Laboratory Evidence on the Effectiveness of Corporate Leniency Programs Author(s): Jeroen Hinloopen and Adriaan R. Soetevent Source: The RAND Journal of Economics, Vol. 39, No. 2 (Summer, 2008), pp. 607-616 Published by: Wiley on behalf of RAND Corporation Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/25474385 . Accessed: 21/11/2014 06:57 Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at . http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp . JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org. . Wiley and RAND Corporation are collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to The RAND Journal of Economics. http://www.jstor.org This content downloaded from 147.251.185.140 on Fri, 21 Nov 2014 06:57:35 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions RAND JournalofEconomics Vol. 39,No. 2, Summer2008 pp. 607-616 Laboratory evidence on the effectiveness of corporate leniency programs Jeroen Hinloopen* and Adriaan R. Soetevent** The number of cartels detected in theUnited States and inEurope has increased considerably since the introductionof corporate leniencyprograms inantitrust legislation. It cannot, however, be ruled out that thisapparent success results inpart from increased cartel activity.We explore theeffectsof corporate leniencyprograms onpricing and cartel activityby use of an experiment. Wefind that in the lab (i)fewer cartels are established when a leniencyprogram is inplace, and (ii) cartels thatdo exist are less successful in chargingprices above thestaticNash equilibrium price and have lower survival rates. 1. Introduction Corporate leniency programs have become an increasingly important tool for antitrust authorities to break cartels. These programs provide fine reductions and/or rewards for reporting a cartel toantitrustauthorities by one of thecartelmembers. The firstsuch programwas initiated by theU.S. Department of Justice in 1978. Since then, they have become part of antitrust legislation intheUnited States, theEuropean Union, and other countries (OECD, 2002; Spagnolo, forthcoming). The number of cartels detected has increased considerably since the introductionof leniency programs, but "in principle this could even be due to an increase in cartel activity" (Spagnolo, 2004). The reason for this is thatalong with the enhanced incentive to cheat on a cartelwhile simultaneously reporting it, leniency programs can also make cartel activity less costly for *Universiteit van Amsterdam and Katholieke Universiteit Leuven; j.hinloopen@uva.nl. **Universiteit van Amsterdam; a.r.soetevent@uva.nl. The comments of Philip Haile (the editor) and of two anonymous referees substantially improved thequality of the article. We furthergratefully acknowledge valuable comments fromMichiel Bijlsma, Cory Capps, Stephen Martin, Jose Luis Moraga-Gonzalez, Theo Offerman, Michael Price, Arno Riedl, Joep Sonnemans, Giancarlo Spagnolo, Charles Thomas, and seminar participants theUniversity ofAmsterdam (CREED), Copenhagen Business School, Katholieke Universiteit Leuven, 2005 EARIE meeting in Porto, and the 2006 ASSA meetings and 2006 IOS meeting, both held inBoston. We thank Jos Theelen for developing the software. Financial support of the Economics Network forCompetition and Regulation (ENCORE) is gratefully acknowledged. Soetevent's research was supported by a grant from the Program of Fellowships for Junior Scholars of theMacArthur Research Network on Social Interactions and Economic Inequality. The usual disclaimer applies. Copyright ? 2008, RAND. 607 This content downloaded from 147.251.185.140 on Fri, 21 Nov 2014 06:57:35 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions 608 / THE RAND JOURNALOF ECONOMICS participants. This occurs when cartel profitsnet of reduced fine payments exceed both defection and expected cartel profits.When thishappens, toomany cartelmembers are given excessive fine reductions upon reporting,and cartels are formed and reported continuously. Leniency programs with thisfeatureare called exploitable (Spagnolo, 2004). So itremains an open question whether thedramatic increase in leniency applications isproof of theirsuccess infightingcartels ormerely reflects increased cartel activitydue to theirconditions having become too generous. To answer thisquestion, empirical evidence on the effectsof leniency programs would be most welcome. This typeof evidence, however, ishard tocome by because informationon cartels not yet disclosed is typicallynot available. Moreover, natural experiments do not easily present themselves, as it is not feasible to adjust legislation too often.lWith a laboratory experiment, however, one can study theeffectsof leniencyprograms on thewillingness of subjects to engage in (nonbinding) price discussions and on themarket prices thatresult. Here we reporton four treatmentsof an experiment that implements such a setup and that follow up and extend thework ofApesteguia et al. (2007). In each treatment,subjects repeatedly play a discrete homogeneous-goods Bertrand pricing game ingroups of three.This game has been introducedbyDufwenberg andGneezy (2000). In each period, subjects have tochoose an integer in the range 101-110. Subjects who choose the lowest number (price) p receive net earnings of (p ? 100)/L, with L equal to thenumber of subjects choosing the lowest number. This lowest number is labeled themarket price. Any price above themarket price yields no revenue. The Nash equilibrium price of theone-shot game ispN = 101. The treatmentsdiffer in theoptions of subjects tohave nonbinding price discussions prior toamarket phase inwhich theactual price is determined. In comparing behavior andmarket outcomes across treatments,we study theeffects of corporate leniencyprograms on pricing, cartel activity,and cartel stability. One notion of cartel activity considers all situationswhere noncompetitive prices (p > 101) occur as collusive. This notion is consistentwith models of tacit collusion with homogeneous products. Apesteguia et al. (2007) apply a differentnotion by defining a cartel as the situation when all groupmembers unanimously decide todiscuss prices. This latternotion ismore in line with current legal practice thatfirms are unlikely to be found guilty of collusion when there have not been explicit attempts by thefirms involved to communicate with each other (Motta, 2004). In our analysis, we consider both notions of cartel stability.Our evidence shows a positive relationship between having price discussions and theoccurrence of noncompetitive prices, and for this reason qualitative outcomes are similar,whichever notion is adopted. The remainder of our article proceeds as follows. Section 2 provides a brief overview of previous studies and an outline of our experimental design. Section 3 discusses the results and Section 4 concludes. 2. Literature and experimental design Apesteguia et al. (2007) examine the effects of leniency programs in a one-shot Bertrand game. In a one-shot game, thepositive effectsof leniency programs are likely tobe overstated, though,because a negative backlash ofwhistle-blowing for futurecooperation is ruled out. Our design,which has subjects repeatedly play the same stage game with the same opponents, reduces thisbias. In this article,we do not, however, attempt tomodel thedynamic strategies thatmay ensue from this setup. InApesteguia et al. (2007), thefine reduction is split among all cartelmembers who report. In contrast,we explicitly take intoaccount theorder inwhich cartelmembers apply for leniency. In thisway, we open up thepossibility for subjects to "race to report" by giving early applicants largerfine reductions. Another difference from their setup is thatour communication phase is shorterandmore structured,in thatsubjects can only communicate about prices and only forone 1 One possibility would be to compare cartel behavior across jurisdictions with different types of corporate leniency programs enacted. Yet, additional factors that affect individual firmbehavior are likely to differ between jurisdictions, including the institutional environment, the ruling legal system, and cultural norms. ?RAND 2008. This content downloaded from 147.251.185.140 on Fri, 21 Nov 2014 06:57:35 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions HINLOOPEN AND SOETEVENT / 609 minute ratherthan tenminutes. Inpractice, cartelmembers can talkabout anything foras long as theywant. In thisrespect, theapproach ofApesteguia et al. (2007) comes closer to reality.2Our results should thereforebe treatedas complementary to those ofApesteguia et al. (2007). Leniency programs differ in the size of fine reduction for reporting a cartel, in the extent towhich leniency is still an option if the antitrustauthorities have started an investigation into theparticular cartel before amember reports it,whether it ispublic informationwhich and how many firms have applied for leniency, and whether fine reductions are available for reporting cartelmembers who are not the first to report the cartel. For example, in The Netherlands, complete exemption from finepayments isavailable to cartelmembers who are thefirstto report a cartel, thatfullycooperate with the ensuing investigation, thatare not the cartel's ringleader, and provided thatno investigation into the particular cartel is ongoing. In case the antitrust authorities are already investigating theparticular cartel, thefine reduction is reduced by 0-40 percentage points. For laterreporting,cartelmember fine reductions in the range of 10^0% are available. As a rule, informationas towhich firmsapplied for leniency isnotmade public during the investigation.The leniency program we investigate resembles the currentpractice inmany jurisdictions: thefirstapplicant receives full amnesty, the second is given a 50% fine reduction, the third to come forward has to pay the fullfine, and applicants remain anonymous.3 As the experiment ismotivated inpart by practice, we consider amoderate program only as opposed to a courageous program. In the latter,thefirstapplicant receives amonetary reward in addition to immunity. Theory offers a number of predictions we can testwith our design. First, given that the leniency program we consider is nonexploitable, we expect introductionof theprogram to lead to a reduction of thenumber of cartels formed (Motta and Polo, 2003). Second, we expect the leniency program to lead to lower average prices, as cartel activity is generally associated with higher price levels. Third,with regard to the cartels thatdo formdespite the leniencyprogram, Spagnolo (2004) points out that leniency programs provide cartelmembers who defect from the collusive agreement, that is, who charge a lower price than the agreed-upon price, a protection from-finesmotive as long as the expected reduced fines of the leniency program are below the expected fine of a defecting agent who does not report.Because of this effect,we expect to observe thatdefecting cartelmembers always apply for leniency in theperiod of defection. Experimental design. We implement four treatments.Benchmark is the standard game where subjects cannot discuss prices. Communication adds thepossibility for subjects todiscuss prices, at no cost (see Step 1below). Ifgroup members unanimously agree to discuss prices, a communication screen opens: a cartel is established. InAntitrust, groups thatdiscuss price face ineach period a probability of 15% of being detected by an antitrustauthority.4Upon detection, groupmembers have topay a fine equal to 10% of theirrevenue inthatperiod. Leniency resembles Antitrust, except thatsubjectswho participate ina cartel have thepossibility to reportthecartel in exchange fora fine reduction (see Step 3 below). In theexperiment, thefine liabilityof individual cartelmembers automatically carries over to thenext period unless the cartel breaks down due to detection or a leniency application by one ormore cartelmembers. This is analogous to an infiniterepose period. Step 1.Communication phase. Each subject has todecide whether shewants todiscuss prices or not by pressing the appropriate button; a communication window opens only ifall threegroup members simultaneously choose to discuss price. The experiment thus precludes the creation 2 Restricting the communication to price discussions precludes subjects bringing the outside world into the experiment ("If Iwin Iwill buy you a beer"). 3 Unlike, for example, Motta and Polo (2003), we do not distinguish between the situation where the antitrust authorities have started an investigation or not. 4 Strictly speaking, having a discussion about prices isnot illegal. To label the third treatmentAntitrust emphasizes, however, the introduction of fines. The chosen probability reflects the empirical finding by Bryant and Eckard (1991) that in a given year, 13%-17% of the existing price-fixing cartels are detected. ?RAND 2008. This content downloaded from 147.251.185.140 on Fri, 21 Nov 2014 06:57:35 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions 610 / THE RAND JOURNALOF ECONOMICS of partial cartels. Subjects only learn the joint communication decision in theirgroup, not the individualwillingness to communicate or thepossible cartel activity inother groups. Ifa cartel is established, a communication window opens thatallows each cartelmember to indicate his or her acceptable price range.All groupmembers simultaneously supply aminimum andmaximum price from thechoice set {101, 102,..., 110}. Ifa subject insistson one particular price, she can articulate thisby choosing thatprice both as herminimum andmaximum price. The intersection of all threeprice ranges becomes the choice set of a second round of price negotiations. If the intersection is empty, the common choice set isnot adjusted. This updating process continues until eithera unique price is reached or aminute has passed (atwhich point the communication window closes).5 Because inour experiment at least 20 roundswere played, we set the communication limitat one minute. Inmost cases, thisminute was more thanenough to allow subjects to reach an agreement. InCommunication, Antitrust, and Leniency, thefraction of price communications thatdid not yield a unique agreed-upon price was 7.3%, 1.0%, and 2.7%, respectively.All price agreements were nonbinding. Step 2.Market phase. Each subject chooses her price from the choice set {101, 102,..., 110}. Subjects learn themarket price, being equal to the lowest of all threeprices submitted. Step 3. Reporting phase. This step only arises inLeniency. If a cartel exists, subjects have to decide whether or not to report the cartel. Each cartelmember has to push either the report button or thenonreport button.6 In this step,no information isgiven about thereportingdecision of other cartelmembers. The decision to report costs one point, irrespective ofwhether or not leniency is granted. This cost reflectsadministrative costs, legal fees, and other consultant fees thatfirms typically incurwhen filing a leniency application. Practically, levyinga small reporting cost precludes a cartelmember who has been undercutfrom punishing defectors forfree.7 If the cartel is reported,all groupmembers' revenues are reduced by 10% of currentperiod revenues. Subjects can thus realize negative earnings. For instance, ifprice negotiations resulted in an agreed-upon price of 107, one member undercuts by quoting a price of 106, the cartel is subsequently reported, and theundercutting cartelmember did not apply for leniency, itsnet earnings in thisperiod would be: (106 ? 100) ? 106/10 = ?4.6. If the cartel still exists afterall subjects have made theirreportingdecision, the cartelwill be detected with 15% probability by theantitrustauthority.Ifdetected, all groupmembers face a revenue deduction of 10% of currentperiod revenues.8 All relevant informationabout the stage game is thendisplayed: submitted price, market price, revenues gross of possible revenue deduction, revenue deduction, reporting costs, and net earnings. The value of participants' totalearnings is also updated and isvisible at all times. Experimental procedure. The experiment was conducted at the CREED experimental laboratoryof theUniversity ofAmsterdam. There were 52 groups of threeparticipants each (12 groups inBenchmark, 13 inboth Communication and Antitrust, and 14 inLeniency). Subjects were drawnfrom a largepool ofundergraduate studentsacross all subject fields. Every participant was matched with the same other two subjects for a total of at least 20 periods.9 Subjects were randomly assigned to a treatmentto ensure that therewere no systematic differences in subject 5 Although this communication scheme is not used elsewhere, it is rooted in the related literature. For instance, in having a communication window of one minute, we are in linewith Cason and Davis (1995), who allow for a two-minute communication phase. 6 We explicitly introduced these two buttons inorder to force subjects tomake their reporting decision consciously. 7 "Free punishment" is possible inApesteguia et al. (2007), which may lead to an overestimation of the effect of leniency programs on cartel reporting. 8 Note that this leniency program is nonexploitable. Per-period expected cartel profits are (110 ? 100)/3 ? 0.15 0.10 110/3 = 167/60. These exceed per-period expected profitswhen applying for leniency: (110 ? 100)/3 ? 1 ? 0.5 0.1 110/3 = 1/2. 9 From period 20 onward, the session ended with 20% probability, to attenuate possible final end-round effects.We analyze only thefirst20 periods. ?RAND 2008. This content downloaded from 147.251.185.140 on Fri, 21 Nov 2014 06:57:35 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions HINLOOPEN AND SOETEVENT / 611 FIGURE 1 PATHSAVERAGEMARKET PRICE (LEFTPANEL)AND CUMULATIVEDISTRIBUTION FUNCTIONOF MARKET PRICES (RIGHTPANEL) 1081 I-*? Communication! -*~Antitnjst. e 103. Jr?m ^^$8?'^K~^'yi^^ H* 0-4 -| ? j --Benchmark If ^^ w^^3|Sv ^ ^ - ?Communication 102' ^_ /^_^/<\^*% 3 0.2 -|Nr-Antitrust 101.^ .^ " ~~""^ ^ S ^ ? "^ ~- '^,_ ._ 0.1 -I l~;;:r-Leniency 0.0-I-1-1-1-1-1-1-1-.-1-, 100-1?.?.?,?,?,?,?.?,?,?,?,?,?.?-.?,?,?.?.?, 101 102 103 104 105 106 107 108 109 110 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 1920 per** P'iC* characteristics across treatments.Participants were paid theircumulative earnings ineuros (with theconversion rate 1point = 0.25) plus a 5 show-up fee.Average earningswere 14.40 and themaximum andminimum paymentswere 41.40 and 6.80, respectively.10The lengthof the sessions was between one hour and one hour and 40 minutes. 3. Experimental results Pricing. First we consider the impact of Leniency programs on prices. The leftpanel of Figure 1 shows the average price path for all four treatments.Prices decrease over time and the average price forCommunication and Antitrust does not differ significantly fromBenchmark (p > 0.1), but average prices inLeniency are considerably lower (p = 0.019). The plot of the cumulative distribution function (cdf) of prices depicted in the rightpanel of Figure 1 confirms this finding.The cdf ofmarket prices in the other treatmentsclearly first-orderstochastically dominates thecdf ofmarket prices in theLeniency treatment(p < 0.01). These lowerprices can be due to lower cartel activity in theLeniency treatmentonly ifthe cartels inour experiment aremore successful thannon-cartels incharging prices above the static Nash equilibrium price. Figure 2 shows that this condition is satisfied despite the nonbinding nature of the price discussions: forCommunication, Antitrust, as well as Leniency, the cdf of market prices in cartel groups first-orderstochastically dominates the cdf of those innon-cartel groups (p < 0.001). The figurefurthermore shows that the cdf ofmarket prices of cartel groups inLeniency is first-orderstochastically dominated by the corresponding cdfs ofmarket prices inAntitrust and Communication (p = 0.284 and 0.166, respectively). That is, cooperation in cartels thatdo establish in theLeniency treatmentis less successful than in theother treatments.11 Thus, we have twopotential explanations for theobserved lowermarket prices inLeniency: first,as shown above, cartels thatexist seem less successful in charging prices above the static Nash equilibrium price; and second, leniencymay lead to fewer cartels being established. We investigate the latterpossibility in thenext subsection; in the subsection on cartel stability,we address thequestion why cartels in theLeniency treatmentare less successful. Cartel activity. The bottom row of Table 1 shows that introduction of an antitrust authority about halves the frequency of price discussions, thep value of no treatmenteffect 10 None of the subjects ended up with negative cumulative earnings. 11 For non-cartels, average prices are higher inBenchmark than inCommunication, Antitrust, or Leniency (p = 0.076,0.350, and 0.036, respectively). This can be ascribed to a selection effect: inBenchmark, subjects have no option to communicate, so that those subjects who wish to form a cartel inorder to establish higher prices also end up innon-cartel groups. ?RAND 2008. This content downloaded from 147.251.185.140 on Fri, 21 Nov 2014 06:57:35 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions 612 / THE RAND JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS FIGURE 2 CUMULATIVEDISTRIBUTION FUNCTIONOF MARKET PRICES INCARTEL AND NON-CARTEL GROUPS 1.0 -j^^^^^j n .~~~^p-~_?, j , ,, || ..,., JWp^^g?j jso.4-/ jA? - ?non-cartels-Benchmark ^ fAjr ? ?non-cartels-Communication 3 0.3- /?? ?a?non-cartels-Antitrust /// ??non-cartels-Leniency d/y -o?cartels- Communication 01_ Kf-^-cartels-Antitrust O ~Q~ cartels - Leniency 0.0-I-,-,-,-,-,-,-,-,-,-, 101 102 103 104 105 106 107 108 109 110 price versus the one-sided alternative being 0.028. Introduction of a leniency program provides a furtherreduction of cartel activity of about 50% (p = 0.017). As shown in the first row of Table 1, the alternative notion of cartel activity, that treats all situationswith noncompetitive market prices as collusive, displays about the same picture. The reduction in noncompetitive prices when an antitrustauthority is introduced is no longer significant,however (p = 0.210). To answer thequestion why fewer cartels come intoexistence in theAntitrust and Leniency treatment,we firstconsider the development of the fraction of individual subject decisions in favor of forming a cartel for all treatmentswhere communication is an option. The leftpanel of Figure 3 shows that inAntitrust, the reduction in cartel activity is related to a significant drop in the percentage of decisions in favor of price discussions relative to Communication (p = 0.025). In contrast, thenumber of subject decisions infavorof price discussions inAntitrust and Leniency are about equal (p > 0.10). This cannot explain thedrop incartel activitybetween these two treatments. Recall thatfora cartel tobe formed,all threegroupmembers unanimously have to say "yes" to startprice discussions. The rightpanel of Figure 3 shows thatLeniency not only has the lowest fraction of unanimous decisions but also the highest fraction of "near unanimity" situations where price discussions are blocked because one groupmember refuses to communicate. This in turnraises thequestion whether theexperimental differences between Antitrust and Leniency lead subjects in the lattertreatmenttobe more persistent in theirchoice not to collude. TABLE 1 Average Fraction of Noncompetitive Prices and Cartels Formed Benchmark Communication Antitrust Leniency Noncompetitive prices 0.47 0.60 0.50 0.16 O> 101)(0.36) (0.31) (0.29) (0.14) Cartels - 0.47 0.27 0.13 (-) (0.30) (0.20) (0.13) Standard errorswithin parentheses. ?RAND 2008. This content downloaded from 147.251.185.140 on Fri, 21 Nov 2014 06:57:35 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions HINLOOPEN AND SOETEVENT / 613 FIGURE 3 PER-PERIOD AVERAGE FRACTIONOF SUBJECTS WHO WISH TO FORMA CARTEL (LEFTPANEL) AND A HISTOGRAMOF THE NUMBEROF GROUP MEMBERS AGREEING TO FORMA CARTEL (RIGHT PANEL) 1.0 -j 0.9- >^ q Communication 0 8 - ^'''^"^ ^ ^^IIK^k P<^ ~*"*N-, 0S antitrust A mS*\ ^OJ'*"^*^*^'^ ^^?~* & 0SsLeniency - ?Communication iiSHill /IfiS 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 200123 petiOGfnunterofsubjects Figure 4 addresses thisquestion bymapping thecdf of thenumber of times each subject consents to discussing prices. Whereas inCommunication and Antitrust all subjects consent to discuss prices at least once, in theLeniency treatmentabout 10% of the subjects neverwants todiscuss prices. Their persistence successfully blocks some of thecartels, although thedifferencebetween thecdfs of Leniency and Antitrust isnot significant (p = 0.402). Cartel stability. In this section,we limitattention to the cartels thatdo form in order to explain why cartels inLeniency are less successful in establishing highmarket prices. The cdfs of the agreed-upon prices in the communication phase of thedifferent treatments(Figure 5) do not reveal a significantdifference of subjects' behavior in theprice discussions (p = 0.230): in all treatments,67%-83% of the subjects agrees to charging themonopoly price of 110. Apparently, if no differences in agreed-upon prices are observed but market prices in Leniency are considerably lower,cartelmembers inLeniency defectmore often and/orundercut FIGURE 4 CUMULATIVEDISTRIBUTION FUNCTIONOF THE NUMBEROF PERIODS INDIVIDUALSUBJECTS WANT TO COLLUDE ? ?Communication JT 0.9 --^Antitrust / 0.8 - ~~Q~~ Leniency gj | 0.6 - JjJ 3 no . r-y^a^^mi ~.*JQT 0.1 Cf jf M-+--+** 0.0 Imi Mi-1-1-?-1-1-1-1-r-1-?-1-1-1-1-1-1-r-1-1 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 number of times subjects say "yes" ?RAND 2008. This content downloaded from 147.251.185.140 on Fri, 21 Nov 2014 06:57:35 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions 614 / THE RAND JOURNALOF ECONOMICS FIGURE 5 CUMULATIVEDISTRIBUTION FUNCTIONOF THE AGREED-UPON PRICES BY CARTEL MEMBERS ? ? Communicati on j 0.9 .-^Antitrust / 0 8 . ~-o~~ Leniency I ? 0.7 - I 1 0.6 - II I 0.4 - 11 3 0.3 - jt^B 0.0 -I?D r^nZj^'^'r^Cj.\?\Ji^~i^-1? -?-1-1-1-> 101 102 103 104 105 106 107 108 109 110 price TABLE 2 Causes of Cartel Breakdowns Fraction of Cartels Defection Detection Reporting Communication 0.72 -- Antitrust 0.75 0.17 Leniency 0.97 0.03 0.78 TABLE 3 Fraction of Leniency Applications in Leniency among Winning and Nonwinning Defectors and Compliers Defect Comply Win Not Win Win Not Win Report 0.51 0.29 0.330.37 1st0.67 0.67 1.00 0.56 2nd0.25 0.22 0.00 0.33 3rd0.08 0.11 0.00 0.11 Observations 47 31324 more rigourously on the agreed-upon prices. Table 2 shows that this is indeed the case. The agreed-upon price isundercut inLeniency by one ormore cartelmembers in97% of the cases, as compared to about 75% in theother treatments.12The table also shows that in about 80% of all cases, defection from theagreed-upon price is followed by a leniency application fromone or more cartelmembers in the same period. On basis of theprotection-from-fineseffect,we expect thatwinning defectors will always be among theapplicants for leniency.Table 3 only partly supports thisexpectation: although the 12 The other 3% of cartels is detected by the antitrust authority so no cartel inLeniency survives formore than one period. ?RAND 2008. This content downloaded from 147.251.185.140 on Fri, 21 Nov 2014 06:57:35 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions HINLOOPEN AND SOETEVENT / 615 FIGURE 6 KAPLAN-MEIERSURVIVALESTIMATES BY TREATMENT 8 in d_ 1 "" (DO. ?_ CM I M--J_ l_ ^ ~h--^S-1-1-1-r? 0 5 10 15 20 duration Inperiods ? Benchmark ?-?? Communication " -"""" " Antitrust -..? ?- Leniency percentage of leniency applications in thepool ofwinning defectors, 51%, is considerably higher than in theother groups (p = 0.029), only about half of thewinning defectors file for leniency. All this should affect theduration of cartels. To estimate the cartel survival rate,however, the above definition of cartels is ambiguous, as it is unclear whether sequential periods with price discussions and lower-than-agreedmarket prices constitute the same cartel or not. Figure 6 thereforedisplays theKaplan-Meier cartel survival estimates,with all prices above 101 treatedas collusive. The estimated survivor functionsare not differentforBenchmark, Communication, and Antitrust (p = 0.37). But the log-ranktestclearly rejects equality across treatmentswhen Leniency is included (p = 0.00). That is, theprobability thatthemarket price exceeds 101 forany number of consecutive periods ismuch lower inLeniency than inany other treatment.An alternative test thatdefines cartel duration as thenumber of periods between the firstsuccessful price discussions and the firstperiod inwhich market price is lower than themost recent agreed-upon price leads to similar results. Equality of the survival functions can in this case not be rejected due to the stricterdefinition of cartel breakdowns. This shortens considerably the recorded cartel lifetime, therebyeliminatingmost of all variation across treatments. 4. Concluding remarks The study explores the effects of moderate corporate leniency programs on pricing and cartel activity.We find that introduction of a leniency program leads to lower prices for two reasons. First,puttinga leniencyprogram inplace leads toa reduction incartel activity.A notable difference from theother treatmentsis that in theLeniency treatment,about 10% of the subjects refuses to discuss prices throughout the experiment. Second, those cartels thatare established are less successful incharging prices above the staticNash equilibrium price. This isnot caused by differences inbehavior in the communication phase but bymore frequent and more severe undercutting of theagreed-upon price in themarket phase. This behavior in turn is related to the shorter cartel lifetime in theLeniency treatment; theprobability that themarket price exceeds the competitive level for any number of consecutive periods is significantly lower inLeniency. ?RAND 2008. This content downloaded from 147.251.185.140 on Fri, 21 Nov 2014 06:57:35 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions 616 / THE RAND JOURNALOF ECONOMICS The data furthermoreindicate thatdefectors use the leniencyprogram to receive protection from fines. As noted by Spagnolo (forthcoming), "more empirical and experimental evidence would be extremely welcome on all aspects of leniency and whistleblower programs." This article responds to thiswish, but thereare stilla number of importanttheoretical results thatremain tobe scrutinized. For example, although the leniency program we considered here complies with the currentpractice inmost jurisdictions, Spagnolo (2004) stresses that themost effective leniency programs are those thatgive a (more than) fullfine reduction to the first applicant and none to subsequent ones. Likewise, experiments that incorporate endogenous detection probabilities would also be most welcome (e.g., Harrington, forthcoming;Chen andHarrington, 2007). References Apesteguia, J.,Dufwenberg, M., and Selten, R. "Blowing theWhistle." Economic Theory, Vol. 31 (2007), pp. 143-166. Bryant, P.G. and Eckard, E.W. "Price Fixing: The Probability ofGetting Caught." Review ofEconomics and Statistics, Vol. 73 (1991), pp. 531-536. Cason, T.N. and Davis, D.D. "Price Communications inaMulti-Market Context: An Experimental Investigation." Review of Industrial Organization, Vol. 10 (1995), pp. 769-787. Chen, J.and Harrington, J.E. "The Impact of the Corporate Leniency Program on Cartel Formation and the Cartel Path." InV Ghosal and J.Stennek, eds., The Political Economy ofAntitrust. New York: North-Holland, 2007. Dufwenberg, M. and Gneezy, U. "Price Competition andMarket Concentration: An Experimental Study." International Journal of Industrial Organization, Vol. 18 (2000), pp. 7-22. Harrington, J.E., Jr. "Optimal Corporate Leniency Programs." Journal of Industrial Economics, forthcoming. Mason, C.F. and Phillips, O.R. "In Support of Trigger Strategies: Experimental Evidence from Two-Person Noncoop erative Games." Journal ofEconomics andManagement Strategy, Vol. 11 (2002), pp. 685-716. Motta, M. Competition Policy. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press, 2004. -and Polo, M. "Leniency Programs and Cartel Prosecution." International Journal of Industrial Organization, Vol. 21 (2003), pp. 347-380. OECD. Fighting Hard-Core Cartels; Harm, Effective Sanctions and Leniency Programs. Paris: OECD, 2002. Spagnolo, G. "Divide et Impera: Optimal Leniency Programs." Working Paper no. 4840, CEPR, 2004. -. "Leniency and Whistleblowers inAntitrust." In P. Buccirossi, ed., The Handbook of Antitrust Economics. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press, 2008, pp. 259-304. ?RAND 2008. This content downloaded from 147.251.185.140 on Fri, 21 Nov 2014 06:57:35 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions