Emigration and wages in source countries: Evidence from Mexico Prachi Mishra* International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC 20431, United States Received 22 February 2004; received in revised form 4 August 2005; accepted 2 September 2005 Abstract This paper examines empirically the effect of Mexican emigration to the United States on wages in Mexico using data from the Mexican and US censuses from 1970 to 2000. The main result in the paper is that emigration has a strong and positive effect on Mexican wages. There is also evidence for increasing wage inequality in Mexico due to emigration. Simple welfare calculations based on a labor demand–supply framework suggest that the aggregate welfare loss to Mexico due to emigration is small. However, there is a significant distributional impact between labor and other factors. D 2005 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved. JEL classification: F22; J31 Keywords: Emigration; Wages; Wage inequality 1. Introduction A vast theoretical and empirical literature considers the labor-market impact of immigration. In contrast, the literature on the labor-market impact of emigration or the outflow of workers is almost exclusively theoretical.1 The absence of an empirical literature on the labor-market impact of emigration is surprising because the shares of the labor force leaving many individual 0304-3878/$ - see front matter D 2005 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved. doi:10.1016/j.jdeveco.2005.09.002 * Tel.: +1 202 623 9409. E-mail address: pmishra@imf.org. 1 See Borjas (1994, 1995) and Friedberg and Hunt (1995) for surveys of the empirical literature. The theoretical literature on international movement of factors includes, for example, Bhagwati and Hamada (1974), Rivera-Batiz (1989) and Quibria (1989). Journal of Development Economics 82 (2007) 180–199 www.elsevier.com/locate/econbase source countries is considerably higher than the proportionate changes in the labor force of many receiving countries due to immigration. To cite a few examples, the labor force in El Salvador, Jamaica, Barbados, Guyana and Belize have been reduced by 15% or more due to emigration to the US between 1970 and 2000.2 In comparison, immigrants constitute about 12% of the US labor force (Davis and Weinstein, 2002). This paper is the first econometric study of the effect of emigration on the national wages in a source country. I examine empirically the effect of Mexican emigration to the US on wages in Mexico using data from the Mexican and the US censuses from 1970 to 2000. The questions addressed in this paper are: how does emigration affect real wages in Mexico? What is the direction and magnitude of the impact? What are the implications of emigration for (i) wage inequality across schooling groups and (ii) national income distribution between labor and the other factors in Mexico? My identification strategy to estimate the impact of emigration on Mexican wages follows Borjas (2003) in that I utilize variation across schooling and experience groups in the labor force, and over time. Emigration is assumed to be exogenous in the basic specifications. However, I also address concerns about endogeneity and self-selection biases in the estimates. I find a strong and positive impact of the outflow of workers on wages in Mexico. A 10% decrease in the number of Mexican workers due to emigration in a skill group (defined by schooling and experience), increases the average wage in that skill group by about 4 percent. The estimates suggest that the outflow of Mexican workers to the US between 1970 and 2000 has increased the wage of an average Mexican worker by about 8%. The impact on wages, moreover, differs dramatically across schooling groups, with the greatest increase in wages being for the higher wage earners (those with 12–15 years of schooling). Hence, the estimates in this paper suggest that emigration could serve as one possible explanation for the increasing wage inequality in Mexico. Emigration as a channel to explain the increasing wage inequality in developing countries has received little attention in the literature.3 Simple welfare calculations in a competitive partial equilibrium framework show that the emigration loss to Mexico due to the outflow of workers between 1970 and 2000 is 0.5% of Mexico’s GDP in 2000.4 The estimated welfare loss is lower than the official worker remittances to Mexico, which were about 1% of GDP in 2000 (IMF).5 The emigration loss would also be easily outweighed by the big gains of the migrants themselves. However, there is a significant distributional impact. The gain to the workers who have stayed behind is 5.9% of GDP and the loss to the owners of fixed factors is 6.4% of GDP. Hence, the estimated distributional impact is about 12–13 times the aggregate economic impact. 2 In several source countries, the reduction in the labor force due to emigration to the US is in the range of 7–27%. In countries like Turkey and Algeria, the labor force has been reduced by about 10% due to emigration to Western Europe. There is also anecdotal evidence of sizeable flows to the gulf countries for which no systematic data exists. (Sources: US Census, OECD Migration Statistics, World Development Indicators). 3 Robbins (2002) and Zhu and Trefler (2005) provide evidence for increasing wage inequality in developing countries. 4 This is analogous to the estimates of immigration surplus that exists in the migration literature (Borjas, 1995). The concept was first given by MacDougall (1960) in the context of capital flows. Based on the simple textbook model of labor demand and supply, emigration leads to second order triangle losses for the aggregate economy (excluding the migrants) but there are large redistribution effects between workers and other factors. 5 The figure, however, excludes large amounts of unrecorded remittances. P. Mishra / Journal of Development Economics 82 (2007) 180–199 181 It is a very difficult problem to examine empirically the impact of emigration because source countries, in general, do not record information on those who leave. Mexico offers an ideal case to study because almost all emigration from Mexico is to the US. More than 95% of the international migrants from Mexico go to the US (Woodruff and Zenteno, 2002). Hence it gives an excellent opportunity to use the US data sources to study the effect on a source country’s labor market. One important contribution of this paper is to merge two micro-level data sets to examine empirically the impact of emigration on a source country’s labor market.6 The second reason why Mexico offers an ideal case is that the outflow of workers is sizeable in proportion to the Mexican labor force. In 2000, Mexican emigrants constituted about 16% of the Mexican labor force or approximately one out of seven Mexican workers migrate to the US. There are three types of studies on emigration that are related to this paper. First, there are a few case studies by the International Labor Organization (Stalker, 1994). Second, there are a few studies based on simulation exercises (e.g., O’Rourke and Williamson, 1999; Boyer et al., 1994). Third, there are a few region/sector specific studies (see Hanson et al., 2002; Hanson, 2003; Lucas, 1987). The present paper differs from the above studies in that I estimate the effect of overall emigration (legal and illegal, temporary and permanent) on a source country’s national (not regional) wages.7 The paper is organized as follows. Section 2 presents the empirical specifications, Section 3 describes the data and evidence, Section 4 discusses the results, Section 5 presents the quantifiable implications of the results. Section 6 concludes. 2. Empirical framework 2.1. Empirical specification Following Borjas (2003), I specify the regression equation as: wijt ¼ dmijt þ si þ vj þ pt þ si4pt þ vj4pt þ si4vj þ eijt ð1Þ where wijt is the mean value of monthly earnings (in logs) for workers in Mexico with education level i, experience j and observed in year t.8 The measure of the emigrant supply shock in schooling-experience-time cell (i, j, t) is denoted by mijtu Mijt Nijt , where Mijt is the number of Mexican emigrants in the US in cell (i, j, t) and Nijt is the national workforce in Mexico in cell (i, j, t). An emigrant from Mexico in the United States is defined as a person whom the US Census records as being born in Mexico. Hence, by this definition, an emigrant is a Mexican-born person in the US who may be a naturalized citizen 6 Chiquiar and Hanson (2005) also merge US and Mexican Census data for 1990 to examine who migrates from Mexico to the United States. They find evidence of intermediate/positive self-selection in terms of observable skills, which is consistent with the findings in this paper. 7 Robertson (2000a) looks at US–Mexico wage convergence in the border cities of Mexico and the US. He finds that the convergence is stronger in Tijuana (the border city with the highest INS apprehensions) than in other border cities. Based on the predictions of 3-good, 3-factor Heckscher Ohlin model, Mahmood (1991) conjectures that the rise in real wages in Pakistan in the mid-1970s could be due to emigration. 8 The reduced form empirical specification is derived assuming a 3-level CES production function for the national economy and perfectly competitive markets. The detailed derivation can be obtained upon request from the author. Using emigrant share as a measure of the emigrant supply shock follows the immigration literature which uses the immigrant share of the native population as a measure of the immigrant supply shock (e.g., Borjas, 2003, 1994; Friedberg, 2001; Altonji and Card, 1991, for representative studies). P. Mishra / Journal of Development Economics 82 (2007) 180–199182 or a non-citizen. Using the Census data, it is not possible to distinguish between legal and illegal immigrants in the US. However, there exists evidence of an undercount of the illegal migrants in the Census data, and hence also of emigration from Mexico (Costanzo et al., 2001). A worker in Mexico is defined as a person who is counted by the Mexican Census as residing in Mexico in a given year, and is a part of the labor force. si, vj and pt are vectors of fixed effects indicating the group’s schooling, work experience and time, respectively, which control for differences in wages across schooling, experience groups and over time. The interaction terms (si * pt) and (vj * pt) are introduced to control for the possibility that the returns to schooling and experience could change over time. The interaction terms, (si*vj), control for the possibility that the experience profile for the wages could differ across schooling groups. The impact of the economy-wide shocks would be captured through the period fixed effects. The shocks, which have differential impact on schooling and age groups, would be captured through the interaction of the period fixed effects with schooling and experience, respectively. The regressions are weighted by the number of workers in Mexico in cell (i, j, t). The parameter d gives the percentage change in wages due to a 1% change in the number of Mexican workers due to emigration. d is identified by within skill-group changes in emigrant shares over time. 2.2. Using individual level data It is also possible to estimate the effect of emigration on Mexican wages by estimating an individual level wage regression, including the emigrant supply shock as one of the explanatory variables. Friedberg (2001) also uses an individual level wage regression to estimate the impact of immigration on the wages of natives. The regression equation is specified as: wI ijt ¼ dmI ijt þ bXI ijt þ pt þ eI ijt ð2Þ where wI ijt is the real wage (in logs) for individual I in schooling group i, experience j, counted in year t. mI ijt is the ratio of emigrants to the workforce in Mexico in the cell to which individual I belongs, pt is a year dummy. mI ijt is a group variable and is same for all individuals within a cell. mI ijt is the vector of standard control variables used in the labor literature like experience, schooling, marital status, nativity, occupation, industry and the interactions of these variables with the year dummy. There are two advantages of using individual level regression specified in (2) as compared to the group regressions specified in Eq. (1): (i) the individual level regression can control for many individual-level factors affecting wages and (ii) greater efficiency because of more observations. Since the emigrant supply shock is the same for all individuals in the same cell, the errors eI ijt may be correlated within the cell, which may lead to inefficient estimates. Therefore, the standard errors have to be adjusted for clustering at the schooling-experience-time level. The grouped regression nevertheless is important since the regressor of interest, i.e. the emigrant supply shock is a group variable. 3. Data and evidence Data on the Mexican born population in the US are drawn from the 1970, 1990 and 2000 Public Use Microdata Samples (PUMS) of the Decennial Census of US. Data on the population in P. Mishra / Journal of Development Economics 82 (2007) 180–199 183 Mexico are drawn from the 1970, 1990 and 2000 PUMS of the Decennial Census of Mexico.9 The emigrant extracts form a 1% random sample in 1970 and 2000, and a 5% random sample in 1990. The extracts of the population in Mexico form a 1% random sample for 1970, 1990 and 2000. The individuals in the sample are divided into schooling and experience groups. The workers are divided into four schooling categories (i) high school dropouts (HSD)—less than 12 years of schooling, (ii) high school graduates (HSG)—exactly 12 years of schooling, (iii) some college (SC)—13 to 15 years of schooling, (iv) college graduates (CG)—16 years or more of schooling. Since the largest proportion of Mexicans are high school dropouts, for the regressions, I use a finer set of schooling categories where HSD are further divided into those with 0, 1–4, 5–8 and 9–11 years of schooling. The measure of work experience is defined as Age-AT, where AT is the assumed age of entry into the labor market for the typical worker. AT is assumed to be 17, 19, 21 and 23 years for HSD, HSG, SC and CG, respectively. The assumed values of AT reflect the assumption that individuals enter the labor force immediately after school. In order to focus on individuals in the working age group, the sample is restricted to individuals with experience ranging from 1 to 40 years (18–63 years of age). The data contains samples only of males due to issues related to self-selection biases into the workforce. Also, the measure of work experience is a more appropriate measure for males. Fig. 1 shows the measure of the emigrant supply shock—i.e. the ratio of emigrants to the workforce in Mexico, in aggregate and by schooling groups. In 1970, the emigrants constituted around 3% of the Mexican labor force and it increased to 11% in 1990 and 16% in 2000. The aggregate migration rates, however, mask a lot of variation by schooling. It is a wellknown fact that immigration has increased by the greatest proportion the supply of high school dropouts in the US (Borjas et al., 1997). However, there is a sharp contrast when we look at migration from the perspective of the source country. As shown in Fig. 1, the bigger proportionate losses are amongst the high school graduates and those with some college education. In 2000, Mexican emigrants with 12 years of schooling constituted 47% while emigrants with 13–15 years of schooling constituted about 52% of the corresponding labor force 9 The data used in this paper is publicly available at www.ipums.org. The earthquake of 1985 destroyed the Mexican Census agency computing facilities before a national microdata sample could be constructed from the 1980 enumeration. Fig. 1. HSD=High School Dropouts (less than 12 years of schooling), HSG=High School Graduates (12 years of schooling), SC=those with some college (13–15 years of schooling), CG=College Graduates (16 or more years of schooling). All the figures are for males in the labor force, who were not enrolled in school at the time of the Census, and have experience in the range of 1–40 years. An emigrant is defined as a person counted by the US census as being born in Mexico in a given year. Aworker in Mexico is defined as person counted by the Mexican Census as residing in Mexico in the same year and is a part of the labor force in Mexico. P. Mishra / Journal of Development Economics 82 (2007) 180–199184 in Mexico in the same schooling groups. In contrast, Mexican emigrants who are high school dropouts constituted only 16% of the corresponding labor force in Mexico. The reason is, though Mexican migrants are predominantly high school dropouts in absolute numbers, Mexico is so abundant in high school dropouts that the emigrant supply shock in the high school dropout category is relatively small. Around 80% of Mexican workers are high school dropouts whereas only about 12% have 12–15 years of schooling.10 An important issue in measuring emigration by schooling categories is where the emigrant acquired the education, in the US or in Mexico. The US census does not provide information on this. Even if this information were available, it is not clear what the counterfactual level of educational attainment of the migrant would have been, had he not migrated and whether his emigration could constitute shocks to the same schooling groups in Mexico. The strategy I follow in this paper is to exclude from the migrant sample those who are more likely to have got their schooling in the US. The literature on Mexican migration to the US (e.g., Grogger and Trejo, 2002; Gonzalez, 2002; Chiquiar and Hanson, 2005; Clark and Jaeger, 2002) provides strong evidence that those who arrive in late teens or later are less likely to complete high school in the US. Following Chiquiar and Hanson (2005), I exclude from the migrant sample individuals who were less than 17 years of age at the time of entry into the US.11 In the restricted migrant sample, there is a higher probability that these individuals got their schooling in Mexico. The emigrant supply shock (not shown) in the 12–15 years of schooling category remains high. In 2000, Mexican emigrants who are high school graduates constituted 31% while emigrants with some college education constituted 33% of the corresponding labor force in Mexico. Appendix Fig. 1 shows the emigrant supply shocks by schooling and experience. The emigrant sample excludes those who migrated as children, as defined above. The emigrant supply shocks are not balanced across experience groups within particular schooling categories. The central message is that there is variation in the emigrant supply shock across schooling and experience groups and over time that we can utilize to estimate the impact on Mexican wages. Fig. 2 shows the average real monthly earnings (nominal earnings deflated by Consumer Price Index from the International Financial Statistics) in Mexico. Between 1970 and 2000, the real wage in Mexico decreased both on average, as well as for each schooling group. 4. Results and interpretation 4.1. Basic regressions Table 1 shows the estimates of d, i.e. the effect of emigration on the wages in Mexico. There are 840 schooling-experience-time cells (7 schooling groups, 40 experience groups and 3 time periods). Specification I includes fixed effects for schooling (si), experience (vj) and time (pt). The estimate shown in column 1 is 0.33 (SE=0.06). Specification II includes the interactions of period fixed effects with the education and experience fixed effects, respectively. The interaction terms control for the changing wage structure for different schooling and age groups respectively over time. The estimate of d is 0.42 (SE=0.08) in Specification II. Specification III shows the 10 It is surprising that the emigrant supply shock in the college graduate category is very small. One possible reason could be that the highly educated Mexicans want to live in Mexico and consume the cheap non-traded goods and have a high standard of living. 11 The estimates of the effect of emigration on Mexican wages are robust to assuming higher cutoffs like 18, 19 or 21 years. P. Mishra / Journal of Development Economics 82 (2007) 180–199 185 estimates from the fully specified regression model with both the individual fixed effects as well as the pair-wise interactions between the vectors of fixed effects. The estimate of the impact of emigration, shown in the third column of Table 1, is 0.44 (SE=0.10).12 To summarize, the basic regressions indicate that there exists a positive, strong and statistically significant (at 1% level) relationship between emigration and Mexican wages. A 10% decrease in the supply of workers in any skill group due to emigration (where skill is defined by schooling and experience) increases the average wage in that skill group by about 4%.13 4.2. Using individual level data The estimates from the individual wage regressions are shown in Table 2. The explanatory variables include additional individual level controls that can affect wages—marital status, nativity (whether the person is born in Mexico or outside Mexico), occupation, industry, state and the interaction of these with the year dummy. The estimated coefficient is 0.31 (SE=0.06). This estimate is similar to that of the group level regressions in Table 1. The individual wage regression with additional regressors supports the result that emigration has a positive and strong effect on wages in Mexico.14 4.3. Self selection issues The estimates of impact of emigration on Mexican wages may be biased if the workers in Mexico constitute a non-random sample from the population. Selectivity bias may arise because 12 When four schooling categories are used instead of seven, the coefficient estimate in Specification III, Table 1 is 0.38 (SE=0.16). Fig. 2. The wages shown above are the average of the logarithm of real monthly earnings. Monthly earnings are deflated by the CPI from the IMF. The figures are for males, in the labor force, who are not enrolled in school, and have work experience of 1–40 years, and report positive monthly earnings. HSD=High School Dropouts, HSG=High School Graduates, SC=those with some college, CG=College Graduates. 13 I also estimate the model in differences. Regressing the difference in wages on difference in the emigrant supply shocks, controlling for schooling, experience and period effects gives an estimate of 0.37 (SE=0.09). 14 One concern is that of unemployment in Mexico. Surprisingly, the national unemployment rate in Mexico for males is about 1% (Source: Mexican Census, 2000. Unemployed are defined as those who are out of work and actively seeking work), much lower than that in the US. One reason for the low unemployment could be that there is no unemployment insurance program in the country. However, there could also be measurement errors or underemployment in Mexico that is not measured. P. Mishra / Journal of Development Economics 82 (2007) 180–199186 wages in Mexico are observed only for the selected workers who decide not to migrate. If the blowest abilityQ individuals are the most likely to migrate from every skill group, then the positive correlation between emigration and wages might not be due to the favorable impact of emigration on Mexican wages. Instead it could be due to the blowest abilityQ individuals leaving and raising the average wage in that skill group. It is difficult to ascertain who emigrates in terms of the unobserved characteristics from each skill group; hence it is difficult to predict the direction of the sample-selection bias. I follow one approach taken to address the classical sample selection problem encountered in estimating wage equations in the labor literature where the issue is that the wages are observed only when the individual decides to participate in the labor force. It is argued that the sample selection bias is less severe in a sub-sample of male workers whose labor force participation rates are very high, so that in this restricted sample, almost everyone participates in the labor force (Pencavel, 1986). Applying the same logic to the case of emigration, the analysis is undertaken for a subsample of Mexican workers who are least likely to emigrate implying that we would observe ballQ the individuals and not just the ones who decide not to migrate. In this sub-sample, it cannot be the case that those left behind in schooling-experience cells are different from those who emigrate from these cells simply because almost no one (or very few) emigrate from these cells. The literature on Mexican migration provides plenty of evidence that some states send more migrants than others due to long-standing regional networks. (The US census does not ask the migrant which state in Mexico does he/she comes from). Also there has been continuity in the state migration patterns over time (e.g., Woodruff and Zenteno, 2002; Massey and Espinoza, 1997). Woodruff and Zenteno (2002) estimate that the states in central-west Mexico have very high migration rates, with 10–15% of the households having an external migrant. There are eight states mostly in southeast Mexico, where 2% or less of the households have an external migrant. I estimate the impact of national emigrant supply shocks on wages of workers in the low migration states of Mexico. The assumption here is that the Mexican labor market is integrated at the margin, i.e. that the wage impact of emigration gets transmitted to the economy as a Table 1 Estimated effect of emigration on Mexican wages (1970–2000) Dependent variable: average real monthly earnings (in logs) in schooling-experience-time cell (i, j, t) in Mexico I II III Ratio of the number of emigrants to the workforce in Mexico in cell (i, j, t) 0.33*** (0.06) 0.42*** (0.08) 0.44*** (0.10) p-value 0.00 0.00 0.01 Schooling, experience and time fixed effects Yes Yes Yes Interaction between schooling and time fixed effects No Yes Yes Interaction between experience and time fixed effects No Yes Yes Interaction between schooling and experience fixed effects No No Yes There are 840 observations. The total number of schooling-experience-time cells is 7*40*3=840. The standard errors reported have been corrected for heteroskedasticity using White’s correction. The regressions are weighted by the number of workers in Mexico in schooling-experience-time cell. *** Indicates statistical significance at 1% level. An emigrant from Mexico in the United States is defined as a person whom the US Census records as being born in Mexico. A worker in Mexico is defined as a person who is counted by the Mexican Census as residing in Mexico in a given year and is a part of the labor force. P. Mishra / Journal of Development Economics 82 (2007) 180–199 187 whole.15 The regression model in (1) is estimated using the wages from the sample of workers from the low-migration states. The emigrant supply shocks are national shocks, as measured before. The results for the fully specified regression model are shown in Table 3. The estimates of the coefficient of emigration are positive and statistically significant (at 1% level) and similar to that in Table 1 when we consider the wages of the entire sample of workers in Mexico. The fact that the impact of emigrant supply shocks gets transmitted to the country as whole provides evidence that the results are not driven by sample selection but rather through supply effects that are transmitted throughout the integrated Mexican labor market.16 4.4. Endogeneity issues Another potential concern about the empirical strategy used for the estimations is the issue of endogeneity, i.e. the emigrant supply shock may be correlated with the unobserved component of wages. There is evidence that migration increases when wages decline in Mexico (Hanson and Spilimbergo, 1999; Hanson et al., 2001). If lower wages lead to increased emigration then the estimated coefficient on emigration would be an underestimate of the impact of emigration on Mexican wages. To check the robustness of the results, I use an instrumental variable strategy. An ideal instrument should be exogenous to the wages in Mexico and should be strongly correlated with emigration. The sociology literature argues that an important factor driving US–Mexico migration is social capital i.e. social connections to the US migrants (Massey and Espinoza, Table 2 Estimated effect of emigration on Mexican wages—individual wage regressions (1970–2000) Dependent variable: log real monthly earnings of individual workers in Mexico Ratio of the number of emigrants to the workforce in Mexico in the individual worker’s schooling-experience-time cell 0.31*** (0.06) p-value 0.00 Experience, experience squared, dummies for schooling, year, interaction of year dummy with schooling dummy and experience Yes Dummies for marital status, nativity, occupation, industry, state, interaction of year dummy with marital status, nativity, occupation, industry, state Yes Number of observations 321,346 R2 0.46 The standard errors are adjusted for clustering at schooling-experience-time level. *** Indicates statistical significance at 1% level. The principal regressor ratio of emigrants to workforce in Mexico measures the emigrant supply shock in the individual worker’s schooling-experience-time cell. This is a group variable and is the same for all the individuals in the same schooling-experience-time cell. The data on Mexican wages are from a 1% random sample of the Mexican population in 1970, 1990 and 2000. 16 One potential concern is that lower ability individuals may be migrating internally. However, there is not much evidence for internal migration within Mexico. For 80% of the individuals in the sample, the state of current residence is the state of residence 5 years ago (see also Hanson, 2003). The wage impact could be transmitted to the country as a whole through movement of goods, capital or labor. It is not necessary that there should be perfect mobility of labor. How are wage impacts transmitted throughout the country, is an interesting question. However, given the dataset, addressing this question is beyond the scope of the paper and would be an interesting area for future research. 15 It is important to note that I am looking at wage adjustments over very long periods of time (10 or 20 years span). Robertson (2000a) also provides evidence for co-movement of wages between the interior and border regions of Mexico. Chiquiar (2003) finds that for the period 1970–1985, there was convergence in per capita state GDP levels across US states. P. Mishra / Journal of Development Economics 82 (2007) 180–199188 1997). Each migrant creates additional social capital capable of sustaining further migration. I apply this idea and use a measure of networks as an instrument for the emigrant supply shock. Networks are usually based on relatives and friends where schooling and occupation are similar. I use lagged migration rates by schooling as a measure of social networks.17 The correlation between the past and current emigrant supply measures is high, around 0.8. The results of the instrumental variable regressions are shown in Table 4. The IV regressions are implemented using the individual wage specification. Specification I includes wages from the full sample of Mexican workers as the dependent variable. Specification II includes the wages of only workers from low migration states. In Specification II, both the concerns— sample-selection and endogeneity, are addressed together. The IV regressions do not include dummies for schooling. This is a necessary identification assumption to use past migration rates by schooling as instrument. The first stage regression (not shown) indicates a significant and positive relationship between the past and current emigrant supply shocks. In the first stage regression, the coefficient of the lagged emigrant supply shock is 1.0 (SE=0.0) and the R2 =0.7. The second stage IV estimate (shown in Table 4) is about 0.3–0.4 (SE=0.1). The IV estimate of 0.42 in Table 4 (Specification I) is higher than the non-IV regression estimate of 0.31 (see Table 2). To summarize, the instrumental variable regression results support that emigration has a large and positive effect of on Mexican wages. 4.5. How long do the labor supply shocks last? In the empirical exercise above, the emigrants are grouped into schooling-experience cells irrespective of how long ago they left Mexico. The emigrant supply shocks are assumed to be Table 3 Estimated effect of emigration on Mexican wages—sample selection (1970–2000) Dependent variable: average real monthly earnings (in logs) in schooling-experience-time cell (i, j, t) of workers in Mexico from low-migration states I II III Ratio of the number of emigrants to the workforce in Mexico in cell (i, j, t) 0.32*** (0.10) 0.54*** (0.11) 0.54*** (0.13) p-value 0.00 0.00 0.00 Schooling, experience and time fixed effects Yes Yes Yes Interaction between schooling and time fixed effects No Yes Yes Interaction between experience and time fixed effects No Yes Yes Interaction between schooling and experience fixed effects No No Yes There are 840 observations. The total number of schooling-experience-time cells is 7*40*3=840. The standard errors reported have been corrected for heteroskedasticity using White’s correction. The regressions are weighted by the number of workers in Mexico in schooling-experience time cell (i, j, t). *** Indicates statistical significance at 1% level. The wages are only for workers in eight low migration states of Baja California Sur, Campeche, Chiapas, Distrito Federal, Quintana Roo, Sonora, Tabasco and Yucatan. The emigrant supply shocks are national emigrant supply shocks for Mexico as a whole. 17 Network connections based on experience may not be very plausible. However, IVestimate is higher if past migration rate by schooling and experience is used as instrument. One potential concern with using lagged explanatory variable as instrument is that if the dependent variable is correlated over time, then the instrument may not be exogenous. However, this is less of a concern here because I am using data over very long periods of time. The concern would be more severe if I were using high frequency data. P. Mishra / Journal of Development Economics 82 (2007) 180–199 189 permanent. One possibility is that the shocks persist for a shorter duration. The question that follows is how long do the shocks last, and whether the entire stock of emigrants should affect wages in Mexico, even when some of them have been out of the country for two or three decades. In order to address this concern, I break up the emigrant supply shock into two parts. The emigrant sample is divided into (i) recent emigrants defined as those who emigrated in the last decade—the 1990 emigrant sample is restricted to those who emigrated between 1980 and 1990, and the 2000 emigrant sample is restricted to those who emigrated between 1990 and 2000, and (ii) those whose emigrated more than a decade back—the 1990 emigrant sample is restricted to those who emigrated before 1980, and the 2000 emigrant sample is restricted to those who emigrated before 1990. I run an alternative empirical specification given by: wijt ¼ dSRmSR ijt þ dLRmLR ijt þ si þ vj þ pt þ si4pt þ si4vj þ ej þ eijt ð3Þ where mSR ijt u MSR ijt Nijt ; mLR ijt u MLR ijt Nijt M SR ijt =number of emigrants who migrated in the last decade, M lR ijt =number of emigrants who migrated more than a decade back. dSR can be termed as the bshort-runQ effect and dlR can be termed as the blong-runQ effect of emigration on wages. The results are shown in Table 5, column I. Since the sample of emigrants in 1970 is small, I do not include 1970 in the analysis. The estimated short-run effect is 0.34, and it is statistically significant at 1% level ( p-value=0.00). The estimated long-run effect is 0.53 ( p-value=0.00). The significant long run effect suggests that the effect of emigration on wages tends to persist and does not die out over time. For comparison, the estimates obtained when all emigrants are included in one measure, are shown in column II. The coefficient is 0.42 ( p-value=0.00), it lies in between the short-run and the long run effect, and can be termed as the baverage effectQ of emigration on wages. The basic empirical specifications used in the paper essentially capture this baverage effectQ. Table 4 Estimated effect of emigration on Mexican wages—instrumental variable (1990–2000) Dependent variable: Log real monthly earnings of individual workers in Mexico in 1990 and 2000 I II Full Sample of workers in Mexico Restricted sub-sample of workers from low migration states in Mexico Emigrant supply shock in 1990 and 2000 in the worker’s schooling-experience group instrumented with emigrant supply shock in 1970, 1990 in the worker’s schooling group 0.42*** (0.09) 0.32*** (0.09) p-value 0.00 0.00 Number of observations 261,246 59,764 R2 0.36 0.42 The standard errors are adjusted for clustering at schooling-experience-time level. *** Indicates statistical significance at 1% level. In the first stage regression, emigrant supply shock in 1990 and 2000 in a worker’s skill group is regressed on lagged emigrant supply shocks in 1970 and 1990 in the worker’s schooling group. The coefficient of lagged emigration is 1.00 and 0.97 (SE=0.0) in specifications I and II, respectively, and the R2 of the first stage regressions in both the specifications is 0.7. The first and second stage regressions include experience, experience squared, dummies for year, nativity, marital status, occupation, industry, state, and interactions of the year dummies with experience, nativity, marital status, occupation, industry and state. P. Mishra / Journal of Development Economics 82 (2007) 180–199190 4.6. Additional robustness checks 4.6.1. Alternative categories of experience To check for the robustness of the results I also allow for alternative experience categories. The workers are divided into eight instead of forty categories as used in the earlier analysis (Table 1). The idea behind having broader experience groups is to allow for the possibility of non-independence of earnings in adjacent schooling-experience cells, which could be a source of bias in the standard errors. The results are shown in Appendix Table 1 (column I). The estimate when broader experience groups are used is much higher than the basic regressions in Table 1, when work experience was divided into finer categories. One possible reason could be that there is measurement error in the emigrant supply shock when using finer experience categories, which leads to attenuation bias in the estimates. Using broader experience categories reduces the measurement error. 4.6.2. Labor demand shocks The aim of the paper is to isolate the impact of emigration, controlling for other variables that are correlated with emigration and affect wages. If there are labor demand shocks that are correlated with emigration and drive up the wages, then the estimates will be biased. Two possible sources of labor demand shocks are technology shocks and capital flows. However, based on the identification strategy used in the paper, shocks correlated with both emigration and wages, which are not controlled for in the framework must be skill (schooling and experience) specific, and must vary at the schooling-experience-time level. Other shocks are controlled for by the fixed effects and the two-way interactions specified in Eq. (1). Positive technological shocks and capital flows to particular schooling-experience cells would increase labor demand. This would increase wages and thus discourage emigration implying that emigration is negatively correlated with the unobserved component of wages. Hence the positive estimates would be biased downwards. In this case, the true effect of emigration on wages would be bigger in magnitude than the estimated effect. However, if there exist technology shocks, which are positively correlated with emigration, then this would imply that the impact of emigration on wages is overestimated and raise serious Table 5 Estimated effect of emigration on Mexican wages (1990–2000): alternative definition of emigrant supply shocks I II Emigrant supply shock with recent migrants (who came within the last 10 years) 0.34*** (0.08) p-value 0.00 Emigrant supply shock with those migrants who have been out of the country for more than a decade 0.53*** (0.10) p-value 0.00 Emigrant supply shock with all emigrants included 0.42*** (0.08) p-value 0.00 Number of observations 560 560 The standard errors reported have been corrected for heteroskedasticity using White’s correction. The regressions are weighted by the number of workers in Mexico in schooling-experience time cell (i, j, t). *** Indicates statistical significance at 1% level. The regressions include fixed effects for schooling, experience, time and all the two-way interactions. P. Mishra / Journal of Development Economics 82 (2007) 180–199 191 concerns. For example, there could be positively correlated labor demand shocks in the US and Mexican labor markets that raise labor demand and wages in Mexico but also attract Mexican migrants to the US. To address this concern, I control for average wages in the US in the schooling-experience-time cell in Appendix Table 1, column II. The estimate of the coefficient of emigration is similar to those in the basic specifications. I also control for the average wage of Mexican migrants in the US in the schooling-experience-time cell. Wages of migrants can be considered as a proxy for remittances as well. The coefficient on emigration (not shown) is similar to that shown in Appendix Table 1, column II. 4.6.3. Undercount of illegal migrants Another issue is that of undercount of illegal migrants in the US census. To correct for the undercount, I make adjustments to the measure of emigrant supply shock making the following two assumptions: (i) all illegal migrants are high school dropouts (ii) that the Census undercounts by 15% or 30% the number of emigrants in each of the schooling-experience cells with high school dropouts in the age group of 26–45 (or 9–28 years of experience) (Costanzo et al., 2001; Jorda´n and Tera´n, 1996). The basic regression model in (1) is estimated by revising the number of emigrants by the estimates of the undercount. The estimates (shown in Appendix Table 1, columns III and IV) are similar to the estimates in Table 1. Thus, the results are robust to the undercount of illegal migrants. 4.6.4. Cross skill effects The empirical specification in (1) does not control for emigration in other skill categories. To allow for cross-effects, I augment the empirical specification in (1) to allow for emigration in other schooling categories (in the same experience group). The coefficient of emigration in the own schooling-experience cell is constrained to be the same for all schooling groups. The regression model is specified as: wijt ¼ dmijt þ X s p1 dsmsjt þ si þ vj þ pt þ si4pt þ vj4pt þ si4vj þ eijt ð4Þ where msjt is the ratio of emigrants to workers in Mexico in the schooling group s, s p i, experience cell j, at time t. The estimates (shown in Appendix Table 1, column V) of the owneffect (d) are positive and statistically significant (at least at 5% level), and the magnitude is similar to those in Table 1. Additionally, I also control for emigration in two closest experience groups in the same schooling groups, using the individual wage specification. The estimate of the own-effect (not shown) is positive, statistically significant and similar to the estimates in Table 2. To summarize, controlling for emigration in other schooling groups and experience cells, reinforces the strong and positive own-effect of emigration in a particular skill group on wages in that skill group. 4.6.5. Additional specification checks Appendix Table 2 shows some additional specification checks. Column I shows the result when the regressions in Table 1 are not weighted by the number of Mexican workers in the skill group. Column II shows the results when both males and females are included in the measurement of the emigrant supply shock. Column III controls for the number of Mexican workers in the schooling-experience-time cell to address the concern that changes in the size of the Mexican workforce due to reasons other than emigration could be driving the results. P. Mishra / Journal of Development Economics 82 (2007) 180–199192 Column IV shows the result when the migrant sample excludes those who migrated at less than 21 years of age to increase the likelihood that the migrants got their schooling back in Mexico. The estimates in all these specifications remain positive and statistically significant and comparable to the estimates in Table 1. 5. Implications of the results There are at least two key quantifiable implications of the impact of emigration on real wages. First, the variation across schooling groups has implications for wage inequality within Mexico. Secondly, the estimated elasticity can be used to compute simple welfare measures based on a standard partial equilibrium model of labor demand and labor supply. 5.1. Implications for wage inequality Since the mid-1980s, Mexico has experienced a widening wage inequality and this has been attributed mainly to an increase in relative demand for skill owing to trade and investment liberalization in Mexico (Hanson, 2003; Robertson, 2000b; Hanson and Harrison, 1999; Feenstra and Hanson, 1997; Cragg and Epelbaum, 1996). This section focuses on an alternative channel—the impact of emigration on wage inequality. The estimates of the effect of emigration on wages (Table 1) can be used to calculate the wage impact in different schooling groups. The estimate of 0.4 implies that a 10% decrease in the supply of workers owing to emigration in a particular schooling-experience group increases the wages in that group by 4%. To estimate the wage impact of emigration in a particular schooling category, we have to aggregate the impact in all experience cells within that schooling category. The Ideal Log Change Index Number measures the percentage change in unit labor costs between two time periods. Following Sato (1976), the bIdeal Log Change Index NumberQ, or the change in log wage for schooling group S between 1970 and 2000, can be expressed as: DlnwS;2000À70 ¼ X j /jSDlnwSj;2000À70 ð5Þ Where /jS is the weight for experience cell ( j) within a schooling group (S), consistent with the CES production function and can be expressed as: /jS ¼ DEjS=DEjS P j DEjS=DEjS À Á ð6Þ Where EjS is the earning share of experience group j in total earnings in schooling group S, DEjS =EjS,2000 ÀEjS,1970, DEjS =logEjS,2000 ÀlogEjS,1970. Using the estimated impact of emigration on wages (Specification III in Table 1), and using (5) and (6), emigration between 1970 and 2000 increased the wages of high school dropouts by 5%, of high school graduates by 15%, those with some college education by 13%, and of college graduates by around 2%. Aggregating the wage impact over the schooling groups, the emigrant outflow between 1970 and 2000 increased the wage of the average Mexican worker by 8%. It is useful to look at the estimated increase in wages due to emigration between 1990 and 2000 because the Mexican Census data shows increasing wage inequality during this period. As shown in Fig. 3, between 1990 and 2000, the relative wages of high school graduates increased by 11%, of P. Mishra / Journal of Development Economics 82 (2007) 180–199 193 those with some college education by 21% and of college graduates by 8% (relative to high school dropouts). Using (5) and (6), the outflow of workers between 1990 and 2000 increased the relative wages of high school graduates by 4% and those with some college education by 3% (relative to high school dropouts). Thus, the estimated impact of emigration accounts for approximately 37% of the increase in relative wages of high school graduates and 14% of the increase in relative wages of those with some college education. The greater impact of emigration on wages of workers with 12–15 years of schooling is driven by the fact that this group exhibits the highest emigration rates given that we assume constant labor demand elasticity across schooling groups.18 Emigration does not explain the increase in relative wages of college graduates. The magnitude of the positive effect of emigration on the wages of high school dropouts is higher than that on the wages of college graduates; hence emigration leads to a decrease in the relative wage of college graduates. Since emigration does not explain the entire rise in wage inequality, it should be considered as a complementary explanation for the rising wage inequality in Mexico. Emigration as a channel to explain increasing wage inequality in developing countries has received little attention in the literature (Robbins, 2002). The estimates in the case of Mexico suggest that it could potentially be an important factor. 5.2. Welfare implications In this section, I use the estimated impact of emigration on Mexican wages to compute simple welfare measures based on the standard textbook model of labor demand and supply. The simple economic model of labor demand and supply is an important starting point to quantify the welfare implications and has been used in the literature in the context of immigration and capital flows (Borjas, 1995; MacDougall, 1960). The calculations in this paper differ in one important Fig. 3. The figures are for males, in the labor force, who are not enrolled in school, and have work experience of 1–40 years, and report positive monthly earnings. HSD=High School Dropouts, HSG=High School Graduates, SC=those with some college, CG=College Graduates. Relative wages are measured by the ratio of the real monthly earnings in schooling category s (s =HSG, SC, CG) to the real monthly earnings of HSD. Monthly earnings are deflated by the CPI from the IMF. 18 I also allow for different coefficients across schooling categories. However, only experience and period fixed effects can be included in these regressions (and not their interactions). The estimates are imprecise but the effect is much higher in the higher schooling categories. One possible reason for the small effect in the lower schooling category could be unemployment. P. Mishra / Journal of Development Economics 82 (2007) 180–199194 aspect from that of the gains from immigration that exist in the literature. Prior work calculates the impact based on the estimates of labor demand elasticity drawn from studies unrelated to migration. This paper uses the elasticity of wages with respect to emigration estimated from the Mexican data to do the calculations. Welfare is measured by GDP accruing to those who have stayed behind (TSB) in Mexico. Consider a single good which is the numeraire and its production function is given as: Q ¼ F K; Lð Þ ð7Þ Where K is the fixed factor assumed to be internationally immobile, L is the labor employed in production and Q is the gross domestic product. Fig. 4 shows the simple model of labor demand and supply. The initial equilibrium wage is w0. A large emigration flow of a magnitude M of workers reduces the labor force from (N +M) to N. Wage rate as a result increases from w0 to w1. The workers who have stayed behind gain an area equal to w0w1ab (rectangle region A), owners of the fixed factors in the economy lose an area equal to w0w1ac (rectangle region A +triangle region B) and the country as a whole loses the triangle abc (region B). The triangle abc (region B) can be termed as the bemigration lossQ. As a fraction of the post-emigration GDP: Emigration loss ðtriangle B in Fig: 4Þ ¼ 1=2ð Þsem2 ð8Þ Gain to workers who have stayed behind ðrectangle A in Fig: 4Þ ¼ sem ð9Þ Loss of the owners of fixed factors ðA þ B in Fig: 4Þ ¼ 1 2 sem2 þ sem ð10Þ Where e ¼ eLLjL¼N ¼ Dw DL N w, s ¼ wN wNþrK, m ¼ M N , s is the share of labor in GDP, e is the percent change in wages due to a 1% change in the labor force, where the elasticity is measured at the post-emigration labor-force and m is the ratio of emigrants to the workforce in Mexico. The expressions in (8)–(10) are analogous to Borjas (1995) study of immigration. The emigration loss and distributive impact as a result of the flow of workers between 1970 and 2000 can be estimated using (8)–(10). From Section 5.1, the estimated change in wages of a Fig. 4. Effect of immigration on wages—labor demand–supply model. P. Mishra / Journal of Development Economics 82 (2007) 180–199 195 typical worker in Mexico due to flow of emigrants between 1970 and 2000 (e*m) is around 8%. The assumed share of labor income in GDP (s) is 0.7 (Borjas, 1995, 2003; Hall and Jones, 1999).19 The emigrant share of the Mexican workforce (m) estimated from the 2000 Mexican and US censuses is about 16% (including men and women).20 The estimated emigration loss to Mexico is about 0.5% of Mexico’s GDP in 2000. The economic loss from emigration in a $580 billion economy is about $3 billion per year. The gain to the workers who have stayed behind is about 5.9% of GDP and the loss to the owners of the fixed factors is about 6.4% of GDP, the difference being the estimated aggregate economic loss to Mexico. Thus, the estimated distributive impact is about 12–13 times the aggregate economic loss to Mexico. 6. Conclusion This paper presents the first attempt in the literature to estimate the effect of emigration on the national wages in a source country. The main result in the paper is that there is a strong and positive relationship between emigration and wages in Mexico. The impact of emigration on wages has important implications for wage inequality across schooling groups and for national income distribution between labor and other factors (which are assumed to be immobile in this paper). The measured welfare impact on who have stayed behind in the sending country is based on the very simple static partial equilibrium framework. There may be other counteracting forces like the impact on human capital formation, positive external effects through networks and diaspora, remittances, etc., that can outweigh this loss and result in a net benefit to the source country. Also, if Mexico has some market power in the world market, emigration may affect terms of trade of Mexico. Quantifying these additional channels through which emigration can affect the welfare of Mexican workers who have stayed behind, is a subject for further research. Acknowledgements This paper is a part of my PhD dissertation at Columbia University. I am deeply indebted to Donald Davis and David Weinstein for their guidance and support. I am also grateful to Ronald Findlay, Jagdish Bhagwati, Rajeev Dehejia, Francisco Rivera-Batiz, Gordon Hanson, George Borjas, Stanley Fischer, David Autor, Joseph Tracy, Albert Fishlow, Sanjay Reddy, Miguel Urquiola, Cristian Pop-Eleches, Till Von Wachter, Lena Edlund, Cordelia Reimers, Rohini Pande, Ratna Sahay, David O. Robinson, Paul Cashin, two anonymous referees and seminar participants at Columbia, Yale, World Bank, IADB, FRB Boston and the IMF for comments and discussions. I also wish to thank the University of Minnesota Historical Census Projects team, Steven Ruggles and Matthew Sobek et al. (Integrated Public Use Microdata team Series: Version 3.0 University of Minnesota, 2003) for helping me with the data from the US and Mexican Censuses. All errors are mine. 20 The elasticity estimate used in the welfare calculations is from Table 1 (when only men are included in the analysis). However, the estimate is very similar when women are included as well (Appendix Table 2, column II). 19 According to Mexico’s national accounts, labor share of GDP is about 0.35; this figure seems to be highly underestimated. However, the welfare results are qualitatively unchanged under the alternative estimate of the labor share. P. Mishra / Journal of Development Economics 82 (2007) 180–199196 Appendix Appendix Fig. 1. Emigrant supply shock—by schooling and experience. The emigrant supply shock is defined as the ratio of Mexican-born emigrants in the US to the workforce in Mexico. The estimates are for males, in the labor force, who are not enrolled in school, and have work experience of 1–40 years. The emigrant sample excludes those who migrated at an age of less than 17 years. Appendix Table 1 Robustness checks I II III IV V 8 experience groups Controlling for average wages in the US in schooling experience time cell 15% undercount of illegal migrants in the Census 30% undercount of illegal migrants in the Census Controlling for cross-schooling effects Ratio of emigrants to the workforce in Mexico 1.1** (0.48) 0.38** (0.16) 0.42*** (0.15) 0.45*** (0.15) 0.31** (0.16) p-value 0.03 0.02 0.01 0.00 0.05 The standard errors reported have been corrected for heteroskedasticity using White’s correction. The regressions are weighted by the number of workers in Mexico in schooling-experience time cell (i, j, t). ***, ** and * indicate statistical significance at 1%, 5% and 10% levels, respectively. All regressions include fixed effects for schooling, experience, time and all the two-way interactions. P. Mishra / Journal of Development Economics 82 (2007) 180–199 197 References Altonji, J., Card, D., 1991. The effects of immigration on the labor market outcomes of less-skilled natives. In: Abowd, J., Freeman, R. (Eds.), Immigration, Trade, and the Labor Market. University of Chicago Press, Chicago, IL, pp. 201–234. Bhagwati, J.N., Hamada, K., 1974. The brain drain, international integration of markets for professionals and unemployment: a theoretical analysis. Journal of Development Economics 1 (1), 19–42. Borjas, G.J., 1994. The economics of immigration. Journal of Economic Literature 32 (4), 1667–1717. Borjas, G.J., 1995. The economic benefits of immigration. Journal of Economic Perspectives 9 (2), 3–22. Borjas, G.J., 2003. The labor demand curve is downward sloping: reexamining the impact of immigration on the labor market. Quarterly Journal of Economics 118 (4), 1335–1374. Borjas, G.J., Freeman, R.B., Katz, L.F., 1997. How much do immigration and trade affect labor market outcomes? Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1–67. Boyer, G.R., Hatton, T.J., O’Rourke, K., 1994. Impact of emigration on real wages in Ireland, 1850–1914. In: Hatton, Timothy J., Williamson, Jeffrey G. (Eds.), Migration and the International Labor Market, 1850–1939. Routledge, London, pp. 221–239. Chiquiar, D., 2003. Essays on the Regional Implications of Globalization: The Case of Mexico Ph.D. Dissertation, University of California, San Diego. Chiquiar, D., Hanson, G.H., 2005. International migration, self-selection, and the distribution of wages: evidence from Mexico and the United States. Journal of Political Economy 113 (2), 239–281. Clark, M., Jaeger, D.A., 2002. Natives, the Foreign Born and High School Equivalents: New Evidence on Returns to the GED. Working Paper #462 Princeton University Industrial Relations Section. Costanzo, J., Davis, C., Irazi, C., Goodkind, D., Ramirez, R., 2001. Evaluating Components of International Migration: The Residual Foreign Born Population. U.S. Bureau of the Census, Division Working Paper #. 61. Cragg, M.I., Epelbaum, M., 1996. Why has wage dispersion grown in Mexico? Is it the incidence of reforms or the growing demand for skills? Journal of Development Economics 51, 99–116. Davis, D.R., Weinstein, D.E., 2002. Technological superiority and losses from migration. NBER Working Paper 8971. Feenstra, R., Hanson, G., 1997. Foreign direct investment and relative wages: evidence from Mexico’s Maquiladoras. Journal of International Economics 42 (3–4), 371–393. Friedberg, R.M., 2001. The impact of mass migration on the Israeli labor market. Quarterly Journal of Economics 116 (4), 1373–1408. Friedberg, R.M., Hunt, J., 1995. The impact of immigrants on host country wages, employment and growth. Journal of Economic Perspectives 9 (2), 23–44. Gonzalez, A., 2002. bIs the Education of Child Immigrants Affected by Their Age at Arrival? Findings and Policy ImplicationsQ. Mimeo. Grogger, J., Trejo, S.J., 2002. Falling Behind or Moving Up? The Intergenerational Progress of Mexican Americans. Public Institute of California, San Francisco. Hall, R., Jones, C.I., 1999. Why do some countries produce so much output per worker than others? Quarterly Journal of Economics 114 (1), 83–116. Appendix Table 2 Additional specification checks I II III IV Unweighted Females included Size of the Mexican workforce (in logs) as additional regressor Age at arrival of the emigrants restricted to 21 years or more Ratio of emigrants to the workforce in Mexico 0.35** (0.16) 0.30** (0.14) 0.33** (0.16) 0.55* (0.29) p-value 0.03 0.03 0.03 0.06 The standard errors reported have been corrected for heteroskedasticity using White’s correction. The regressions, except in column I, are weighted by the number of workers in Mexico in schooling-experience-time cell (i, j, t). ** and * indicate statistical significance at 5% and 10% levels, respectively. All regressions include fixed effects for schooling, experience, time and all the two-way interactions. P. Mishra / Journal of Development Economics 82 (2007) 180–199198 Hanson, G.H., 2003.What Has Happened to Wages in Mexico since NAFTA? NBER WP # W9563. Hanson, G.H., Harrison, A., 1999. Trade liberalization and wage inequality in Mexico. Industrial and Labor Relations Review 52 (2), 271–288. Hanson, G.H., Spilimbergo, A., 1999. Illegal immigration, border enforcement and relative wages: evidence from apprehensions at the U.S.–Mexico Border. American Economic Review 89, 1337–1357. Hanson, G.H., Scheve, K.F., Slaughter, M.J., Spilimbergo, A., 2001. Immigration and the US economy: labor market impact, illegal entry and policy choices. In: Boeri, T., Hanson, G.H., McCormick, B. (Eds.), Immigration Policy and the Welfare State. Oxford University Press. Hanson, G.H., Robertson, R., Spilimbergo, A., 2002. Does border enforcement protect U.S. workers from illegal immigration? The Review of Economics and Statistics 84 (1), 74–92. International Monetary Fund, 2000. Balance of Payment Statistics Yearbook. Jorda´n, A., Tera´n, M., 1996. Profiles of Illegal Border Crossers. San Diego Dialogue. Lucas, R.E., 1987. Emigration to South Africa’s mines. American Economic Review 77, 313–330. MacDougall, G.D.A., 1960. The benefits and costs of private investment from abroad. Economic Record 36, 13–35. Mahmood, Z., 1991. Emigration and wages in an open economy: some evidence from Pakistan. Pakistan Development Review 30, 243–262. Massey, D.S., Espinoza, K.E., 1997. What’s driving Mexico–US migration? A theoretical, empirical and policy analysis. American Journal of Sociology 102 (4), 939–999. O’Rourke, K.H., Williamson, J.G., 1999. Mass migrations: impacts on labor markets, home and abroad. Globalization and History: The Evolution of a Nineteenth Century Atlantic Economy. MIT, Cambridge. Pencavel, J., 1986. Labor supply of men: a survey. In: Ashenfelter, O., Layard, R. (Eds.), Handbook of Labor Economics, vol. 1. North Holland, Amsterdam, pp. 3–44. Quibria, M.G., 1989. International migration and real wages: is there any neo-classical ambiguity? Journal of Development Economics 31 (1), 177–183. Rivera-Batiz, F.L., 1989. The impact of international migration on real wages: another look. Journal of Development Economics 31 (1), 185–192. Robbins, D., 2002. The Impact of Trade Liberalization upon Inequality in Developing Countries — A Review of Theory and Evidence. Mimeo. Robertson, R., 2000a. Wage shocks and labor market integration. American Economic Review 90 (4), 742–764. Robertson, R., 2000b. Trade liberalization and wage inequality: lessons from the mexican experience. World Economy 23 (6), 827–849. Sato, K., 1976. The ideal log-change index number. The Review of Economics and Statistics 58 (2), 223–228. Stalker, P., 1994. The Work of Strangers: A Survey of International Labor Migration. ILO. Woodruff, C., Zenteno, R., 2002. Remittances and Micro enterprises in Mexico. UCSD, Graduate School of International Relations and Pacific Studies (IR/PS) Working Paper. Zhu, S., Trefler, D., 2005. Trade and wages in developing countries: catch up as a catalyst. Journal of International Economics 65, 21–48. P. Mishra / Journal of Development Economics 82 (2007) 180–199 199