# I CHICAGO JOURNALS [The Sgcfcty of Labor Ecwnwntstsi NORC at the University of Chicago The University of Chicago Did Henry Ford Pay Efficiency Wages? Author(s): Daniel M. G. Raff and Lawrence H. Summers Source: Journal of Labor Economics, Vol. 5, No. 4, Part 2: The New Economics of Personnel (Oct., 1987), pp. S57-S86 Published by: The University of Chicago Press on behalf of the Society of Labor Economists and the NORC at the University of Chicago Stable URL: http://www..jstor.org/stable/2534911 Accessed: 18-03-2015 10:48 UTC Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org. 1 5TOR The University of Chicago Press, Society of Labor Economists, NORC at the University of Chicago and The University of Chicago are collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to Journal of Labor Economics. http://www.jstor.org This content downloaded from 147.251.185.127 on Wed, 18 Mar 2015 10:48:41 UTC All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions Did Henry Ford Pay Efficiency Wages? Daniel M. G. Raff, Harvard University, Graduate School of Business Administration Lawrence H. Summers, Harvard University and National Bureau of Economic Research We examine Henry Ford's introduction of the five-dollar day in 1914 in an effort to evaluate the relevance of efficiency wage theories of wage and employment determination. We conclude that the Ford experience strongly supports the relevance of these theories. Ford's decision to increase wages dramatically is most plausibly the consequence of labor problems of the kind efficiency wage theorists stress. The structure of the five-dollar day program is consistent with the predictions of efficiency wage theories. There is vivid evidence that the introduction of the five-dollar day resulted in substantial queues for Ford jobs. Significant increases in Ford productivity and profits accompanied the new regime. Economists understand well how a perfectly competitive labor market without information problems would function. Flexible wages would This paper represents a drastic revision of an earlier paper by the second author having the same title. We are grateful to Anne Piehl for her very capable research assistance and to David Crippen, curator of automobile history at the Ford Archives, Dearborn, Michigan. This research was supported by the National Science Foundation and the Sloan Foundation. The data underlying the regressions are available on request. [Journal of Labor Economics, 1987, vol. 5, no. 4, pt. 2] © 1987 by The University of Chicago. All rights reserved. 0734-306X/87/0504-0012$01.50 S57 This content downloaded from 147.251.185.127 on Wed, 18 Mar 2015 10:48:41 UTC All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions S58 Raff and Summers clear labor markets and eliminate involuntary unemployment. The wages of workers of a given productivity would be equalized and would not depend on age, race, sex, or location of employment. Wage differentials for workers with the same productivity could not persist because employers would hire only the low-wage workers, creating an excess supply of high-wage workers. Yet wage determination does not seem to work this way in practice. Involuntary unemployment is observed frequently, and it has proved extremely difficult to account for the extent of age-, race-, sex-, firm size-, and industry-related wage differentials by pointing to differences in productivity or to relative disamenities in the work itself. This is not just an artifact of union activity; even in labor markets in which labor is unorganized, involuntary unemployment and wage differentials appear pervasive. These realities have led to the development of efficiency wage theories along lines recently surveyed by Stiglitz (1984) and Katz (1986). These theories have in common the implication that over some range a firm can increase its profits by raising the wage it pays its workers to some level above the market-clearing one. A variety of mechanisms, turning on the role wage increases might play in eliciting effort, reducing turnover, attracting better workers, and improving morale, have been suggested to explain why profits might be an increasing function of wages. Some such mechanism must be central to any neoclassical explanation of these facts. So long as we assume that firms maximize profits, the only way to explain why firms do not lower their wages in the face of excess supply of labor is to postulate that it would lower their profits to do so. This tautological argument in support of efficiency wage theories is not especially satisfying in several respects. First, it rests on the demonstration of wage differentials that cannot be explained by differences in ability. Since individual productivity cannot be observed directly, such an inference is inherently problematic. Second, it provides no indication of which efficiency wage theory explains the payment of supracompetitive wages and therefore gives no explanation of why firms fail to lower their wages in the face of an excess supply of labor.1 Third, as an argument by elimination, it does not provide any direct support for efficiency wage theories as opposed to some as yet unspecified alternative line of explanation for wage differentials. For all these reasons, one would like to see more direct tests of particular efficiency wage theories or, more generally, of alternative explanations for wage differentials. Such tests are difficult to construct. The very impediments to evaluating workers' ability, motivation, and 1 Throughout this paper, we will use the phrases "supracompetitive wages" and "wages above the market-clearing level" interchangeably. This content downloaded from 147.251.185.127 on Wed, 18 Mar 2015 10:48:41 UTC All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions Did Henry Ford Pay Efficiency Wages? S59 stability that might lead employers to pay efficiency wages make conventional testing of efficiency wage theories difficult. If the information needed to test these theories were available, there might be no need to pay efficiency wages. Econometric tests of efficiency wage theories also face the problem that variations in wages across firms or workers are unlikely to be exogenous, complicating considerably the problem of identification. It is thus not surprising that fully satisfactory tests of efficiency wage models have yet to be undertaken.2 This paper considers a famous historical episode with obvious bearing on the relevance of efficiency wage theories. In January 1914, Henry Ford instituted a five-dollar-a-day minimum wage in his automobile factory. This doubled the pay of most of his workers. Ford himself, in a subsequent commentary on this epochal event, observed, "There was . . . no charity in any way involved. . . . We wanted to pay these wages so that the business would be on a lasting foundation. We were building for the future. A low wage business is always insecure. . . . The payment of five dollars a day for an eight hour day was one of the finest cost cutting moves we ever made" (Ford 1922, pp. 126, 127, 147). Ford (or his ghostwriter) seems to be suggesting here that efficiency wage concerns both motivated the five-dollar day and were validated by its aftermath. Given the general difficulties involved in testing these theories econo-metrically, a qualitative approach to a specific, narrowly defined episode seems to hold some promise. By focusing on a single event and a single company, we are able to avoid the blurring of important distinctions within firms and industries that afflicts other recent studies and to examine complexities that are inevitably obscured in situations in which only summary statistics are available. We are greatly aided in this by the fact that an extraordinary amount is known (or inferable from materials in archives) about production in this particular firm and about not only the actions of the company and their consequences but also the decision makers' motivations. Moreover, the Ford episode involves a spectacular rise in workers' income. If evidence of productivity-enhancing effects cannot be found in this setting, with the take-home pay more than doubled, it is implausible that such effects could represent an important aspect of the much smaller differentials generally observed in contemporary labor markets. We begin by describing the developments at Ford and elsewhere that preceded the introduction of the five-dollar day. Our focus here is on whether the dramatic wage increase offered by Ford might have been motivated by a desire to improve profits through influencing worker 2 Two recent but not entirely satisfactory attempts are Dickens and Katz (1986) and Krueger and Summers (1986). This content downloaded from 147.251.185.127 on Wed, 18 Mar 2015 10:48:41 UTC All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions S60 Raff and Summers behavior along the lines suggested by some efficiency wage theories. Next we describe the five-dollar day program—payouts and associated rules and institutions—in some detail. Here the goal is to draw inferences about the intent from the structure of the program put in place. Finally, we turn to an evaluation of the actual effects of the five-dollar day, concentrating on the two questions suggested by contemporary efficiency wage theories. First, did the program in fact generate queues of workers? (Alternatively, was Ford simply paying the wage necessary to attract labor of the desired quality to his plant?) Second, did the wage increase confer productivity benefits through any of the channels suggested by efficiency wage theorists—increased worker discipline, better selection of workers, reduced turnover, or improved worker morale? Our general conclusion is that the Ford experience supports the relevance of efficiency wage theories. Ford's decision to increase wages dramatically is most plausibly portrayed as the consequence of labor problems of the kind stressed by efficiency wage theorists. The structure of the five-dollar day program is consistent with the predictions of efficiency wage theories. There is vivid evidence that the five-dollar day resulted in substantial queues for Ford jobs. Finally, significant increases in productivity and profits at Ford accompanied the introduction of the five-dollar day. While the Ford experience is generally consistent with efficiency wage theories, it is not easy to explain the large productivity improvements that occurred in the Ford plant wholly in terms of the mechanisms that have been stressed in the recent efficiency wage literature. Jobs were sufficiently menial that it is unlikely that high turnover was extremely costly or that worker selection effects were important. While improved productivity was associated with notable increases in effort, the increases in effort probably were easily monitored, contrary to the implication of theories based on the difficulty of perfect monitoring. Ford's wage-setting policies probably involved a substantial component of rent sharing—and at that rent sharing in a context in which history and the beliefs of the employed workers mattered. To explain the Ford experience fully, richer theories that treat the details of the production technology in more detail and assign a more active role to incumbent workers in the wage-setting process appear to be required. Such ideas are developed and explored in Raff (1986), which draws on extensive archival research to subject such an account, along with those considered here, to detailed analysis. This paper is organized as follows. Section I briefly describes some of the events leading up to the introduction of the five-dollar day and puts them in the context of efficiency wage theory. Section II describes the measure itself in a similar way. Section III examines the extent to which the wage proved to exceed the equilibrium wage needed to attract a This content downloaded from 147.251.185.127 on Wed, 18 Mar 2015 10:48:41 UTC All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions Did Henry Ford Pay Efficiency Wages? S61 sufficient supply of labor to the Ford plant. Section IV examines the effect of the five-dollar day on profits and productivity. Section V concludes the paper by discussing the implications of the results for efficiency wage theories and more generally for the economic analysis of labor markets. I. The Period Preceding the Five-Dollar Day This section describes the events preceding Ford's introduction of the five-dollar day in January 1914. It draws heavily, as all subsequent treatments must, on Nevins's authorized company history, Ford (1954), and on Meyer's careful if less wide ranging study, The Five Dollar Day (1981). But it puts the basic material, and the gleanings of our own research, in a very different light, for neither Nevins nor Meyer writes with an economist's perspective. Nevins portrays Ford as idealistically attempting to do the right thing for his workers. Meyer sees matters in terms of a struggle for control of the working environment between Ford and his workers. The question of whether Ford was trying to maximize something other than profits is skirted by both authors. More generally, these authors—like the other historians and more popular writers who have written about the five-dollar day—are more concerned with describing what happened than with analyzing in any systematic context the reasons behind the event. General Background The Ford Motor Company was founded in 1903 and remained quite small for the next 5 years. By 1908 it had only 450 employees and produced just 10,607 automobiles. At this point Ford's share of the automobile market was 9.8%. A large fraction of the company's employees were skilled craftsmen—one description of the early Ford factory was of "a congeries of craftsmen's shops rather than an integrated plant" (quoted in Meyer 1981, p. 15). By 1910 roughly two-thirds of the work force were either foremen or mechanics rated either "highly skilled" or "skilled" (Meyer 1981, p. 48). Such workers exercised, as they would have done most everywhere in American industry of the day, "broad discretion in the direction of their own work and that of their helpers." The reasons Ford employment had this character are easy to identify. Ford was not manufacturing, but merely assembling, cars. The parts were produced by outside machine shops and were not made to any particularly high tolerances. A great deal of shaping and fitting was required to get them together properly. Thus the judgment of the metalworking craftsman had to be relied on. The period 1908-14 saw drastic changes in the method and scale of production at Ford. Early in 1908 Ford settled on the design of the This content downloaded from 147.251.185.127 on Wed, 18 Mar 2015 10:48:41 UTC All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions S62 Raff and Summers Model T and the idea of producing nothing else. Ford's philosophy was clear. As he subsequently stated: "The way to make automobiles is to make one automobile like another automobile, to make them all alike, to make them come through the factory just alike, just like one pin is like another pin when it comes from the pin factory and one match is like another match when it comes from the match factory" (Chandler 1964, p. 28). Ford wanted to do this by having the parts made to sufficiently high tolerances that skilled fitting would no longer be required. The production process was also simplified by redesigning the workshop to minimize unnecessary movement of workmen and parts. In general, the work was brought to the workers, and the workers' tasks came to involve less and less judgment and discretion. All this enabled production on an unprecedented scale.3 By 1913, just before the introduction of the five-dollar day, the number of workers had increased to 14,000. Output had risen twenty-five-fold over the preceding 5 years to 248,307 cars. One sees something of the impression this made on contemporaries in the vivid description of one journalist: "One day's shipment alone leaving the factory a half a mile apart, would reach from Detroit to New York City" (Colvin 1913, p. 758). That day's shipment was many times the daily, and in some cases even monthly, output of any of Ford's competitors. They still produced cars in the old-fashioned way. These changes in production methods, capped by the introduction of the assembly line, were associated with a major change in the character of the Ford work force. By 1914 three-quarters of it were foreign born, and more than half were recent immigrants from the unindustrialized regions of southern and eastern Europe. There is a great deal of evidence that the jobs they filled could be learned extremely easily. Meyer quotes reports suggesting that jobs could swiftly be learned by a man in off the street. The following report of a Yale engineering student who worked for Ford during a summer is typical:4 3 The first moving assembly lines were installed in April 1913, and that production technology first came to final chassis assembly in October. These were the dramatic events. But we should be clear, as many who write on this subject are not, that as of late 1913 most of the Ford production work force was not working on an assembly line. Nonetheless, the influence of these routinizing methods was pervasive by then. Demands for component parts and subassemblies were more and more driven by the demands of the line. Machining tasks themselves were more and more being carried out with single-purpose rather than general-purpose tools, offering less and less scope for metalworking skills and for machinists to control their time. (It was this development—more broadly, the so-called American System of production—and not assembly lines in themselves that made production on a very large scale possible [see Hounshell 1984].) 4 The period, we should note, was a later one, but the technology and shop-floor methods were essentially unchanged. This content downloaded from 147.251.185.127 on Wed, 18 Mar 2015 10:48:41 UTC All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions Did Henry Ford Pay Efficiency Wages? S63 Division of labor has been carried on to such a point that an overwhelming majority of the jobs consist of a very few simple operations. In most cases a complete mastery of the movements does not take more than from five to ten minutes. All the training that a man receives in connection with his job consists of one or two demonstrations by the foreman or the workman who has been doing that job. After these demonstrations he is considered a fully qualified "production man." All that he has to do now is to automatize these few operations so that speed may rapidly be increased. [Meyer 1981, p. 41] The dramatic evolution in production technology changed the life of the working man fundamentally. As tasks were divided more and more finely and became more and more routinized, work became more menial. At the same time, the need for workers to be in lockstep to make the assembly line work smoothly increased the pressure on workers. The issue here is centralized setting of the pace of work and, more generally, centralized control of effort requirements. Single-purpose machine tools and the moving assembly line both offered means for the company to utilize fully the labor time it purchased in the same way its mechanics and repair shops allowed it to utilize fully its machines.5 Meyer quotes another Yale student on the immediate consequences: "You've got to work like hell in Ford's. From the time you become a number in the morning until the bell rings for quitting time you have to keep at it. You can't let up. You've got to get out the production and if you can't get it out, you get out" (Meyer 1981, p. 44). The effect of all this was well summed up by the contemporary autoworker laborer who said, "If I keep putting on Nut No. 86 for about 86 more days, I will be Nut No. 86 in the Pontiac bughouse" (Meyer 1981, p. 40). While anecdotal evidence of worker dissatisfaction can be found almost anywhere, worker dissatisfaction at Ford took visible form. In 1913, annual turnover at the Ford plant reached 370%. Ford had to hire 50,448 men during the course of the year in order to maintain the average labor force at 13,623.6 A company survey revealed that slightly more than 7,300 workers left the company in March 1913. Of these, about 18% were discharged, 11% quit formally, and 71% were so-called 5-day men who had missed 5 work days in a row without excuse and so were simply deemed to have quit. The 370% was exceptional even by the standards of the fluid Detroit labor market, in which turnover rates 5 Ford himself had long railed against the problem of soldiering, i.e., output restriction, which he labeled as "the source of more than half the trouble in the world today" (Meyer 1981, p. 88). Commons (1923, p. 365) described the labor market behavior of such workers vividly when he wrote, "They are conducting a continuous unorganized strike." 6 The figures come from Slichter (1921, p. 244). Other sources give slightly different numbers, but to no different effect. This content downloaded from 147.251.185.127 on Wed, 18 Mar 2015 10:48:41 UTC All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions S64 Raff and Summers of 200% were quite common (Slichter 1921, pp. 33-34). Contemporary experts on the problem of high turnover, notably Boyd Fisher (1917), regarded high turnover as being the result of a combination of factors, including the arbitrariness of some foremen, inequities in pay, and inadequacies in plant conditions. Some observers also blamed the problem on the monotony of workers' jobs. At the same time that turnover became so alarming, Ford also faced an epidemic of absenteeism. In 1913, the company suffered a 10% daily absenteeism rate. (This meant that on the average day it was necessary to make use of 1,300 or 1,400 replacement workers, each of whom was inexperienced at the specific task he was to perform.) Sumner Slichter (1919, pp. 826-27) took the view that the worker simply needed a break from the rigors and routines of mechanized factory life. Without formal vacations, he thought, the voluntary layoff was the working-class vacation. Despite all this the company was flush. Ford's market niche had emerged as a near monopoly in the production of the relatively inexpensive cars selling for $600 or less: by 1913, the Model T had a 96% market share. During the 5 years preceding March 1, 1913, profits averaged 118% of tangible assets. During 1912 these profits had exceeded 132%. It is indicative of the demand for Ford cars that the company was able to price in such a way that it earned profits equal to 31% of sales. The profitability reflected in part the popularity of Ford cars and in part the efficiency of Ford production techniques. Motivations for Making a Change in Compensation The motivations for the decision to introduce the five-dollar day package in January 1914 are difficult to pin down. Ford's ghostwriters are certainly inconsistent regarding his intentions.7 But enough is known of the historical record to permit some inferences about Ford's intent. The simplest explanation suggested by economic theory for why a firm would raise its wages sharply involves the possibility that it was unable to attract a sufficient quantity of labor of the desired quality. Inability to attract workers could result from either wages that were too low or uncompensated unpleasant aspects of jobs. While Ford had substantial difficulty in retaining and eliciting effort from workers, it is very unlikely that Ford raised wages in January 1914 because of difficulties getting enough workers to accept Ford jobs. By 1913 the long employment line in front of the Ford plant had become, in the phrase of one contemporary observer, "one of sights to whet the 7 Compare, "If it is right for the manager of a business to try to make it pay a larger dividend, it is quite as right that he should try to make it pay higher wages. . . . Such are the fundamental truths of wages. They are partnership distributions," with, "I am not a reformer" (Ford 1922, pp. 121, 3). This content downloaded from 147.251.185.127 on Wed, 18 Mar 2015 10:48:41 UTC All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions Did Henry Ford Pay Efficiency Wages? S65 curiosity of rubber neck tourists" (Porter 1917, p. 263). There is essentially no evidence that the company had any trouble with vacancies at the wages it was offering. Ford's labor problems in this sense transcended demand and supply. And beginning in the summer of 1913, the available supply of labor must have increased as the national economy in general and that of the Detroit hinterlands in particular suffered a significant downturn. Table 1 shows that the number of persons receiving special unemployment relief in the county including Detroit increased by about two-thirds between the period July 1912-June 1913 and the analogous period the following year. It is thus not very plausible that labor shortages, to whatever extent they existed, were expected to be particularly acute during the winter of 1914. Nor is it plausible that Ford chose to raise wages in order to attract more highly qualified workers. The whole of the technical change at Ford during this period was moving toward less skilled work. Other things being equal, this would lead to a prediction that wages would fall, not rise. Ruling out these standard competitive explanations for a wage increase, we are left with two other possible explanations. Ford may have increased wages in an effort to raise productivity by reducing the turnover and absenteeism or by getting directly at some morale problem. These are the canonical efficiency wage explanations for the decision to raise wages. Alternatively, he may have doubled wages for some personal reason—to be magnanimous or perhaps to become famous. There is evidence in the events leading up to the five-dollar day to support and to refute both interpretations. It is clear that, for some time prior to the introduction of the five-dollar day in 1914, Ford management had been concerned about labor motivation and its consequences for productivity. Originally, the company had had no particular policy or strategy for managing labor. John R. Table 1 Poor Relief in Wayne County, Michigan, 1910-15 Persons Granted Period Relief July 1910-June 1911 5,724 July 1911-June 1912 5,768 July 1912-June 1913 5,266 July 1913-June 1914 8,932* July 1914-June 1915 19,085t July 1915-June 1916 9,047 sources.—Garrity (1940, tabular apps.). * Nearly a 50% increase. tThe recession in full force. This content downloaded from 147.251.185.127 on Wed, 18 Mar 2015 10:48:41 UTC All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions S66 Raff and Summers Lee, the first Ford personnel manager, later described the evolution of this state of affairs: "We began to realize something of the relative value of men mechanism and material, so to speak, and we confess that up to this time we believed that mechanism and material were of larger importance and that somehow or other the human element of our men were taken care of automatically and needed little or no consideration" (Lee 1916, p. 299). Lee went on to recount an incident in which the output of a drop hammer operator fell off abruptly. Investigation revealed that his wife was very ill and that he was preoccupied with fears for her and worries about paying for the medical expenses being incurred. The company paid off the debts. The operator's productivity jumped back up again. In the summer of 1913 Ford management asked Lee to undertake a study of the condition of labor at Ford, including the worrying turnover rates. Lee conducted an investigation, compared what he had found to what was to be seen in other contemporary plants, and issued a report. In it he said that the chief causes of dissatisfaction and unrest among the employees were as follows (Meyer 1981, pp. 100-101): 1. Too long hours. A man whose day is too long and whose work is exhausting will naturally be looking for another job. 2. Low wages. A man who feels that he is being underpaid will always be looking for a change in occupation. 3. Bad housing conditions, wrong home influences, domestic trouble, etc. 4. Unsanitary and other undesirable shop conditions. 5. Last and perhaps the most important cause of dissatisfaction is the unintelligent handling of the men on the part of the foremen and superintendants. These points speak to the question of what lay behind the turnover. They are equally consistent with the view that turnover was a problem in itself and with the view that the dissatisfaction motivating the turnover was what was to be feared. Workers who may in the end leave but who for the moment are still on the shop floor are in a position to slow down or otherwise interfere with operations. Smooth coordination was becoming a more and more important component of the company's value added, and collective acquiescence in shop-floor order and discipline was crucial in this. Following Lee's study, on October 1, 1913—3 months prior to the introduction of the five-dollar day—the company instituted a new personnel program with several elements designed to combat worker dissatisfaction. The first was an across-the-board wage increase of 15%. The second was a major effort to rationalize the pay structure. Previously, there had been a wide variety of pay scales and pay rates. Individual foremen had had great discretion and essentially no supervision in these This content downloaded from 147.251.185.127 on Wed, 18 Mar 2015 10:48:41 UTC All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions Did Henry Ford Pay Efficiency Wages? S67 matters. Lee introduced a simpler and less easily abused "skill-wages" classification program in which workers' pay was determined on the basis of a relatively simple formula involving performance and seniority. Third, Lee eliminated foremen's ability to discharge workers arbitrarily by centralizing authority over hiring and firing in the Employment Department. Evaluating this program is important in determining the motivation for the five-dollar day. To the extent that the reforms introduced in October were successful in solving the labor problems experienced within the Ford plant, it would be difficult to attribute the introduction of the five-dollar day to efficiency wage considerations. Alternatively, if the October program ameliorated but did not solve the labor problems at Ford, it is reasonable to see the five-dollar day as just the second stage in a program (or the second battle in a campaign) directed at raising productivity. The limited information that is available supports the second interpretation. Lee, in describing the introduction of the five-dollar day, treats the October and January reforms as aspects of a single program (Lee 1916, p. 301). Meyer (1981, p. 108) concurs, describing the program as "supplementing and extending" the earlier Ford reforms. Strong evidence supporting this view is the observation that turnover declined in October when the reforms were introduced but appears to have risen sharply again in November and December (see Hounshell 1984, p. 258).8 An incident recounted by Nevins suggests that efficiency wage considerations may have played quite a conscious role in Ford's decision to raise wages: it establishes that Ford had had the possibility of a wage-productivity link quite explicitly explained to him. A close professional associate and personal friend of Ford's, Percival Perry, opened Ford's original British plant in Manchester. At first, Perry paid the then going wage of about 1.5 pounds a week. But he then discovered that a wage of 3 pounds was required for a worker and his family to subsist adequately. He thereupon raised wages for all workers to 3 pounds a week and reaped substantial productivity benefits. When Ford visited 8 All the available secondary source literature we have reviewed on the introduction of the five-dollar day, except Nevins (1954, p. 537), draws the conclusion reached in the text. Nevins attributes the decision instead to "practical idealism," claiming that all the demands of efficiency engineering would have been met by Lee's October reforms. He draws his views (often, indeed, his sentences) in that passage from Heliker (n.d.) (Heliker was Nevin's research assistant). Neither Nevins nor Heliker addresses, or even alludes to, any evidence about turnover in November and December. It is difficult to avoid the impression that they saw the monthly turnover figure for October, made up their minds, and gave the matter no further thought. But there are a number of reasons for believing that this is too simple an analysis and that the reports cited above are what one ought to have expected (see Raff 1986, sec. 8). This content downloaded from 147.251.185.127 on Wed, 18 Mar 2015 10:48:41 UTC All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions S68 Raff and Summers England in 1912, Perry is known to have explained his "high wages and straight wages" plan in some detail (Meyer 1981, p. 120). We have been arguing, as we shall throughout this paper, as if it were certain that Ford was coping with whatever problems he saw in an effort to maximize profits. But it is possible that Ford raised wages not in response to labor market problems but out of a desire to be magnanimous or to attract attention to himself. This possibility must be taken seriously. Henry Ford owned 58.5% of the Ford Motor Company. There is little reason to expect that he would maximize company profits rather than his own utility. Ford spoke, at least in 1914, frequently and somewhat mystically about the importance of sharing with the working man. Furthermore, the introduction of the five-dollar day brought him worldwide fame and reknown.9 There is no particular reason to think that Ford did not enjoy this acclaim. On the other hand, he often seemed embarrassed that anyone might think him anything other than a hardheaded businessman. "Mr. Ford laid emphasis," the New York Times reported of an informal press conference he gave at the New York Auto Show shortly after the announcement, "on the fact that he did not consider his profit-sharing plan as a work of philanthropy" ("Ford Gives Reasons for Profit Sharing" 1914). The announcement itself, though proud and self-important in tone (see below), was hardly publicized at all. Ford and his business manager, Couzens (also present at the announcement), knew very well that Reuters and the national wire services had resident correspondents in Detroit. Several Eastern newspapers had stringers. Representatives of auto and manufacturing trade journals were close at hand. Yet only reporters from the Detroit Free Press, Journal, and News were summoned to hear the great news (Lewis 1974, p. 69). While the desire for publicity or an altruistic impulse may have had something to do with Ford's decision, either or even both seem unlikely to represent the whole story. The five-dollar day was projected to represent a $10 million increase in the company's 1914 costs—an amount totaling about half the projected annual profits. It strains credulity to suggest that an expenditure of this magnitude could be explained wholly without recourse to tangible gains Ford might have expected to derive. Furthermore, and more tellingly, there is no evidence of any serious objection from any of the minority shareholders. This group certainly included men who were willing to go to a law court if necessary to protect their minority interests against what they saw as Ford's unreasonable caprice.10 In all likelihood, then, it seems safe to place significant 9 In 7 days, e.g., the New York press devoted more than 50 columns, mostly on front pages, to Ford. Lewis, who has surveyed the New York Times systematically, says the conservative paper ran 35 articles in 90 days. On the press coverage in general, see Lewis (1974, pp. 69-77). 10 The famous case is discussed in Clark (1986, pp. 602-4). This content downloaded from 147.251.185.127 on Wed, 18 Mar 2015 10:48:41 UTC All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions Did Henry Ford Pay Efficiency Wages? S69 weight on the motivation stemming from Ford's view that he was in business to make money. The act is certainly consistent with that view and what Ford knew in early January. II. The Five-Dollar Day Program Itself The new policy was announced with rhetorical flourishes but, as noted above, without much real publicity on January 5, 1914. The opening sentence set the tone: "The Ford Motor Company, the greatest and most successful in the world, will on January 12, inaugurate the greatest revolution in the matter of rewards for its workers ever known to the industrial world" (Ford Motor Co. 1914). The details were a reduction in the length of the working day from 9 to 8 hours and a raise in minimum daily pay from $2.34 to $5.00 a day for those workers who were judged to qualify. The extra compensation paid to workers was labeled as profit sharing rather than as wages. (We will come back to this point below.) At the same time, a number of the company's policies were altered. Some aspects of the package are difficult to tie to the efficiency wage theory literature, but many of the central features— written off by historians to Ford's (undoubted) personnel idiosyncrasies— are precisely the sort of features efficiency wage theory would lead one to expect. There were three main qualifications for eligibility. First, the five-dollar day was extended only to men over the age of 22. Second, workers had to have worked with the company for 6 or more months to be eligible.11 Third, in the words of a 1914 Ford pamphlet, "A worker is only put on the list of profit sharers after he has been carefully looked up and the company is satisfied that he will not debauch the additional money he receives" (Meyer 1981, p. 125). A Sociological Department with a team of investigators and a considerable support staff—interpreters, drivers, cars, and so forth—was set up to carry out this last provision. Paternalism is the most commonly advanced explanation for why women and young men were excluded from the Ford profit-sharing program. The New York Times, after interviewing a number of Ford officials, reported on January 7, 1914: The reason that women and girls in the employ of the Ford Motor Company will not share in the profit distribution announced by the company is because they are not, as a rule, the heads of families. In this respect, they are classed with the youths, the male employees of less than 22 years of age not [profit] sharing unless they happen to be married or supporting their mothers or families of brothers and sisters. It is understood that there are no women or girls in the 11 This was, in fact, not brought in until the following autumn, but thereafter it or a close variant remained as an integral part of the program roughly as long as the program itself lasted. This content downloaded from 147.251.185.127 on Wed, 18 Mar 2015 10:48:41 UTC All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions S70 Raff and Summers Ford plant who come under this classification. If there should be, they undoubtedly would be taken care of. ["Wage Earners Only Get Ford Bounty" 1914] A more cynical explanation consistent with the efficiency wage hypothesis is offered by Conot. He writes, "Women did not work on the assembly line, and were not likely to drink and fail to show up for work. They did not jump from job to job. So there was no reason to include them" (Conot 1974, p. 175).12 The motivation for the 6-month qualifying period was thought to be even less clear. Unlike the exclusion of women and the requirement of scrutiny by the Sociological Department, it receives virtually no attention in either contemporary or subsequent discussions of the five-dollar day. Nevins does discuss it briefly, suggesting that the intent was to reward experience and reduce turnover as a matter of fairness and good business practice. But some sort of tenure requirement for the receipt of the supracom-petitive compensation is entirely consistent with the hypothesis that Ford was pursuing an efficiency wage strategy. Modern theoretical analyses of efficiency wage models based on either effort elicitation or turnover considerations suggest that firms will profit by tilting age-wage profiles relative to age-productivity profiles.13 The performance incentives of such tilting will be limited by employees' fear that, if the tilt gets steep enough, the firm will be tempted to renege on its commitments. So the payment of efficiency wages is predicted to coincide with the limited use of bonding devices such as the granting of high wages only to experienced workers. Nevins specifically cites fears that Ford would systematically fire workers before their 6-month probationary period ran out but says that Ford did not do this. It is thus plausible that such fears constrained Ford from imposing too long a probationary period, whatever his impulses about the appropriate length may have been. Most historical accounts of the five-dollar day devote a great deal of space to discussions of the role of the Sociological Department in regulating the habits of Ford workers. Both Lee and Ford themselves made much of it. They said that teaching their workers good living 12 Nevins (1954, pp. 547-48) reports that Ford, under pressure from his colleagues, reluctantly allowed white-collar workers to share in the five-dollar day even though he did not see the need to raise their wages. ("He always figured you didn't need an office. . . . Mr. Ford not being an office man, he didn't understand the routine" [Brown, n.d., p. 118].) He acted, it was said, on grounds of fairness. This type of behavior is consistent with the finding of Dickens and Katz (1986) that the interindustry wage structure is similar across occupations. 13 For surveys, see Stiglitz (1984) or Katz (1986). This content downloaded from 147.251.185.127 on Wed, 18 Mar 2015 10:48:41 UTC All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions Did Henry Ford Pay Efficiency Wages? S71 habits was a moral obligation on the company's part. The message was pointed and clear. Ford pamphlets told workers about the importance of taking baths, living in clean, airy, well-lighted, and uncrowded surroundings, and saving to buy one's own house. Excessive drinking, gambling, untidiness, consumption of unwholesome foods, and lack of enthusiasm for putting money regularly into a savings account were all potential grounds for exclusion from the profits. The 150 Sociological Department inspectors went to the homes of all workers and had to certify them before their occupants could receive profit-sharing payments. Those workers who were disqualified from profit sharing could get their full payments restored if they complied with the Sociological Department's instructions within 30 days. They could get partial payments if it took them longer to come into compliance. Once a worker fell from grace, the profit shares were donated to charity until he returned— this was a show of good faith on the company's part.14 In all this there seems to be a posture of conscious education, and the company said repeatedly that the interventions seemed to be welcome. Accounts of the fraction of workers who actually received payments of at least $5.00 a day in spite of these hurdles vary. Ford claimed that all but 1% received a payment of at least $5.00 a day. Lee wrote in 1916 that 69% of the labor force qualified for profit sharing within the first 6 months of the plan and that this figure rose to 87% after a year and to 90% in mid-1916. These figures appear not to include workers who had not yet been at Ford for 6 months. Whichever figure is accepted, the overall percentage is large. Two other elements of the Ford plan merit comment. First, Ford was at pains to avoid the capricious discharge of workers but at the same time to maintain the threat that inefficient workers would be discharged. The foundering worker was to be given several chances to locate a job he could do well. But if none of these worked out or if the worker came to seem simply a disciplinary problem, he was indeed to be let go. The strategy of trying to avoid capricious firings by stabilizing employment while at the same time threatening to punish genuine shirkers with discharge is exactly the one predicted by effort elicitation versions of efficiency wage theories.15 Second, Ford executives laid considerable public stress on the fact that it was a profit-sharing rather than a wage-increasing plan.16 This was intended to convey a notion that the extra payments were gifts to 14 See the exchange between Carmichael (1985) and Shapiro and Stiglkz (1985). 15 As Bulow and Summers (1986) emphasize, the possibility of an arbitrary termination of employment reduces a worker's horizon. This makes holding his job less valuable and therefore encourages shirking. 16 They were to lay less stress on this as time passed and profits fluctuated. This content downloaded from 147.251.185.127 on Wed, 18 Mar 2015 10:48:41 UTC All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions S72 Raff and Summers workers rather than payments they had a right to expect.17 The fact that the profits were being shared with workers was said to be a justification for the company's conditioning payments on workers' spending their salaries wisely. Labeling the payments profit sharing also made it clear that the company would not feel bound, and certainly could not be held to have promised, to continue the income stream if its own fortunes sagged. Indeed, the plan was initially announced as an experiment to which the company was bound only for 1 year. This discussion of Ford's five-dollar day program gives a picture broadly consistent with the conclusions reached from our review of its prehistory. Whether or not the Ford wage increases were given for reasons like those suggested by efficiency wage theories, they provide a natural testing ground for these theories. We therefore turn in the next two sections to events occurring in the aftermath of the introduction of the five-dollar day. III. Were the New Ford Wages Competitive? A hallmark of efficiency wage theories is their implication that some firms choose to pay a wage greater than necessary to attract labor of the quality they desire.18 Since firms paying efficiency wages pay workers more than their opportunity cost, they will in general face an excess supply of labor and so will find themselves rationing jobs. In this section we argue that the available evidence strongly suggests that the Ford Motor Company was paying more than the going wage for the type of labor it was attracting. This of course does not establish that Ford was paying efficiency wages rather than simply excessively high wages. In the next section, therefore, we consider the profit and productivity consequences of Ford's wage strategy and possible wage-productivity links. The evidence that the five-dollar day represented a supracompetitive wage at least in 1914 and 1915 is overwhelming. We examine the question first by looking at the response of the external labor market to Ford's offer of high wages and then by considering the response of those employed at Ford. As noted above, Ford did not have problems attracting labor even prior to doubling the wage it paid. The deteriorating labor market conditions in Detroit and its hinterlands meant that, even with no wage increase, the length of the queues for Ford jobs would have 17 Perhaps this should be interpreted as an instance of Akerlof's (1982) gift exchange efficiency wage model. We discuss this further below. 18 Put more formally, efficiency wage theories have the implication that the constraint facing firms—that they provide workers with a reservation level of utility—does not bind. Eaton and White (1983) are particularly clear on this point. Note that it refers to the strategy of a single firm, not the nature of market equilibrium. This is fortunate since our analysis is concerned only with Ford's strategy. This content downloaded from 147.251.185.127 on Wed, 18 Mar 2015 10:48:41 UTC All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions Did Henry Ford Pay Efficiency Wages? S73 been increasing in January 1914, all other things being equal. As would be expected, a doubling of the wage, even offered with a 6-month lag, had a large effect on the supply of labor to Ford. Following the introduction of the five-dollar day, long queues for jobs were all too evident. The New York Times report on January 13, 1914, is typical of the reports that appeared almost daily for the 2 weeks after the inception of the five-dollar day: "Twelve thousand men, more than congregated around the plant on any day last week celebrated the [five-dollar day] with a rush on the plant which resulted in a riot and turning of a fire hose on the crowd in weather but little different from zero. . . . The crowd began forming at 10 o'clock last night in spite of a blizzard. As a last resort at about 8 o'clock this morning the police got out the water hose. ... As soon as the job hunters had dried or changed their clothing they came back" ("Job Seekers Riot, Storm Ford Plant" 1914). There is evidence that an excess supply of labor seeking jobs at Ford persisted even after workers gave up on lining up outside the plant gates. The Ford Archives contain a letter from the Ford legal department to the Sociological Department dated April 1915 indicating that two entrepreneurs who had charged large numbers of would-be Ford employees $0.50 or $1.00 for writing letters of application to Ford had been induced to give up the practice (Hartman 1915). It is hard to see why Ford would object to this practice if it was actively seeking more workers. More telling perhaps is the observation that large numbers of workers migrated to Detroit in the hope of getting jobs at Ford. Eventually, it proved necessary for Ford to make a rule that no worker would be hired who had not already lived in Detroit for 6 months. Further evidence of the supracompetitive wages being offered at Ford comes from the reaction of other auto manufacturers in Detroit. The treasurer of one firm was quoted as saying, "The Ford plant can only give employment to so many men and after that the others will have to seek employment in other plants at the prevailing wage" ("Other Auto Men Say They Do Not Expect Plants to Be Affected" 1914). Nevins goes so far as to assert that the Ford plan benefited all the automobile companies in Detroit by swelling the pool of available labor. (Even after it was announced that Ford would not hire workers from out of town, thousands continued to stream in to Detroit.) The economist's standard response to evidence of this type is to suggest that the increase in wages was intended to improve the quality of the workers Ford was attracting. In this case, the apparent excess supply of labor would have reflected only the low skill levels of the workers applying, levels inferior to those of the workers actually engaged. This line of argument does not seem very relevant to the Ford experience. Ford made no effort to replace his work force with new, This content downloaded from 147.251.185.127 on Wed, 18 Mar 2015 10:48:41 UTC All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions S74 Raff and Summers more highly skilled workers when he raised wages. Abell (1914, p. 306) noted, "The Ford Motor Company does not wish to change the present standard of labor in its plant. Three quarters of the employees are of foreign birth; a large number of them non-English speaking and of the grade ordinarily fitted for common labor. . . . The increment added to wages under the plan will not result therefore in the attraction of a higher grade of workmen and their substitution for the class at present employed." Certainly, everything we know about the technical change under way is consistent with this. Finally, if the goal were to attract better workers, it is hard to see why Ford would exclude workers from other cities from being hired. The long queues for jobs at Ford seem to belie the view that the Ford high wage was merely a compensating differential (to the sort of people on the queues) for unpleasant working conditions.19 Furthermore, the behavior of workers within the plant casts serious doubt on the compensating differential explanation for the five-dollar day. If it were correct, one would expect that the radical change in the conditions and wages package would not be to the taste of some workers, who would then quit. On the other hand, if the change were simply toward an equilibrium in which workers were paid more than their opportunity cost, one would expect to see the quit rate plummet. In fact, as we discuss below, turnover declined precipitously after the introduction of the five-dollar day. Abell (1915, p. 37) reports that the quit rate fell by 87% between March 1913 and March 1914. A similar comparison is provided by Fisher (1917, p. 15), who concludes that turnover fell from 400% to 23% between the period October 1912-October 1913 and the subsequent year. Slichter (1921, p. 233) gives the figures 370% for calendar year 1913 and 54% for 1914. Anecdotal evidence on whether the five-dollar day was necessary as a compensating differential appears conflicting. The experience of Charles Madison, a skilled mechanic who left the Dodge plant to work at Ford and then returned because he was "too fatigued after leaving the Ford factory to do any serious reading or attend a play or concert" seems atypical in more respects than just Madison's leisure tastes (Madison 1980/1981). Being a skilled mechanic, Madison was welcomed back to Dodge. (The Dodge foreman was not surprised to see him again.) But most of the Ford employees lacked Madison's skills. There is more insight into the situation at the Ford plant in the observations of Leslie McDonnell, a Ford worker, who recalled, "It would almost have required 19 It might be argued that the queues were composed of workers who did not realize how unpleasant life was inside the Ford plant. Even granting this, an excess supply of labor was nevertheless readily available to Ford. This content downloaded from 147.251.185.127 on Wed, 18 Mar 2015 10:48:41 UTC All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions Did Henry Ford Pay Efficiency Wages? S75 Table 2 Ford Motor Company Net Income, 1910-15 Nominal Real ($) (1910 $) 1910 4,163,451 4,163,451 1911 7,338,588 7,413,464 1912 13,542,678 13,139,301 1913 27,087,204 26,452,347 1914 31,757,769 30,419,318 1915 40,307,167 36,901,187 SOURCE.—Nevins (1954, p. 647). The 1914 and 1915 figures have been (crudely) adjusted to put them, like the others, on a calendar year basis. Trie real values use the gross national product deflator from U.S. Department of Commerce (1975, p. 224). the use of a rifle in order to separate the average Ford employee from the payroll" (McDonnell, n.d.).20 On balance, it seems fair to infer that the introduction of the five-dollar day represented a decision to pay more than was necessary to attract workers. Indeed, it is hard to see how a sudden doubling of wages paid given constant or deteriorating opportunity costs could possibly be explained in any other way. Whether the five-dollar day might reasonably, in retrospect, have been motivated by profit maximization is another matter. We turn next to the question of whether it was in fact, as Henry Ford claimed, "one of the finest cost cutting moves we ever made" (Ford 1922, p. 147). IV. Was the Five-Dollar Day Profitable? Why? Some crude statistics on Ford Motor Company profits are given in table 2. Profits rose steadily in both nominal and real terms in 1914 and 1915. Recall that the out-of-pocket cost of the five-dollar day program was estimated to be $10 million for a year in which total profits were forecast at only $20 million. Where did the money come from? Two contemporaries discussed Ford productivity quite explicitly. Abell (1915, pp. 33, 36) appears detached, though obviously very impressed by the Ford experiment. He begins by asserting, "Conditions in industry could hardly have provided a more severe test for profit sharing plans than they have undergone for the past year. Distributions to employees have been suspended by some of those organizations commonly accepted as the leaders in successful 20 For a careful examination of skill requirements and the structure of the local labor market revealing the underlying consistency here, see Raff (1986, sec. 7). This content downloaded from 147.251.185.127 on Wed, 18 Mar 2015 10:48:41 UTC All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions S76 Raff and Summers management. By way of contrast the comparative financial statement of the Ford Motor Company as of September 30, 1913 and September 30, 1914 is a strikingly interesting and significant document." Abell provides an estimate of the productivity gains resulting from the five-dollar day as well. He concludes on the basis of Ford's testimony before the Industrial Relations Commission that between 1913 and 1914 the Ford company produced 15% more cars per day, with 2,000, or about 14%, fewer workers and a reduction in the number of hours worked per worker. This figure understates the productivity increment because new production techniques raised significantly the share of Ford value added in each car by manufacturing several car parts that had previously been purchased from other suppliers. Even without taking any account of the increase in Ford value added or the reduction in hours per day, his figures suggest close to a 30% productivity increment. Lee is said to have calculated that the Ford plan raised wages by 105% but labor costs by only 35% implying about a 50% improvement in productivity (Nevins 1954, p. 548). It is not clear that this calculation took account of the increase in value added per car that occurred in 1914. These estimates are confirmed by the available quantitative information. Table 3 presents some information drawn from the Ford Archives on the cost of making the Model T chassis. Despite the drastic increase in the wages Ford paid, total costs actually declined between December 1913 and December 1914, even fully counting allocated overhead. The sharp decline in the costs of materials corroborates the suggestion made above that the fraction of value added generated inside the Ford plant was increased in 1913. Similar detailed data are not available on the costs of other components of Ford cars. But the productivity question can be addressed crudely using aggregate data. To isolate any increment in productivity following the introduction of the five-dollar day in January 1914, we estimated multiple regressions relating the log of productivity (measured alternatively using total labor hours and total production labor hours in the denominator) or seasonal dummies, a time trend, and (alternatively) dummies Table 3 Selected Monthly Cost Figures for the Model T Chassis, 1913-15 Materials ($) Labor ($) Overhead ($) December 1913 122.23 17.03 22.66 March 1914 105.07 23.54 31.40 June 1914 106.29 26.18 34.94 September 1914 94.69 25.86 34.54 December 1914 99.28 24.39 32.52 SOURCE.—Ford Archives, accession 125 (Model T Cost Books). This content downloaded from 147.251.185.127 on Wed, 18 Mar 2015 10:48:41 UTC All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions Did Henry Ford Pay Efficiency Wages? S77 Table 4 Effect of the Five-Dollar Day on Productivity Dummy Time Period Log of Output per Production Worker Log of Output per Worker (Total Work Force) 1914 .655 .528 (.164) (.177) 1914-15 .530 .414 (.155) (.166) Source.—Regression data come from Ford Archives, accession 922 (monthly production data). The period is 1912-18. note.—Estimates are based on regression equations, including seasonal dummies and a time trend. Standard errors are given in parentheses. for 1914 and for 1914 and 1915. The data are monthly and the period 1912-18. The results displayed in table 4 suggest a substantial productivity increment of between 40% and 70% following the introduction of the five-dollar day. These figures are probably underestimates, given that no account is taken of the increased share of value added that was generated inside the Ford plant. An alternative and somewhat independent way of looking at the effect of the five-dollar day on productivity is to consider its effect on prices. If it represented a substantial cost increase, one would expect to see an abnormal increase in price and reduction in profits at its inception. Table 5 presents some information on prices. It is clear that prices continued their downward trend in 1914 at about the same pace that typified the period 1910-20. As we have already observed, profits performed reasonably well despite falling prices. Table 5 Model T Prices, 1910-21 Nominal Price ($) Real Price (1910 $) 1910 950 950.0 1911 780 787.9 1912 690 669.4 1913 600 585.9 1914 550 526.8 1915 490 448.6 1916 440 359.3 1917 360 236.7 1918 450 263.1 1919 525 269.0 1920 507 227.9 1921 397 214.0 Sources.—Ford (1922, p. 145) and U.S. Department of Commerce (1975, p. 224). This content downloaded from 147.251.185.127 on Wed, 18 Mar 2015 10:48:41 UTC All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions S78 Raff and Summers Table 6 Separations from the Ford Motor Company for Selected Months, 1912-14 5-Day Men Discharges Quits December 1912 3,594 176 386 March 1913 5,156 1,276 870 October 1913 322 137 326 March 1914 166 166 115 SOURCES.—Abell (1914, p. 49) and Ford (1916, p. 7628). The Sources of Increased Productivity We are therefore driven to the question of whether the five-dollar day itself caused the productivity improvements or merely coincided with the introduction of productivity-enhancing technologies. In order to answer this question, we examine possible mechanisms through which wage increases may have directly increased productivity. The historical details of technical change close off interest in efficiency wage theories based on selection considerations. These theories hold that the point of the high wages is to encourage more highly skilled (and so more productive) individuals, the higher opportunity cost of whose time would certainly be known to them, to select themselves to apply for jobs. But the industrial journalists Arnold and Faurote (1915, pp. 41-42), writing about the Ford factory for a technical audience in this period, record very different needs: "As to machinists, old-time all-around men, perish the thought! The Ford Company has no use for experience in the working ranks, in any way. It desires and prefers machine tool operators who have nothing to unlearn, who have no theories of correct surface speeds for finishing, from bell-time to bell-time." To a first approximation, the company did not want skilled workers. It would therefore hardly have been willing to pay to find them. Ford engineers were deskilling the jobs.21 The second theory has increased wages increasing productivity by reducing turnover costs. We have noted that, prior to the five-dollar day, turnover rates at Ford had reached dramatic heights and that they subsequently declined very sharply. Table 6 presents the only detailed information that is available for particular months.22 There are difficulties in judging just how much of the drastic decline in turnover between 1913 and 1914 can be attributed to the effects of the five-dollar day. As 21 For a historical narrative, see Hounshell (1984, pp. 217-62). For some statistics on the evolution of skill requirements in the plant, see Meyer (1981, pp. 48, 50, 51). 22 It is clear that there was once much more, but our archival searches have not, as yet, turned any of it up. We suspect it simply has not survived. This content downloaded from 147.251.185.127 on Wed, 18 Mar 2015 10:48:41 UTC All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions Did Henry Ford Pay Efficiency Wages? S79 Table 7 Annual Turnover Rates, 1913-15 1913 1914 1915 Average force employed 13,623 12,115 18,028 Total leaving 50,448 6,508 2,931 Turnover rate (%) 370 54 16 Resignations 39,575 5,199 2,871 Layoffs 2,383 385 23 Discharges 8,490 926 27 Source.—Slichter (1921, p. 244). we noted above, the extent to which the reforms of October 1913 solved the turnover problem prior to the advent of the five-dollar day is unclear. Moreover, the sharp economic downturn that had hit Detroit's hinterlands by late 1913 and was afflicting the city itself by late springtime would have substantially reduced turnover even if wages had not been increased. Raff (1986) argues that this effect alone may have accounted for up to half the decline in turnover between 1913 and 1914. But there is a more troublesome problem with this explanation than these timing issues. Payments to the duly-qualified workers did rise radically with the advent of the five-dollar day. In order to rationalize the five-dollar day on grounds of reduced turnover, however, it is necessary that the cost to firms of turnover be considerably reduced. In order to make a crude assessment of the savings, we begin with an expression for the user cost of labor: c = w + (i + q)T, where w is the wage, i the relevant interest rate, q the turnover rate, and T training costs. The crucial question is whether the decline in q associated with the five-dollar day made the second term shrink enough to reduce the total user cost on balance. It is instructive to insert some plausible values into the formula for the user cost of labor. Since we have w on a daily basis, we want i and q on a daily basis. On a daily basis, any reasonable annual i is zero. Putting annual turnover rates for 1913 and 1914 (which we do possess— see table 7) on a daily basis, the cyclically adjusted change in q is .52%.23 The calculation then turns on the size of T. Raff (1986) examines contemporary calculations of the training and breaking-in costs of various grades of labor and a Ford plant survey of training times 23 The adjustment follows the conservative suggestion of Slichter (1921, p. 32). The detailed survey he refers to on pp. 33-34, which might have yielded data for a more sophisticated correction, does not seem to have survived. This content downloaded from 147.251.185.127 on Wed, 18 Mar 2015 10:48:41 UTC All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions S80 Raff and Summers conducted (with reference to essentially the same production process) in 1917. He concludes that setting T equal to a week's pay (i.e., $30) is somewhere between accurate and generous. Assuming a value of $30 for the turnover cost, one then calculates that reduced turnover saved the firms about $0.16 per day. Even allowing for the fact that after a time workers did not earn the five-dollar day until 6 months after coming on the job and that some workers were for one reason or another simply ineligible, it remains difficult to conclude that more than about 6% of the cost of the five-dollar day program was offset by increased wages. Even the most favorable of the pairs of turnover numbers in table 6 yields only 19%. These are very small fractions. This calculation does, however, presume that the relevant turnover costs are simple training costs. It is very plausible that turnover imposed costs other than training new workers. First, turnover largely took the form of workers not showing up for work and then after 5 days being declared to have quit. Presumably, with high turnover, firms were very unsure of their staffing needs and so frequently found themselves either shorthanded or with unnecessary workers. Second, in a highly fluid environment, it may well have been the case that more than one worker had to change jobs for each person who left. In this case, a single departure could require training costs to be borne a number of times. Third, when departure was associated with dissatisfaction, it may well have involved a negative effect on the productivity of others. Sabotage is only an extreme example. Overt conflict with foremen, which was very common, is another. A third alternative explanation for how a wage increase might raise productivity is that higher wages might elicit increased effort. Suppose effort is verifiable only at some cost. If wages are set at a level at which there is a utility cost to losing a job, workers will autonomously choose to work harder: high wages will substitute for monitoring and control. There is ample evidence that workers worked harder after the introduction of the five-dollar day. Table 8 shows a pronounced fall in absenteeism, for example. Even more dramatic reductions in discharges appear to have been realized. Abell (1915) reports that discharges declined by 90% between March 1913 and March 1914, while Lee (1916) Table 8 Absenteeism at Ford Total Workers Number Absent Percent Absent October 6, 1913 12,548 1,250 10 October 6, 1914 12,645 311 2.5 Source.—Abell (1915, p. 37). This content downloaded from 147.251.185.127 on Wed, 18 Mar 2015 10:48:41 UTC All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions Did Henry Ford Pay Efficiency Wages? S81 notes that there was only one discharge at Ford in the early part of 1916. The decline in discharges may well reflect both altered personnel policies (the company both trying to keep its employees and having figured out ways to make those it had given up on decide to leave without being fired) and the improvement in employee performance to be associated with increased cost of job loss.24 It is difficult to gauge the effect of these changes on productivity. They are probably best thought of as visible manifestations of less easily quantified changes in workers' behavior. Certainly, there is ample anecdotal evidence that work habits in the Ford plant changed drastically following the introduction of the five-dollar day. Klann, a production foreman at the time, described the change in the company's labor strategy simply: "[They] called us in and said that since the workers were getting twice the wages, [the management] wanted twice as much work. On the assembly lines, we just simply turned up the speed of the lines" (Klann, n.d., p. 84). Harold Slausen (1914, p. 263), a journalist reviewing the Ford experience, concluded, "But as much as the monotony of each man's work might be expected to lead to discontent the prospect of wages double those that could be obtained in any other factory for the same work serves as a deterrent and positions in the Ford factory are eagerly sought for." Arnold and Faurote (1915, p. 331) described the results of Ford's strategy when they wrote, "The Ford high wage does away with all of this inertia and living force resistance. The working-men are absolutely docile, and it is safe to say that since the last day of 1912, every single day has seen marked reductions in the Ford shops labor costs." A difficulty with the effort elicitation efficiency wage explanation for the productivity increase within the Ford plant is that many of the kinds of malfeasance Ford sought to control were probably easy to monitor. Absenteeism is only the most obvious example. The coming of the assembly line must have made monitoring workers' speed easier (Raff 1986, sec. 6). Increased ease of monitoring might be expected, on the efficiency wage theories, to lead to decreased rather than increased wages. On the other hand, it is apparent from Mathewson's (1931) classic work that in automobile production there was substantial scope— even for the workers with routinized jobs—to collude and restrict output.25 More important, the cost to Ford of any shirking by workers was increasing sharply, given the increasingly interdependent character of 24 On ways the company found to induce employees to quit, see, e.g., Bondie (n.d., p. 11). 25 See Mathewson (1931); the passages on pp. 21-22 and 125 deal explicitly with assembly lines, but there are many other cogent passages—see p. 61 in particular. This content downloaded from 147.251.185.127 on Wed, 18 Mar 2015 10:48:41 UTC All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions S82 Raff and Summers production. More intensive use of fixed and quasi-fixed factors through smooth coordination of work flows (or, more abstractly, through dedicated, Model T-specific physical and human capital) was the real source of the profits. It is revealing in this regard that, in addition to influencing the worker through the use of the assembly line and sharply increasing wages, Ford also increased the relative number of supervisors in his plant drastically between 1913 and 1915 (Meyer 1981, p. 56). This suggests that the increased cost, and risk, of shirking following routini-zation and the introduction of the assembly line was a more important consideration than the automatic monitoring these mechanical innovations provided.26 The question of cooperation raised in the preceding paragraphs brings us finally to what might be called "morale-based" efficiency wage theories such as the one proposed by Akerlof (1982). Morale explanations in general, and Akerlof's gift exchanges in particular, have received relatively little attention compared to other efficiency wage theories. But it is quite plausible that the higher wages might have raised morale and contributed to the Ford plant's productivity. The Ford shops were certainly no workers' paradise in 1914. The company proudly claimed that it crowded workers and machines together extraordinarily tightly to take advantage of every available inch of space on the shop floor. It even filled the air with work in progress. There was no particular dignity in work at the plant. Thus there was ample scope for Ford to raise morale. The changing technology also increased the importance to Ford of "buying the peace" and avoiding systematic soldiering and output restriction or other collective action by his work force. The company coupled wage increases with explicit concern with its workers' sense of dignity. There is evidence to suggest that the employees were quite pleased with their new lot. There were many Ford clubs and societies. Nevins (1954, p. 549) remarks that workers wore their numbered company ID badges with pride to dances and other social events. In contemporary Detroit, these otherwise raw immigrants must nevertheless have seemed, in the ethnic shantytowns, men of substance. The company even tried to help them become citizens and encouraged them to vote. Other aspects of the Ford program besides the wage increase can also be seen as directed at potential morale problems and their consequences. For character investigations were not the only activity of the Sociological Department. Its English classes, with their lessons oriented self-consciously toward "American" home life, a high school civics-style picture of American history, government, and democracy, and, most striking, the 26 On all this, and in particular on the sense of risk as well as cost, see Raff (1986, sec. 9). This content downloaded from 147.251.185.127 on Wed, 18 Mar 2015 10:48:41 UTC All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions Did Henry Ford Pay Efficiency Wages? S83 general subjects of industrial efficiency and labor relations, appear in retrospect as much an elaborate exercise in forming workers' attitudes as a program of language training.27 It is also plausible that, in the context of the costs of malfeasance being more easily imposed by large groups than by individuals, the company may have been tacitly bargaining with workers in its wage-setting policies rather than just responding to a fixed-reaction function. Rent sharing was going on in a context in which history and beliefs (as distinct from preferences) mattered. These two considerations, which to some extent stand outside the established corpus of efficiency wage theory, even of the mixed shirking-morale variety, are developed in detail in Raff (1986). On balance it seems fair to conclude that Ford was able, by offering the five-dollar day, to reduce the turnover among his workers and to extract much more intensive, and generally productive, effort from them. These developments complemented the revolution in the production process, and so in work content, that Ford was bringing about. They allowed him to realize that revolution's full commercial value. V. Conclusions Henry Ford's five-dollar day arose at least in part out of concern about turnover and poor worker morale and their consequences for productivity. Ford's wage surely exceeded his workers' opportunity cost and put him in the position of rationing jobs. The increased wages did yield substantial productivity benefits and profits. A natural question raised by this study is the extent to which other firms emulated Ford. To the extent that they did, some evidence for the efficiency wage interpretation of Ford's actions is provided. While it is obvious that sudden doublings of wages did not become common even after Ford's actions, there is evidence that Ford's actions did affect wage patterns. Rae (1965), in his history of the automobile industry, concludes that, as other firms eventually introduced Ford's technologies, they emulated his high-wage policies. By 1928, before the United Automobile Workers had become an important factor in the automobile industry, wages were almost 40% greater than in the rest of manufacturing (Rae 1965, p. 127; see also Brissendon 1929, pp. 96-97). In future research it would be useful to examine the wage-productivity nexus at other firms as well. This would also permit a judgment about the breadth of the relevance of our findings. The Ford Motor Company was dedicated to manufacturing as few companies in the contemporary American economy can be. The overwhelming majority of its staff were 27 See Marquis (1916, p. 911) and, for some glimpses at materials, Roberts (1912«, \9\2b) and the materials from The Small Accession 1544, Ford Archives, Dearborn, Michigan, quoted at length in Raff (1986). This content downloaded from 147.251.185.127 on Wed, 18 Mar 2015 10:48:41 UTC All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions S84 Raff and Summers actually working on production. A pessimist would conclude that the dramatic technological developments in the Ford plant make it extremely atypical. An optimist would say that, if one could find evidence here, there is real promise in so much less routinized a collection of enterprises as the American macroeconomy today. References Abell, O. J. "The Ford Plan for Employees' Betterment." Iron Age (January 8, 1914), pp. 307-8. -. "The Making of Men, Motor Cars, and Profits." Iron Age (January 9, 1915), pp. 33-41, 56. Akerlof, G. A. "Labor Contracts as Partial Gift Exchange." Quarterly Journal of Economics 97 (November 1982): 543-69. Arnold, H. M., and Faurote, F. L. Ford Methods and Ford Shops. New York: Engineering Magazine Co., 1915. Bondie, A. "Reminiscences." Unpublished typescript held in the Ford Archives, Dearborn, Michigan, n.d. Brissendon, P. F. Earnings of Factory Workers, 1899-1927. Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1929. Brown, G. "Reminiscences." Unpublished typescript held in the Ford Archives, Dearborn, Michigan, n.d. Bulow, J., and Summers, L. "A Theory of Dual Labor Markets with Application to Industrial Policy, Discrimination, and Keynesian Unemployment." Journal of Labor Economics 4 (July 1986): 376-414. Carmichael, L. "Can Unemployment Be Involuntary: Comment." American Economic Review 75 (December 1985): 1213-14. Chandler, A. D., Jr., ed. Giant Enterprise: Ford, General Motors, and the Automobile Industry. New York: Harcourt, Brace, & World, 1964. Clark, R. C. Corporate Law. Boston: Little, Brown, 1986. Colvin, F. H. "Building an Automobile Every 40 Seconds." American Machinist 38 (May 8, 1913): 757-62. Commons, J. R. Labor and Administration. New York: Macmillan, 1923. Conot, R. American Odyssey. New York: Morrow, 1974. Dickens, W., and Katz, L. "Inter-industry Wage Differentials and Theories of Wage Determination." Unpublished manuscript. Berkeley: University of California, Berkeley, 1986. Eaton, B. C, and White, W. D. "The Economy of High Wages: An Agency Problem." Economica 50 (April 1983): 175-81. Fisher, B. "Methods of Reducing the Labor Turnover." Bulletin of the Bureau of Labor Statistics, no. 196 (1917), pp. 15-24. Ford, H. My Life and Work. Garden City, N.Y.: Doubleday, Page, 1922. "Ford Gives Reasons for Profit-Sharing." New York Times (January 9, 1914). Ford Motor Co. Press release announcing the five-dollar day, January 5, 1914, held in the Ford Archives, Dearborn, Michigan, accession 940, box 16. This content downloaded from 147.251.185.127 on Wed, 18 Mar 2015 10:48:41 UTC All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions Did Henry Ford Pay Efficiency Wages? S85 Garrity, L. "The Story of the Poor Commission of Detroit, 1880-1918." M.A. thesis, Wayne State University, 1940. Hartman, H. R. Memorandum to J. R. Lee, April 30, 1915, held in the Ford Archives, Dearborn, Michigan, accession 940, box 16. Heliker, G. "Labor in Detroit, 1900-1916." Unpublished typescript held in the Ford Archives, Dearborn, Michigan, n.d. Hounshell, D. A. From the American System to Mass Production: The Development of Manufacturing Technology in the United States. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1984. "Job Seekers Riot, Storm Ford Plant." New York Times (January 13, 1914). Katz, L. F. "Efficiency Wage Theories: A Partial Evaluation." In NBER Macroeconomics Annual, edited by S. Fischer. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press (for National Bureau of Economic Research), 1986. Klann, W. "Reminiscences." Unpublished typescript held in the Ford Archives, Dearborn, Michigan, n.d. Krueger, A., and Summers, L. "Efficiency Wages and the Inter-industry Wage Structure." Unpublished paper. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University, 1986. Lee, J. R. "The So-called Profit-sharing System in the Ford Plants." Annals of the American Association of Political and Social Sciences 65 (1916): 297-310. Lewis, D. The Public Image of Henry Ford: An American Folk Hero and His Company. Detroit: Wayne State University Press, 1974. McDonnell, L. "Reminiscences." Unpublished typescript held in the Ford Archives, Dearborn, Michigan, n.d. Madison, C. "My Seven Years of Auto Slavery." Michigan Quarterly Review 19/20 (1980/1981): 445-58. Marquis, S. S. "The Ford Idea in Education." National Education Association Addresses and Proceedings . . . 1916 64 (1916): 910-17. Mathewson, S. B. Restriction of Output among Unorganized Workers. New York: Viking, 1931. Meyer, S. The Five Dollar Day: Labor Management and Social Control in the Ford Motor Company, 1908-1921. Albany: State University of New York Press, 1981. Nevins, A. Ford: The Times, the Man, and the Company. New York: Scribner, 1954. "Other Auto Men Say They Do Not Expect Plants to Be Affected." Detroit News (January 6, 1914). Porter, H. F. "Giving the Men a Share: What It's Doing for Ford." System 31 (March 1917): 262-70. Rae, J. B. The American Automobile: A Brief History. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1965. Raff, D. M. G. "Wage Determination Theory and the Five Dollar Day at Ford: A Detailed Examination." Unpublished manuscript. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University, 1986. This content downloaded from 147.251.185.127 on Wed, 18 Mar 2015 10:48:41 UTC All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions S86 Raff and Summers Roberts, P. English for Coming Americans: First Reader. New York: Association Press, 1912. (a) Roberts, P. English for Coming Americans: Second Reader. New York: Association Press, 1912. (b) Shapiro, C, and Stiglitz, J. E. "Can Unemployment Be Involuntary: A Reply." American Economic Review 75 (December 1985): 1215-17. Slausen, H. W. "A Ten Million Dollar Efficiency Plan." Machinery (October 1914), pp. 83-87. Slichter, S. "The Management of Labor." Journal of Political Economy 27 (December 1919): 813-39. -. Turnover of Factory Labor. New York: Appleton, 1921. Stiglitz, J. E. "Theories of Wage Rigidity." Working Paper no. 1442. Cambridge, Mass.: National Bureau of Economic Research, 1984. U.S. Department of Commerce. Historical Statistics of the United States: Colonial Times to 1970. Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1975. "Wage Earners Only Get Ford Bounty." New York Times (January 7, 1914). This content downloaded from 147.251.185.127 on Wed, 18 Mar 2015 10:48:41 UTC All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions