American Economic Association Contracts between Art and Commerce Author(s): Richard E. Caves Reviewed work(s): Source: The Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 17, No. 2 (Spring, 2003), pp. 73-84 Published by: American Economic Association Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/3216857 . Accessed: 20/02/2013 10:10 Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at . http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp . JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org. . American Economic Association is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to The Journal of Economic Perspectives. http://www.jstor.org This content downloaded on Wed, 20 Feb 2013 10:10:58 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions Journal of Economic Perspectives?Volume 17, Number 2?Spring 2003?Pages 73-83 Contracts Between Art and Commerce Richard E. Caves Economists interested in the creative industries like arts and entertainment have had trouble mobilizing a set of economic tools suited to understand? ing such issues as why these industries are organized as they are and what consequences public policies hold for them. However, some useful tools have recently emerged from the theory of contracts. The basic structural characteristics of creative industries?their technologies of production and consumption? fiercely resist governance by anything approaching a complete contract. Yet they have evolved distinctive and serviceable contract forms that seem to differ from deal-making patterns prevalent in other sectors. Great works of art may speak for themselves, as connoisseurs declare, but they do not lead self-sufncient lives. The inspirations of talented artists reach consumers' hands (eyes, ears) only with the aid of other inputs?humdrum inputs?that respond to ordinary economic incentives. The visual artist needs a gallery to display and promote works to potential purchasers. The author requires a publisher, the pop musician a record label. A symphony orchestra or dance company wants a hall and someone to market the tickets. The Hollywood movie, the Broadway play, the TV sitcom?each demands a diverse group of creative talents as well as a set of humdrum inputs. The question of how contracts work between art and commerce thus is nested within the larger question of why artists and humdrum inputs choose to structure their relationships as they do. It turns out that the organization of the arts and entertainment industries depends heavily on the contracts that link creative and humdrum agents. These contracts vary in form, but all depend strongly on a common set of basic structural ? Richard E. Caves is Nathaniel Ropes Professor of Political Economy, Harvard University, Cambridge, Massachusetts. His e-mail address is {rcaves@harvard.edu). This content downloaded on Wed, 20 Feb 2013 10:10:58 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions 74 Journal of Economic Perspectives properties.1 All fall some distance short of the theoretical ideal of a complete contract that prescribes the signatories' actions in all possible states of nature. But all do seem to share a "best-feasible" property that leads the deals struck in diffuse sectors to exhibit common features. The Basics: Bedrock Structural Properties and Contract Theory Several bedrock structural properties seem to underpin the organization of the creative industries. They also distinguish arts and entertainment from other eco? nomic sectors and, in some cases, distinguish between groups of these activities. Each property gets an identifying catch phrase. Nobody knows refers to the fundamental uncertainty that faces the producer of a creative good. All inputs must be incorporated and the good presented to its intended customers before the producer learns their reservation prices. Producers make many decisions that affect the expected quality and appeal of the product, yet their ability to predict its audience's perception of quality is minimal. Producers know a lot about what has succeeded in the past, and they constantly try to extrapolate this knowledge to the project at hand, but these efforts achieve minimal predictive value (Goldman, 1984). That nobody knows would matter little if the inputs to a flopped creative effort could be salvaged and reused. However, the ubiquitousness of sunk costs denies the producer that protection. A creative good's suppliers must snag enough rents from each hit to cover the losses on several flops. Another fundamental property lies in the attitudes of artists toward their work. Art for art's sake invokes the utility that the artist gains from doing creative work. Economists normally assume that work occasions disutility. However, artists may accept wages for creative work that fall short of their opportunity cost in humdrum employment, which means that artists can be viewed as a source of cheap labor. Art for art's sake also embraces artists' tastes as to how the creative work is to be performed, the technique or style to be employed. The artist's preferences over how to execute creative work complicate the contracting process, particularly the definition and allocation of decision rights. Other basic properties involve horizontal and vertical differentiation, temporal coordination, durability and the hazards of coordination when several artists must collaborate. These properties will be introduced as needed. To understand how these properties shape the deals that govern creative 1 Indeed, some economists would roll professional sports into the package. This scope is customary in the legal field of entertainment and sports law (Weiler, 1997). 2This approach is developed in more detail in Caves (2000, especially the "Introduction"). This content downloaded on Wed, 20 Feb 2013 10:10:58 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions Richard E. Caves 75 industries' operation, we draw heavily on contract theory.3 Here we flag some points of connection between contract theory and the conditions of creative industries. First, contract theory pays much attention to asymmetrical information, which usually involves a situation in which the seller knows key characteristics of the product not known to the buyer. However, in creative industries nobody knows, and the core problem is one of symmetrical ignorance. Second, while principal-agent relationships are important in creative industries, many deals in creative goods involve joint ventures between symmetrically placed suppliers of diverse inputs. Third, production in creative industries commonly involves inputs attached in technologically determined sequences: a movie director cannot plan the shooting until the screenplay has been finalized. Critical problems then arise of assigning and transferring decision rights as the project passes from one input supplier to the next. Bilateral Deals: Artist and Facilitator We start with deals of the joint-venture variety, involving one artist and one humdrum party able to bring the artist's inspiration to potential consumers. Examples of such a deal include visual artist and art dealer, author and publisher, musician and record label. The contracts observed in each of these settings illus? trate how the bedrock structures of creative industries shape the structures of deals. Visual Artist and Art Gallery The relationship between artist and art gallery may seem the simplest of economic transactions, yet it is rendered complex and problematic by the bedrock properties. Art for art's 5