hence, wage inflation will be given by: ( )( ) ( )( ) ( ) twtt ww h w ww tt w t w w t mrswWEWW ,11 ˆ 111 11 11 ε βξψ σ σ ψβψ βξ β βξ ξ +− +−      + −− − + + + = +−  (9) where W is nominal wage inflation and εw is a wage mark-up shock. Here ψw is the share of household members able to reoptimise their wages and ξw governs the extent to which non optimised wages are indexed to past inflation. The steady-state wage mark-up is given by 1−w w σ σ and σh denotes the Frisch elasticity of labour supply. The equations defining the marginal rate of substitution and the real consumption wage are: ( )( )1ˆ1ˆ 1ˆ1 −−++= tchabt c t h t cchmrs σψ σσ (10) tcttt wWw ,1ˆˆ π−+= −  (11) 2.2 Non energy producing firms The representative non-energy producing firm is assumed to have the following production function: ( ) tatqtqt eBq ,ˆˆ1ˆ εαα ++−= (12) where q denotes output of non-energy, and εa represents a shock to this. B denotes a bundle of value-added, Vn, and intermediate imported goods, Mn: ( ) tnBtnBt MVB ,, ˆˆ1ˆ αα +−= (13) and e denotes energy input in this sector, which will be given by: tutpt IIe ,, ˆˆˆ == (14) where Ip is input of petrol, and Iu is input of utilities, both to the non-energy sector. Cost minimisation implies the following demand curves for value-added, imports and energy: ta q q t q q t q tvcttn BqpV ,,, 1 ˆ 1 ˆ 1 ˆˆˆ ε σ σ σ σ σ µ − + − ++−= (15) Working Paper No. 432 July 2011 10 ta q q t q t q tmttn BqpM ,,, 1 ˆ1 1 ˆ 1 ˆˆˆ ε σ σ σσ µ − +         −−+−= (16) ( )( ) ( ) taqtUntpnqttqt ppqe ,,, 1ˆ1ˆˆˆˆ εσψψσµσ −+−+−+= (17) where µ is real marginal cost and pvc is the ‘competitive’ price of value-added (the marginal cost of producing it). Firms in the non-energy sector are also subject to nominal rigidities in their price-setting. In particular, each period they are only allowed to set their price optimally with a probability of 1-χp. If they cannot change their price optimally, they partially index their price to lagged inflation. The resulting NKPC is: ( )( ) ( ) tt p pp tttt E ,11 ˆ 1 11 11 µεµ χβε βχχ π βε ε π βε β π + + −− + + + + = −+ (18) where ε is the degree of indexation and εµ is a price mark-up shock. 2.3 Value-added sector ‘Value-added’ producers use labour and capital to produce value-added, V: ( ) ( )ttvtvt zkhV ++−= −1 ˆˆ1ˆ αα (19) The term in z shows that the capital effectively used in production depends on the intensity of capital utilisation. Unlike Harrison et al (2011), I assume value-added producers need to borrow the money to finance a proportion, ψwc, of their wage bill. This can be motivated by the fact that firms typically need to borrow to finance their working capital needs: that is, the need for funds to cover the gap between production and when the firm is able to sell its output. This assumption has been used by many others, eg, Fuerst (1992) and Christiano and Eichenbaum (1992, 1995), and implies a ‘cost channel’ of monetary transmission. Cost minimisation by value-added producers implies the following demand curves for capital and labour:                 +      −−−−+= tbtwcttvcVtt iwpVh ,, 1 1 ˆˆˆˆ ε β ψσ (20) ( )tktvcVttt wpVzk ,,1 ˆˆˆˆˆ −+=+− σ (21) 2.4 Petrol producers Petrol, qp, is produced using inputs of crude oil, Io, and value-added, Vp. I assume a simple Leontieff production function: tptotp VIq ,,, ˆˆˆ == (22) Working Paper No. 432 July 2011 11 The motivation for this choice of production function is that it is not clear how adding more and more workers to a given amount of oil could physically increase the amount of petrol that can be produced from it. Firms in this sector are also subject to nominal rigidities in their price-setting. In this case, they are able to optimally change their price in any given quarter with probability 1χpp and εpp represents the degree of indexation. The resulting NKPC is: ( )( ) ( ) tp pppp pppp tpb pp pp tpbt pp tpb E ,1,1,, ˆ 1 11 11 µ χβε βχχ π βε ε π βε β π + −− + + + + = −+ (23) where real marginal cost in this sector will be given by: ( ) tpbtoqptvcqptp ppp ,,,, ˆˆ1ˆˆ −−+= ψψµ (24) where po is the price of oil and ppb is the basic (pre-duty) price of petrol. Finally, I can note that by definition: 1,,, ˆˆ −−+= tpbtpbttpb ppππ (25) 2.5 Utilities producers Output of utilities, qu, is produced using inputs of gas, Ig, and value-added, Vu. I assume a simple Leontieff production function: tutgtu VIq ,,, ˆˆˆ == (26) Again, the motivation for this choice of production function is that it is not clear how adding more and more workers to a given amount of natural gas could physically increase the amount of gas and electricity that can be produced from it. Firms in this sector are also subject to nominal rigidities in their price-setting. In this case, they are able to optimally change their price in any given quarter with probability χu and εu represents the degree of indexation. The resulting NKPC is: ( )( ) ( ) tu uu uu tu u u tut u tu E ,1,1,, ˆ 1 11 11 µ χβε βχχ π βε ε π βε β π + −− + + + + = −+ (27) where real marginal cost in this sector will be given by: ( ) tutgutvcutu ppp ,,,, ˆˆ1ˆˆ −−+= ψψµ (28) where pg is the price of gas and pu is the price of utilities. Finally, I can note that by definition: 1,,, ˆˆ −−+= tututtu ppππ (29) Working Paper No. 432 July 2011 12 2.6 Monetary and fiscal policy Monetary policy is assumed to follow a Taylor rule with the central bank responding to deviations of inflation from target and value-added from flexible-price value-added: ( )( ) titytcpdotrgtrgt yii ,,1 ˆ11 1 1 1 εθπθθ β θ β ++−+              −−=      −− − (30) where εi is a monetary policy shock. Flexible-price value-added is defined as what value-added would be in a flexible-price version of the model given the estimated values of the shocks. The fiscal authority levies a duty on petrol. In my estimation, I assume that this is not changed over time. Given that, I obtain: ( ) tpbdtp pp ,, ˆ1ˆ ψ−= (31) That is, since it is held constant, the petrol duty has no role other than to reduce the impact of a change in petrol producers’ other costs on the final price of petrol paid by consumers. Since, I assume, as said earlier, that the government balances its budget using lump-sum taxes on consumers (denoted by T), we can write the government’s budget constraint as ttptpdt TqPG += ,,ψ . Unanticipated changes in government spending will form part of the ‘domestic demand’ shock that I discuss below. 2.7 Foreign sector I assume that the United Kingdom is a small open economy. Hence, world prices are exogenous. Oil and gas prices adjust immediately to their world prices:5 tpto sp o ˆˆ , −= ε (32) tptg sp g ˆˆ , −= ε (33) where opε is a shock to world oil prices and gpε is a shock to world gas prices. UK import prices, on the other hand, take time to adjust to purchasing power parity. This results in the NKPC for import prices: ( )( ) ( ) ( )tmtp pmpm pmpm tmt pm tm pm pm tm psE mf ,1,1,, ˆˆ 1 11 11 −− + −− + + + + = +− ε ξβι βξξ π βι β π βι ι π (34) where mpε is a shock to the world price of our imports. Finally, I assume the following demand function for our exports of non-energy goods: 5 For simplicity, I ignore issues about different varieties of crude oil as well as refining costs. Working Paper No. 432 July 2011 13 ( )( )txyztnztn sxx f ˆ1ˆˆ 1,, ηεψψ −−+= − (35) where fyε is a world demand shock. 2.8 Market clearing I close the model with the following market-clearing conditions: ( ) ( )tPtP c uu c n tUtU c uu tn c n ttc cp cp cp cp c cp cp cp c cp c cp ,,,,,, ˆˆ1ˆˆˆˆˆ +        −−+++=+ (36) tp un tu u tn n t V V V V V V V V V V V V ,,, ˆ1ˆˆ       −−++= (37) tP P P tP P P tP I q c c q c q ,,, ˆ1ˆˆ       −+= (38) tU U U tU U U tU I q c c q c q ,,, ˆ1ˆˆ         −+= (39) tO o o tO X I X I ,, ˆˆ −= (40) tG g g tG X I X I ,, ˆˆ −= (41) ( ) tg g tn n t z tttn n t q c x q x z q k k q k k q k c q c q ,,1, ˆˆˆ1ˆˆˆ ε χδ +++ − −+= − (42) ( ) ( ) ( )tntm n toto o tgtg g tn n tftf Mp q M Xp q X Xp q X x q x bb ,,,,,,,1,, ˆˆˆˆˆˆˆ 1 +−+++++= − β (43) where εg is a shock to the exogenous components of domestic demand shock. This can be thought of as combining shocks to government spending, stockbuilding and the part of investment that cannot be explained via the cost of capital. 2.9 Shock processes As is common in the literature, I suppose that the shocks follow AR(1) processes: tataata ,1,, ηερε += − (44) tbtbbtb ,1,, ηερε += − (45) tgtggtg ,1,, ηερε += − (46) tItiiti ,1,, ηερε += − (47) ttt ,1,, µµµµ ηερε += − (48) tinvtinvinvtinv ,1,, ηερε += − (49) twtwwtw ,1,, ηερε += − (50) tytyyty ffff ,1,, ηερε += − (51) tptpptp mfmfmfmf ,1,, ηερε += − (52) tptpptp oooo ,1,, ηερε += − (53) Working Paper No. 432 July 2011 14 tptpptp gggg ,1,, ηερε += − (54) trftrfrftrf ,1,, ηερε += − (55) where the η’s are all assumed to be iid normal processes, whose standard deviations are to be estimated. 3 Estimation 3.1 Data The model was estimated using Bayesian techniques on data for the period 1996 Q2 (the earliest quarter for which data on wholesale gas prices were available) to 2009 Q3. As there are ten shocks in the BBWE model, ten data series were used in the estimation: five domestic and five ‘world’. In terms of domestic data, I used data on final output of the non-energy producing sector, consumption, the consumption deflator, investment, total hours worked in the private sector, real wages and the Bank Rate. Consumption was defined as the sum of the ONS chained volume measures of final consumption expenditure by households (ABJR) and non-profit institutions (HAYO). The consumption deflator was calculated by dividing the sum of the ONS measures of final consumption expenditure at current market prices by households (ABJQ) and non-profit institutions (HAYE) by the volume measure. Investment was defined as ‘business investment’ (NPEL). How the series for final output of the non-energy producing sector was constructed is discussed at length in Harrison et al (2011). Data on total hours worked in the private sector were taken from the Bank of England Quarterly Model (BEQM) and is described in Harrison et al (2005). The real wage was calculated by dividing private-sector wages and salaries including self-employment income (again as described in Harrison et al (2005)) by total hours worked in the private sector and then again by the consumption deflator. Finally, the ONS publish a series for the ‘London clearing banks: Base rate’ as an annual rate (Code: AMIH) and this was converted to a quarterly rate. Prior to the estimation, all data were detrended using the Hodrick-Prescott filter with the smoothing parameter, λ, set to 1,600. For world data I used series for UK-weighted world trade, world export prices and world interest rates taken from BEQM described in Harrison et al (2005). I used the dollar oil price, available on a daily basis from Datastream (Code: OILBRNP_P) converted to its quarterly average. Finally, I calculated a world wholesale gas price by multiplying the wholesale gas price in sterling (available on a daily basis from Bloomberg: Code: NBPGDAHDBBSW) by the sterling exchange rate index, published daily by the Bank of England. Following Harrison and Oomen (2010), these data were used to estimate the foreign shock processes separately and the results were hard-coded into the model that was estimated. The estimation results were:6 0142.0,9061.0 ,1,, =+= − ffff ytytyty σηεε (56) 0075.0,8991.0 ,1,, =+= − mfmfmfmf ptptptp σηεε (57) 6 These equations – with the exception of the equation for world gas prices – were estimated over the period 1977 Q1 to 2009 Q3. The equation for world gas prices was estimated over the period 1996 Q2 – the earliest date for which we have data on wholesale gas prices – to 2009 Q3. Working Paper No. 432 July 2011 15 14100,7283.0 ,1,, .σ oooo ptptptp =+= − ηεε (58) 2544.0,5940.0 ,1,, =+= − gggg ptptptp σηεε (59) 0012.0,8738.0 ,1,, =+= − ffff rtrtrtr σηεε (60) One thing we can note here is that the shocks to world oil and gas prices have high volatility and low persistence relative to the other foreign shocks. 3.2 Priors I followed Harrison and Oomen (2010) and split my parameters into two groups: those that were most important in determining the steady state of the model and, hence, average ratios, and those that determine the dynamics of the model. Parameters in the first group were set so as to match the steady-state values used in Harrison et al (2011). When I came to estimate the model, I held these parameters fixed. The values I used for this first group of parameters, and the relevant steady-state ratios I fixed, are shown in Table A. Table A: First group parameter values Parameter Value Description Motivation β 0.9925 Discount factor Assumption χbf 0.001 Cost of adjusting portfolio of foreign bonds Normalisation δ 0.013 Depreciation rate Assumption χz =1/β-(1- δ) Scales the effect of capital utilisation on the depreciation rate Ensures capital utilisation equals 1 in steady state σw 3.8906 Elasticity of demand for differentiated labour Implies a wage mark-up of 1.35 (that is, 35%) in steady state σe 0.4 Elasticity of substitution between non-energy and energy in consumption Assumption σp 0.1 Elasticity of substitution between petrol and utilities in energy consumption Assumption σv 0.5 Elasticity of substitution between labour and capital in value-added production Assumption σq 0.15 Elasticity of substitution between energy and everything else in nonenergy production Assumption ηx 1.5 Elasticity of demand for exports Harrison et al (2011) ψe 0.0526 Share of energy in consumption Implies 0215.0= cp cp c uu ψp 0.5913 Share of petrol in energy consumption Implies 03.0= cp cp c pp αq 0.0528 Cost share of energy in non-energy output Implies ( ) 016.0= +++ + pppuu ggoo Xcpcpq ipip αB 0.3154 Cost share of imports in ‘bundle’ Implies ( ) 25.0= +++ pppuu nm Xcpcpq mp Working Paper No. 432 July 2011 16 Table A (continued): First group parameter values Parameter Value Description Motivation αv 0.1701 Cost share of capital in value-added Implies 75.0= Vp wh v ψn 0.3096 Cost share of petrol in energy output Implies 82.1= uu pp ip ip ψqp 0.1844 Cost share of value-added in petrol output Implies 82.1= uu pp ip ip ψu 0.4834 Cost share of value-added in utilities output Implies 82.1= uu pp ip ip ψd 0.617 Share of duty in petrol prices Implies ( ) 617.0 1 = + p pp p d τ cp c c n 0.9474 Share of non-energy consumption in total consumption To match data in Harrison et al (2011) cp cp c uu 0.0215 Share of utility consumption in total consumption To match data in Harrison et al (2011) V Vn 0.9815 Share of value-added used as input in non-energy goods To match data in Harrison et al (2011) V Vu 0.0145 Share of value-added used as input in utilities To match data in Harrison et al (2011) p p q c 0.4204 Share of petrol output going to consumption To match data in Harrison et al (2011) u u q c 0.4054 Share of utilities output going to consumption To match data in Harrison et al (2011) o o I X 0.4551 Ratio of oil exports to oil inputs To match data in Harrison et al (2011) g g I X -0.0792 Ratio of gas exports to gas inputs To match data in Harrison et al (2011) q cn 0.5802 Share of private consumption in non-energy output To match data in Harrison et al (2011) q k 4.7202 Ratio of capital to non-energy output To match data in Harrison et al (2011) q cg 0.1032 Share of government consumption in non-energy output To match data in Harrison et al (2011) q xn 0.2552 Share of exports in non-energy output To match data in Harrison et al (2011) q M n 0.2581 Ratio of imports of non-energy goods to output of non-energy goods To match data in Harrison et al (2011) q X o 0.0035 Ratio of oil exports to output of non-energy goods To match data in Harrison et al (2011) q X g -0.0007 Ratio of gas exports to output of non-energy goods To match data in Harrison et al (2011) For the second group of parameters, I generally took my priors from Harrison and Oomen (2010). In particular, I set the priors for the inverse of risk aversion in consumption, σc, the scale parameter for the costs of adjusting the capital stock, χk, the elasticity of capital utilisation Working Paper No. 432 July 2011 17 costs, φz, and the elasticity of labour supply σh, exactly in line with Harrison and Oomen. My prior for the coefficient on inflation in the Taylor rule is normal with a mean of 1.5 (as in the original Taylor paper) and a standard deviation of 0.25. For the remaining parameters I used beta distributions – since, by definition, they have to lie between 0 and 1 – with relatively loose priors. In all cases, I set my prior means to 0.5 and my prior standard deviations to 0.2. My priors are shown in Table B. In terms of the parameters governing the shock processes, I use beta distributions for the autocorrelation coefficients with means of 0.5 and standard deviations of 0.2, and I use inverse gamma distributions for the standard deviations with means of 1% and two degrees of freedom. Table B: Priors for second group parameters Parameter Description Prior distribution Prior mean Prior standard deviation σc Intertemporal elasticity of substitution Normal 0.66 0.198 ψhab Degree of habit persistence in consumption Beta 0.5 0.2 εk Degree of persistence in investment adjustment costs Beta 0.5 0.2 χk Scale of capital adjustment costs Normal 201 60.3 φz Inverse elasticity of capital utilisation costs Normal 0.56 0.168 ψwc Share of wage bill paid financed by borrowing Beta 0.5 0.2 σh Frisch elasticity of labour supply Normal 0.43 0.107 ψw Probability of being able to change wages Beta 0.5 0.2 ξw Degree of wage indexation Beta 0.5 0.2 χp Probability of not being able to change price: nonenergy sector Beta 0.5 0.2 χu Probability of not being able to change price: utilities Beta 0.5 0.2 χpp Probability of not being able to change price: petrol Beta 0.5 0.2 εp Degree of indexation: non-energy sector Beta 0.5 0.2 εu Degree of indexation: utilities sector Beta 0.5 0.2 εpp Degree of indexation: petrol sector Beta 0.5 0.2 ψx Degree of persistence in export demand Beta 0.5 0.2 ψpm Probability of not being able to change price: importers Beta 0.5 0.2 εpm Degree of indexation: importers Beta 0.5 0.2 θpdot Taylor rule coefficient on inflation Normal 1.5 0.25 θy Taylor rule coefficient on output Normal 0.125 0.05 θrg Degree of interest rate smoothing in Taylor rule Beta 0.5 0.2 3.3 Estimation results As is now standard in the literature, I first estimated the mode of the posterior distribution by maximising the log posterior function, which combines the priors with the likelihood given by the data, and then used the Metropolis-Hastings algorithm (as implemented in Dynare) to obtain the full posterior distribution. I used a sample of 250,000 draws (dropping the first 50,000 draws), obtaining an acceptance rate of 0.31. To test the stability of the sample, I used the Brooks and Gelman (1998) diagnostic (as implemented by Dynare), which compares within and between moments of multiple chains. Table C shows the posterior mode and means for the model parameters together with a 90% confidence interval. Working Paper No. 432 July 2011 18 Table C: Estimation results Parameter Description Posterior mode Posterior mean Confidence interval σc Intertemporal elasticity of substitution 0.7103 0.6256 0.4777 0.7775 ψhab Degree of habit persistence in consumption 0.6019 0.5876 0.4204 0.7564 εk Degree of persistence in investment adjustment costs 0.1887 0.1871 0.0793 0.2920 χk Scale of capital adjustment costs 106.05 116.52 64.47 172.96 φz Inverse elasticity of capital utilisation costs 0.4554 0.4591 0.3207 0.5980 ψwc Share of wage bill paid financed by borrowing 0.5548 0.4974 0.2551 0.7067 σh Frisch elasticity of labour supply 0.3547 0.3423 0.2724 0.4172 ψw Probability of being able to change wages 0.4630 0.4719 0.3487 0.5972 ξw Degree of wage indexation 0.1708 0.1882 0.0389 0.3212 χp Probability of not being able to change price: non-energy sector 0.8904 0.8968 0.8297 0.9668 χu Probability of not being able to change price: utilities 0.5618 0.5760 0.4478 0.7047 χpp Probability of not being able to change price: petrol 0.2192 0.2371 0.0948 0.3853 εp Degree of indexation: non-energy sector 0.2832 0.1491 0.0307 0.2581 εu Degree of indexation: utilities sector 0.2769 0.2073 0.0829 0.3359 εpp Degree of indexation: petrol sector 0.5021 0.4622 0.2479 0.7901 ψx Degree of persistence in export demand 0.4175 0.4152 0.3150 0.5234 ψpm Probability of not being able to change price: importers 0.4283 0.4169 0.2817 0.5654 εpm Degree of indexation: importers 0.8937 0.8296 0.7141 0.9481 θpdot Taylor rule coefficient on inflation 1.2190 1.1951 0.9904 1.4646 θy Taylor rule coefficient on output 0.1528 0.1494 0.1196 0.1813 θrg Degree of interest rate smoothing in Taylor rule 0.7800 0.7640 0.6952 0.8318 In terms of the parameter values themselves, the posterior mean estimate for the inverse coefficient of relative risk aversion, σc, is slightly lower than its prior mean, though it is not well identified by the data. The posterior mean estimate for εk is much lower than its prior mean, suggesting little persistence in investment. The inverse Frisch elasticity of labour supply is lower than its prior mean and is well identified. The degree of habits in consumption is not well identified and, at 0.59, is a little lower than previous estimates on UK data.7 I find that about 50% of the wage bill has to be financed using working capital, though again this parameter is not well identified. There appears to be little persistence in export demand. In terms of nominal rigidities, the posterior mean estimates suggest, not surprisingly, that petrol prices are flexible, being changed roughly every four months on average. Utility prices are also quite flexible being changed roughly every seven months on average. Non-energy prices, on the other hand, are very sticky, being changed roughly every 29 months on average, respectively. The relative stickiness of prices in the three sectors are in line with survey and other evidence for the United Kingdom.8 7 See, eg, Banerjee and Batini (2003). But the absolute degree of price stickiness in the non-energy sector 8 See Greenslade and Parker (2010) and Bunn and Ellis (2009). Working Paper No. 432 July 2011 19 seems much too high, although this result has often been found in estimated DSGE models.9 Indexation in all sectors is quite low suggesting little inflation persistence. The posterior estimates suggest that import prices are relatively flexible, changing on average every five months, and the degree of indexation of import prices is high. Surprisingly, wages are estimated to be fairly flexible, changing roughly every six months on average. Wage changes are hardly indexed to lagged wage inflation, as might be expected given the lack of formal indexation of wage bargains in the United Kingdom at present. Turning to the shocks, Table D shows the estimated posterior mode and means for the autocorrelation coefficients and standard errors of the domestic shocks, together with a 90% confidence interval. The posterior estimates suggest that the productivity shock is fairly persistent but the other shocks much less so; the model is able to explain persistence in the data without having to resort to extremely persistent shocks. The mean posterior estimate for the standard deviation of monetary policy shocks is only 15 basis points. This is not altogether surprising given that the model was estimated over the inflation-targeting period. But, the domestic demand and investment-specific technology shocks are highly volatile over this period with posterior mean estimates for their standard deviations of 9.2% and 6.1%, respectively. Table D: Estimation results for the domestic shock processes Autocorrelation coefficients Posterior mode Posterior mean Confidence interval Productivity, εa 0.8906 0.8747 0.8176 0.9311 Risk premium, εb 0.7217 0.6656 0.5760 0.7544 Domestic demand, εg 0.7306 0.6621 0.5235 0.8263 Monetary policy, εi 0.3381 0.3174 0.1888 0.4458 Investment-specific technology, εinv 0.4269 0.4323 0.3025 0.6055 Wage mark-up, εw 0.2569 0.2247 0.0924 0.3407 Price mark-up, εµ 0.2615 0.2398 0.0842 0.3935 Standard deviations Productivity, εa 0.0120 0.0123 0.0103 0.0142 Risk premium, εb 0.0032 0.0041 0.0030 0.0052 Domestic demand, εg 0.0901 0.0923 0.0777 0.1068 Monetary policy, εi 0.0015 0.0015 0.0013 0.0018 Investment-specific technology, εinv 0.0551 0.0612 0.0320 0.0952 Wage mark-up, εw 0.0093 0.0098 0.0079 0.0118 Mark-up, εµ 0.0025 0.0028 0.0023 0.0034 Tables E and F show the importance of each of the shocks in terms of how much each explains the variance in the endogenous variables. The productivity shock is clearly the most important in explaining consumption, accounting for almost two thirds of the variation in consumption. The investment-specific technology shock contributes little to the variation in all variable except for investment, where it explains 83% of the variance. The bulk of the variation in GDP, total hours and gross output is explained by a combination of the productivity, domestic demand, monetary policy and risk premium shocks, which together account for 79%, 77% and 81% of 9 See Smets and Wouters (2003) and Gali et al (2001) for the euro area and Di Cecio and Nelson (2007), Harrison and Oomen (2010) and Kamber and Millard (2010) for the United Kingdom. Working Paper No. 432 July 2011 20 their variance, respectively. Turning to nominal variables, 64% of the variation in price inflation is explained by the price mark-up shock, with the productivity shock accounting for about 18%. Similarly, 80% of the variation in wage inflation is explained by the wage mark-up shock. And, so, a combination of the mark-up and productivity shocks explain 83% of variation in the real wage. 80% of the variation in the nominal interest rate is explained by the productivity, monetary policy and price mark-up shocks. Perhaps surprisingly, the foreign shocks account for little of the variation in UK data with the exception of the real exchange rate, 33% of whose variation is explained by them. Another 30% of the variation in the real exchange rate is explained by the productivity shock. Table E: Variance decompositions – domestic shocks Productivity Monetary policy Domestic demand Investment- specific technology Wage mark-up Price mark-up Risk premium Consumption 62.7% 6.8% 3.3% 0.2% 1.2% 3.0% 10.6% Investment 2.1% 3.8% 1.7% 83.3% 0.5% 2.7% 5.1% GDP 20.5% 13.8% 22.5% 4.7% 4.4% 5.5% 21.8% Gross output 38.3% 9.3% 20.2% 4.0% 0.3% 4.8% 13.5% Total hours 21.4% 12.7% 21.8% 4.5% 8.0% 4.2% 21.0% Real wage 11.0% 5.2% 1.3% 0.2% 57.5% 14.2% 4.3% Real exchange rate 29.7% 11.2% 1.4% 0.2% 1.4% 6.1% 17.5% Nominal interest rate 35.4% 26.6% 2.5% 0.4% 0.3% 17.8% 8.6% Annual inflation rate 17.8% 2.0% 0.3% 0.0% 5.7% 63.7% 0.9% Annual wage inflation rate 1.4% 5.8% 1.4% 0.2% 79.7% 3.6% 5.7% Table F: Variance decompositions – foreign shocks Oil price Foreign demand Foreign export price Foreign interest rate Gas price Consumption 0.3% 4.8% 2.8% 3.6% 0.7% Investment 0.0% 0.4% 0.1% 0.1% 0.0% GDP 0.1% 2.5% 0.2% 3.8% 0.2% Gross output 0.1% 6.7% 1.8% 0.8% 0.2% Total hours 0.1% 2.3% 0.2% 3.5% 0.2% Real wage 0.4% 4.0% 0.6% 0.6% 0.7% Real exchange rate 0.1% 10.8% 1.3% 20.3% 0.2% Nominal interest rate 0.9% 0.7% 1.3% 4.0% 1.6% Annual inflation rate 2.8% 0.5% 1.0% 2.2% 3.2% Annual wage inflation rate 0.0% 0.9% 0.1% 1.0% 0.1% Working Paper No. 432 July 2011 21 3.4 Effects of including/excluding energy This section discusses how the inclusion of energy price effects – the main contribution of this model over, say, the Smets and Wouters (2007) model – affects the estimated coefficients of the model and whether, overall, it forms a better description of UK macroeconomic data than the simpler model. In order to do this, I consider an otherwise identical model in which consumption consists of only one good, which is produced using labour, capital and imports only. I drop the world oil and gas prices from my set of observed variables in the estimation and shocks to world oil and gas prices from my set of shocks in the model. I leave my fixed parameters and priors unchanged. The results are shown in the 4th column of Table G and the 3rd column of Table H. Table G: Parameter estimates for model with and without energy Parameter Description Baseline Ex-energy σc Intertemporal elasticity of substitution 0.6256 0.6481 ψhab Degree of habit persistence in consumption 0.5876 0.5310 εk Degree of persistence in investment adjustment costs 0.1871 0.3698 χk Scale of capital adjustment costs 116.52 219.03 φz Inverse elasticity of capital utilisation costs 0.4591 0.5560 ψwc Share of wage bill paid financed by borrowing 0.4974 0.5629 σh Frisch elasticity of labour supply 0.3423 0.3943 ψw Probability of being able to change wages 0.4719 0.4672 εw Degree of wage indexation 0.1882 0.4864 χp Probability of not being able to change price: non-energy sector 0.8968 0.5344 χu Probability of not being able to change price: utilities 0.5760 χpp Probability of not being able to change price: petrol 0.2371 εp Degree of indexation: non-energy sector 0.1491 0.3149 εu Degree of indexation: utilities sector 0.2073 εpp Degree of indexation: petrol sector 0.4622 ψx Degree of persistence in export demand 0.4152 0.4274 ψpm Probability of not being able to change price: importers 0.4169 0.4489 εpm Degree of indexation: importers 0.8296 0.4788 θpdot Taylor rule coefficient on inflation 1.1951 1.3542 θy Taylor rule coefficient on output 0.1494 0.1413 θrg Degree of interest rate smoothing in Taylor rule 0.7640 0.3018 Working Paper No. 432 July 2011 22 Table H: Shock process parameters for the model with and without energy Autocorrelation coefficients Baseline Ex-energy Productivity, εa 0.8747 0.5252 Risk premium, εb 0.6656 0.4652 Domestic demand, εg 0.6621 0.4810 Monetary policy, εi 0.3174 0.5148 Investment-specific technology, εinv 0.4323 0.3414 Wage mark-up, εw 0.2247 0.5641 Price mark-up, εµ 0.2398 0.5600 Standard deviations Productivity, εa 0.0123 0.0157 Risk premium, εb 0.0041 0.0074 Domestic demand, εg 0.0923 0.0920 Monetary policy, εi 0.0015 0.0035 Investment-specific technology, εinv 0.0612 0.1382 Wage mark-up, εw 0.0098 0.0076 Price mark-up, εµ 0.0028 0.0071 As can be seen, some of the parameter estimates look quite different. In particular, the model with no explicit energy effects estimates capital adjustment costs to be much larger, wage and price indexation to be much higher and suggests that prices are quite flexible. This result probably reflects ‘averaging’ of the degrees of stickiness estimated for the individual sectors in the model with explicit energy effects. Given the lack of energy price shocks, the model without energy requires more volatility in the other shocks to explain the data. Finally, we can note that the model with energy price effects included explains the data much better than the model that does not include them. In particular, the estimated log data density for the benchmark model is 1818 whereas for the model excluding energy effects it is only 1623. 4 Impulse response functions This section presents some impulse response functions for the estimated model. In particular, the results in this section are brought to bear on two questions: to what extent does the inclusion of energy effects alter the estimated responses of variables to shocks in the model, and, more specifically, how do variables respond to world oil and gas price shocks. The variables considered are value-added output, aggregate consumption, inflation, the base rate, the real wage and the exchange rate.10 10 Throughout this section ‘output’ refers to ‘value-added’ output (that is, GDP) and not to the gross output of any sector or the economy as a whole. Working Paper No. 432 July 2011 23 4.1 How does energy affect the responses of variables to shocks? Chart 1 shows the responses of output, aggregate consumption, inflation, the base rate, the exchange rate and the real wage to a one standard deviation monetary policy shock. In each case, the chart shows the responses implied by the estimated model together with the responses implied by the estimated model that excluded energy. In the benchmark estimated model, the shock represents an exogenous increase in the base rate of 51 basis points; in the version of the model estimated without energy effects, it represents a shock to interest rates of 84 basis points. Taking the results of the benchmark model first, we can note that the shock has quite a large effect on output, which falls by about 0.45%, while inflation falls by only about 0.03 percentage points on impact. Consumption also falls. The maximum response of real variables to the shock occurs immediately. Output and consumption then return to base with the shock having a minimal effect on either of them after about one year. Inflation continues to fall for three quarters after the initial shock, reaching a minimum -0.10 percentage points below base, before returning back to base. The effect is basically zero after about two years. Interest rates take about a year to return to base. The exchange rate follows the path of the interest rate – as a result of UIP – with the initial impact of the shock being an appreciation of 0.6%. The shock has a significant effect on real wages in the benchmark model as nominal wages fall quickly relative to the price level – given the estimated degrees of wage and price stickiness. These responses are in line with the empirical results of, eg, Di Cecio and Nelson (2007), Kamber and Millard (2010) and Christiano et al (2005), except that the responses of output and consumption are not ‘hump-shaped’. This results from the assumption of ‘capital adjustment costs’ in the current paper rather than ‘investment adjustment costs’. Christiano et al (2005) makes clear that it is investment adjustment costs that are key to generating hump-shaped responses in real variables to a monetary policy shock. So, replacing these with capital adjustment costs, which Smets and Wouters (2007) argue would not generate a hump-shaped response of investment to shocks, is likely to result in a lack of hump-shaped responses in all real variables. The response of real wages is large and hump-shaped as a result of the high degree of wage flexibility estimated in the current model, particularly relative to the price of non-energy goods. We can note that, with the exception of inflation, real wages and interest rates, the responses of variables are similar to their responses in the estimated version of the model without energy. The inflation response is much stronger in the model without energy effects given that prices were estimated to be much more flexible in this model. For the same reason, the real wage response is much smaller in the model that excluded energy effects. Working Paper No. 432 July 2011 24 Chart 1: Effects of a monetary policy shock Working Paper No. 432 July 2011 25 Chart 2: Effects of a productivity shock Chart 2 shows the responses of the same variables to a positive productivity shock for the benchmark model and for the version of the model without energy. Perhaps surprisingly, valueadded output falls. This is because the productivity shock affects gross output (of the nonenergy good) given value-added input. With sticky prices, demand for gross output will not respond much to the increase in productivity, so producers will cut down on inputs – including value-added. Consumption rises as the shock makes households wealthier and habit persistence is large enough to ensure a hump-shaped response. Inflation and interest rates fall and the Working Paper No. 432 July 2011 26 exchange rate depreciates as UK goods are now cheaper to produce vis-à-vis foreign goods. We can note that the inclusion of energy within the model has a large impact on the responses; in particular, value-added oscillates for the first couple of years after the shock before returning to base and the effect of the shock on inflation (and, as a result, interest rates) is much stronger. Again these results come about because prices are estimated to be quite flexible in the version of the model that ignores energy prices. Chart 3: Effects of a domestic risk premium (financial) shock Chart 3 shows the responses of value-added output, aggregate consumption, investment, inflation, the base rate, the exchange rate, the real wage, employment and wage inflation to a positive domestic risk premium shock (ie, a shock that raises the interest rate faced by consumers relative to the policy rate). This is an important shock to consider since we would Working Paper No. 432 July 2011 27 expect it to pick up the recent financial crisis. As expected, an increase in risk premia caused by, say, a credit tightening, would lead to falls in consumption, output and price inflation. However, the exchange rate appreciates as demand falls in the United Kingdom relative to abroad; the effect on the exchange rate of changes in the relative risk of UK versus foreign assets would, in this model, come through movements in the foreign exchange risk premium shock. In this case, the responses of output, consumption and the exchange rate are quantitatively similar to their responses in the estimated version of the model without energy. Real wages respond less in the model with no explicit energy effects since they are estimated to be stickier. Inflation, on the contrary responds by more – since prices are estimated to be more flexible – and the interest rate responds more given the central bank’s Taylor rule. Chart 4 shows the effects of a one standard deviation (about 9%) domestic demand shock. Such a shock leads to an increase in output of about 0.85% but a fall in consumption of about 0.15%, as the increase in output is much smaller than the increase in the exogenous components of domestic demand. The increase in demand leads to a rise in inflation and interest rates. The real wage rises on account of the increased demand for labour, though the magnitude of this rise again depends on which version of the model is used. Finally, the increase in domestic demand relative to foreign leads to an appreciation of the exchange rate. Finally in this subsection, Charts 5 and 6 show the effects of a world demand and a world export price shock, respectively. A world demand shock leads to an increase in output, real wages and, eventually, consumption. The increase in demand also pushes up on inflation and interest rates rise in response but the effect on both these variables is small. The rise in relative demand for the home economy’s exports leads to an appreciation of the exchange rate. Now, a shock to world demand might be expected to lead to rises in world commodity prices, such as oil and gas, with a dampening effect on domestic output. However, this channel is not present in this model since world oil and gas prices are assumed to be exogenous and are unaffected by world demand. A shock to world export prices leads to a rise in domestic import prices, which, in turn, feeds into domestic inflation. Domestic consumption falls as final output becomes more expensive. The response of value-added is interesting. A rise in import prices leads to a reduction in gross output and, other things equal, lowers the demand for value-added. But in the model with explicit energy effects, the fall in the relative price of energy will lead to an increase in demand for energy – both for production and consumption – and, in turn, an increase in the demand for value-added in energy production, outweighing the effect coming from the fall in demand for value-added in the production of non-energy goods. We can note, however, that in both cases the effect on value-added is small. Finally, the exchange rate appreciates in response to the increased demand for the home economy’s exports. Working Paper No. 432 July 2011 28 Chart 4: Effects of a domestic demand shock Working Paper No. 432 July 2011 29 Chart 5: Effects of a world demand shock Working Paper No. 432 July 2011 30 Chart 6: Effects of a world export prices shock Working Paper No. 432 July 2011 31 4.2 The effects of a rise in energy prices The key difference between this model and more standard macroeconomic models is the presence of a supply chain linking movements in world oil and gas prices, to movements in petrol and utilities prices, to movements in the overall level of consumer prices. Given that, it is instructive to consider the effects of shocks to the world prices of oil and gas. Chart 7: Effects of a world oil price shock Working Paper No. 432 July 2011 32 Chart 7 shows the responses of output, aggregate consumption, investment, inflation, the base rate, the exchange rate, the real wage, employment and wage inflation to a temporary exogenous increase in the world price of oil of 14% (a one standard deviation shock). The effects of such a shock on real variables are small.11 Output has fallen by just under 0.04% after one quarter, consumption by roughly 0.08% and investment by roughly 0.06%. Inflation is 0.11 percentage points higher after one quarter but then falls back quickly, being close to its steady-state rate after two years and beyond. Workers take a hit in their real consumption wage in the year and a half following the shock; that is, there is little evidence of real wage resistance. Why are the effects of an oil shock estimated to be so low? The answer is the result of the relatively low autocorrelation of this shock (estimated to be 0.73). Given the persistence of movements in oil prices, this seems like a surprising result. The answer to the puzzle can be seen in Chart 8. The chart shows that the large rises in the oil price in recent years have been interpreted as trend increases by the model; it is only the additional movements in the oil price that are interpreted as shocks.12 Chart 8: World oil price, actual and trend This model can also be used to analyse the effects of shocks to world gas prices. Chart 9 shows the responses of output, aggregate consumption, investment, inflation, the base rate, the exchange rate, the real wage, employment and wage inflation to a temporary exogenous increase in the world price of gas of 25% (a one standard deviation shock). The effects of this shock are similar to those of an oil price shock. The effects on real variables are, again small and, again, this is because the shock has low persistence (estimated to be 0.59). Output has fallen by 0.06% after one quarter, consumption by 0.11% and investment by 0.15%. Inflation is 0.11 percentage points higher after two quarters but then falls back quickly. Again, workers take a hit in their real consumption wage in the two years following the shock. 11 Although this might seem surprising, it is, as I said earlier, a fairly common result within the DSGE literature on oil (eg, Dhawan and Jeske (2008) and Rotemberg and Woodford (1996)) and it also matches the recent experience of large oil price movements with little obvious effect on output. 12 It would be instructive to consider the effects of permanent movements in energy prices within this model. But, in order to do this properly, it is necessary to take a stand on the degree of self-sufficiency of oil and gas production in the long run, as is done in Harrison et al (2008), but which is really beyond the scope of this paper. The interested reader is referred to their paper for further elaboration on these issues. Working Paper No. 432 July 2011 33 Chart 9: Effect of a world gas price shock 5 Using the model to decompose movements in output and inflation A major motivation for estimating this model is that it is important for monetary policy makers to understand what drives output and inflation in different periods. Given that the estimation produces time series for the shocks, it is possible to decompose movements in output and inflation into those fractions caused by each of the shocks. Doing this enables us to ascertain what shocks have been the main drivers of these variables. Working Paper No. 432 July 2011 34 Chart 10: Domestic shocks Working Paper No. 432 July 2011 35 Chart 10 shows the estimated time series for the domestic shocks within the model and Chart 11 shows the time series for the world shocks. As implied by the estimation results, we can see that the shocks to domestic demand, investment-specific technology and world oil and gas prices have been highly volatile over this period whereas monetary policy shocks have been small. Chart 11: Foreign shocks Working Paper No. 432 July 2011 36 Concentrating on the recent past, we can see that the economy has been affected by large negative shocks to productivity and domestic and world demand and a large positive shock to the domestic risk premium. This positive shock to the domestic risk premium is what the model will have picked up as the financial crisis of 2007-09. The increase in risk premium occasioned by the financial crisis would act to reduce demand in the model creating a recession, as was seen in the United Kingdom from 2008 Q2 to 2009 Q3. The world demand shock reflects what happened to world trade around the end of 2008 and the beginning of 2009. The negative productivity shock is harder to explain; it is likely to reflect, at least partly, the negative impact of the financial crisis on the ability of firms to raise working capital. To investigate further which shocks have been driving the UK economy over this sample period, Chart 12 shows a decomposition of movements in gross non-energy output between 2005 Q1 and 2009 Q3 into the portions caused by each of the shocks. We can see that, as expected, the recent slowdown in gross non-energy output has been driven by the negative productivity shock, the domestic risk premium shock and world demand.13 What may come as a little surprising is that energy prices are not major drivers of movements in non-energy output, despite being an input into production of that good and despite having moved substantially over this period. Again, this can be explained by the fact that the bulk of the movement in oil and gas prices was treated as a ‘trend increase; the remaining movements are quite volatile and, as a result, nonenergy producers seem to smooth through movements in this component of costs. Monetary policy shocks were mildly supporting output in 2009 since interest rates were cut by more than would have been suggested by the Taylor rule in the model. Of course, the ‘systematic’ response of monetary policy would have been supporting output in 2009 as would have the additional monetary stimulus coming from quantitative easing. Chart 12: Shock decomposition for gross non-energy output 13 Recall, a negative productivity shock would result in a rise in value-added output but a fall in gross output. Working Paper No. 432 July 2011 37 Of course, we might expect movements in energy prices to be key determinants of movements in energy (ie, petrol and utilities) output. This is illustrated in Chart 13. As can be seen, the high energy prices of 2008 substantially pulled down on energy output. By the end of the sample, low energy prices were pushing up on energy output. In addition, low productivity of non-energy inputs in the non-energy sector were pushing up on the demand for energy as nonenergy producers substituted towards energy. Against this, low world demand and the risk premium shock (proxying the effects of the financial crisis) were pulling energy output down. Chart 13: Shock decomposition for gross energy output Chart 14: Shock decomposition for the CPI inflation rate Turning to inflation, Chart 14 suggests that the price mark-up shock was pushing down substantially on inflation in 2009 with the financial shock and energy prices also contributing. Against this, the negative productivity shock was acting to push inflation up. Energy prices seem to have a much larger effect on inflation than they do output. The high oil prices in early Working Paper No. 432 July 2011 38 2008 and gas prices throughout 2008 were pushing up on inflation in 2008. As oil and gas prices fell in 2009, they again acted to push down on inflation. 6 Conclusions This paper has estimated a DSGE model of the United Kingdom developed originally by Harrison et al (2011). The basic building blocks of the model are standard in the literature. The main complication is that there are three consumption goods: non-energy output, petrol and utilities; given relative prices and their overall wealth, consumers choose how much of each of these goods to consume in order to maximise their utility. Each of the consumption goods is produced according to a sector-specific production function and sticky prices in each sector imply sector-specific New Keynesian Phillips Curves. This model, once estimated, forms a useful additional input within a policymaker’s ‘suite of models’. Estimating the parameters of this model using Bayesian techniques enables the user to apply the model quantitatively to UK policy issues. The paper has shown how this could be done by examining the effects of many different shocks on inflation and by decomposing recent movements in output and inflation into those parts caused by each of the structural shocks. It found that the fall in gross non-energy output from 2008 Q2 to 2009 Q3 was driven by three shocks: to productivity, to world demand and to the domestic risk premium. The risk premium shock also put downwards pressure on inflation during this period while the productivity shock was putting upwards pressure on inflation. The world demand shock was much less important in explaining the behaviour of inflation over this period. Working Paper No. 432 July 2011 39 References Banerjee, R and Batini, N (2003), ‘UK consumers’ habits’, Bank of England External MPC Unit Discussion Paper No. 13. Blanchard, O J and Galí, J (2007), ‘The macroeconomic effects of oil price shocks: why are the 2000s so different from the 1970s?’, in International dimensions of monetary policy, Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research. Brooks, S P and Gelman, A (1998), ‘General methods for monitoring convergence of iterative simulations’, Journal of Computational and Graphical Statistics, Vol. 7, pages 434-55. Bunn, P and Ellis, C (2009), ‘Price-setting behaviour in the United Kingdom: a microdata approach’, Bank of England Quarterly Bulletin, Vol. 49, No. 1, pages 28-36. Cavallo, M and Wu, T (2006), ‘Measuring oil-price shocks using market-based information’, Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco Working Paper No. 2006-28. Christiano, L J and Eichenbaum, M (1992), ‘Liquidity effects and the monetary transmission mechanism’, American Economic Review, Vol. 82, pages 346-53. Christiano, L J and Eichenbaum, M (1995), ‘Liquidity effects, monetary policy and the business cycle’, Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, Vol. 27, pages 1,113-36. Christiano, L J, Eichenbaum, M and Evans, C L (2005), ‘Nominal rigidities and the dynamic effects of a shock to monetary policy’, Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 113, pages 1-45. Dhawan, R and Jeske, K (2008), ‘Energy price shocks and the macroeconomy: the role of consumer durables’, Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, Vol. 40, pages 1,357-77. Di Cecio, R and Nelson, E (2007), ‘An estimated DSGE model for the United Kingdom’, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review, Vol. 89, pages 215-31. Faccini, R, Millard, S P and Zanetti, F (2011), ‘An estimated DSGE model of the UK labour market’, Bank of England Working Paper No. 408. Fuerst, T S (1992), ‘Liquidity, loanable funds, and real activity’, Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 29, pages 3-24. Gali, J, Gertler, M and Lopez-Salido, D (2001), ‘European inflation dynamics’, European Economic Review, Vol. 45, pages 1,121-50. Greenslade, J and Parker, M (2010), ‘New insights into price-setting behaviour in the United Kingdom’, Bank of England Working Paper No. 395. Working Paper No. 432 July 2011 40 Hamilton, J D (1985), ‘Historical causes of postwar oil shocks and recessions’, Energy Journal, Vol. 6, pages 97-116. Hamilton, J D (2008), ‘Oil and the macroeconomy’, in Durlauf, S N and Blume, L E (eds.), The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan. Harrison, R, Nikolov, K, Quinn, M, Ramsay, G, Scott, A and Thomas, R (2005), The Bank of England Quarterly Model, London: Bank of England. Harrison, R and Oomen, O (2010), ‘Evaluating and estimating a DSGE model for the United Kingdom’, Bank of England Working Paper No. 380. Harrison, R, Thomas, R and de Weymarn, I (2011), ‘The impact of permanent energy price shocks on the UK economy’, Bank of England Working Paper No. 433. Hoover, K D and Perez, S J (1994), ‘Post hoc ergo propter hoc once more: An evaluation of ‘Does monetary policy matter?’ in the spirit of James Tobin’, Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 34, pages 89-99. Kamber, G and Millard S P (2010), ‘Using estimated models to assess nominal and real rigidities in the United Kingdom’, Bank of England Working Paper No. 396. Kim, I-M and Loungani, P (1992), ‘The role of energy in real business cycle models’, Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 29, pages 173-89. Rotemberg, J and Woodford, M (1996), ‘Imperfect competition and the effects of energy price increases on economic activity’, Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, Vol. 28, pages 549-77. Smets, F and Wouters, R (2003), ‘An estimated dynamic stochastic general equilibrium model of the euro area’, Journal of the European Economic Association, Vol. 1, pages 1,123-75. Smets, F and Wouters, R (2007), ‘Shocks and frictions in US business cycles: a Bayesian DSGE approach’, American Economic Review, Vol. 97, pages 586-606.