The University of Chicago Press is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to Journal of Political Economy. http://www.jstor.org Sectoral Shifts and Cyclical Unemployment Author(s): David M. Lilien Source: Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 90, No. 4 (Aug., 1982), pp. 777-793 Published by: The University of Chicago Press Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/1831352 Accessed: 18-03-2015 11:05 UTC Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org. This content downloaded from 147.251.185.127 on Wed, 18 Mar 2015 11:05:45 UTC All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions Sectoral Shifts and Cyclical Unemployment David M. Lilien Universityof California, San Diego A substantial fraction of cyclical unemployment is better characterized as fluctuations of the "frictional" or "natural" rate than as deviations from some relatively stable natural rate. Shifts of ernployment demand between sectors of the economy necessitate continuous labor reallocation. Since it takes time for workers to find new jobs, some unemployment is unavoidable. This paper presents evidence that most of the unemployment fluctuations of the seventies (unlike those in the sixties) were induced by unusual structural shifts within the U.S. economy. Simple time-series models of layoffs and unemployment are constructed that include a measure of structural shifts within the labor market. These models are estimated and a derived natural rate series is constructed. I. Introduction Some unemployment is unavoidable in free market economies. Variations of factors, such as the demand for their products or the cost of inputs to production, require firms continually to adjust the size of their labor force. Even in periods of stable aggregate employment, continuous labor reallocation within the United States results in almost 5 percent of employment leaving old jobs for new ones every month. Because it takes time for separated workers to be matched to jobs, some positive level of unemployment will always exist. Economists have long recognized this fact and have labeled this necessary quantity of unemployment the "frictional," "natural," or "equilibrium" unemployment rate. I would like to thank John Conlisk and Vincent Crawford for comments on the current paper and Olivier Blanchard and Robert Lucas for comments on an earlier draft. All remaining errors are mine. [Journal of Political Economy, 1982, vol. 90, no. 4] ? 1982 by The University of Chicago. All rights reserved. 0022-3808/82/9004-0009$01.50 777 This content downloaded from 147.251.185.127 on Wed, 18 Mar 2015 11:05:45 UTC All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions 778 JOURNAL OF POLITICAL ECONOMY Since the widespread acceptance of the natural rate hypothesis, economists have come to view cyclical unemployment as deviations from some relatively stable natural rate. In this paper, it will be argued that, given a definition of the natural rate based on microeconomic foundations, much of cyclical unemployment is better described as fluctuations of the natural rate itself. As much as half of the variance of unemployment over the postwar period can be attributed to fluctuations of the natural rate brought about by the slow adjustment of labor to shifts of employment demand between sectors of the economy. Several models describing the determinants of the equilibrium rate of unemployment have been put forth in the microfoundations literature (see, e.g., Phelps et al. 1970; Hall 1979). The Lucas and Prescott (1974) model is perhaps the one most relevant to this paper. In their paper, Lucas and Prescott explicitly derive the equilibrium unemployment rate from the assumptions that labor is exchanged in many spatially distinct markets and that labor mobility between markets is time consuming. While aggregate demand is assumed to be constant in their model, the product demand in individual markets is subject to stochastic fluctuations. Random fluctuations of product demand within markets induce fluctuations of labor demand and lead to temporary wage differentials between markets. These wage differentials encourage shifts of sectoral labor supply as workers leave lowwage markets for high-wage markets. Since the process of moving from one market to another is time consuming, a positive level of unemployment exists in stationary equilibrium. The stationary equilibrium described by Lucas and Prescott assumes that the process generating market-specific demand fluctuations has constant variance over time and therefore yields a constant equilibrium unemployment rate. In the real world there is little reason to believe that the variance of firm-specific or market-specific demand is time invariant. In some periods, such as the mid-sixties, product demand, and thus derived labor demand, may grow relatively uniformly across labor market segments. In other periods, such as the decade of the seventies, exogenous events such as the end of the war in Viet Nam, oil boycotts and price increases, and changing import competition in manufactured goods can induce dramatic shifts of demand between labor market segments over relatively short intervals. Allowing the variance of individual market demands to vary over time in the Lucas and Prescott model leads to an equilibrium unemployment rate that itself varies as the quantity of required labor reallocation within the economy changes. Casual evidence suggests that part of the higher unemployment rates of the last decade (the average adult male unemployment rate This content downloaded from 147.251.185.127 on Wed, 18 Mar 2015 11:05:45 UTC All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions CYCLICAL UNEMPLOYMENT 779 increased from 3.6 percent in the sixties to 4.5 percent in the seventies) may be due to the unusual volatility of employment demand over the period. Between 1969 and 1980, manufacturing's share of aggregate employment fell from 28.7 percent to 22.4 percent, a decline of 22.8 percent. Over the same period, retail trade; finance, insurance, and real estate (FIRE); and service industries' share of total employment grew by 10.1 percent, 14.2 percent, and 23.3 percent, respectively. To put these numbers into some perspective, note that manufacturing's share of employment fell by only 6.1 percent between 1958 and 1969. The shifts of industry employment shares, while significant in themselves, understate the full magnitude of employment shifts by not accounting for the shifts of employment that took place within broad industry groupings. The cyclical pattern of unemployment over the decade provides further supporting evidence for the hypothesis that unusually large sectoral shifts contributed to unemployment increases. The shifts of employment shares over the last decade did not take place smoothly over the period. The shift out of durable manufacturing, in particular, seems to be better described as the result of three distinct shocks than as a secular trend: Durable manufacturing's share of total employment fell by 12.6 percent in 1970-71, by 9.1 percent in 1975, and by 5.3 percent in 1980. With the exception of a modest 3.1 percent increase in 1973, its share remained relatively stable over the remainder of the decade. These three periods of falling employment in durable manufacturing coincided with the three cyclical increases in unemployment over the decade: The annual unemployment rate increased by 2.4 percentage points in 1970-7 1, by 2.9 points in 1975, and by 1.3 points in 1980. Note that in all three downturns of the economy, employment (as well as employment shares) actually rose in retail trade, FIRE, and service industries. Further, with the exception of the modest increase in 1973, the share of durables did not significantly increase as unemployment abated. These last two facts support the hypothesis that sectoral shifts played a role in inducing the general economic downturn as opposed to the downturn inducing temporary shifts of employment. In the remainder of this paper, evidence will be presented to support the hypothesis that a significant fraction of cyclical unemployment over the postwar era can be explained by the slow adjustment of labor to exogenous shifts of sectoral employment demand. In Sections II and III we conduct an analysis of the effects of dispersion in employment demand on aggregate layoffs and unemployment. A measure of this dispersion is constructed and included in a flow model of the unemployment rate. Finally, in Section IV the dispersion series is combined with the parameter estimates from the unemployment This content downloaded from 147.251.185.127 on Wed, 18 Mar 2015 11:05:45 UTC All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions 780 JOURNAL OF POLITICAL ECONOMY model to construct an estimated equilibrium or natural unemployment rate series. II. Layoffs In a typical month, between 4 and 5 percent of all workers flow through the labor market. While over half of this flow is voluntary, the overwhelming fraction of unemployment stems from involuntary employment separations, layoffs initiated by firms in response to economic conditions (see table 1). Cyclical fluctuations of the unemployment rate are directly related to fluctuations of the aggregate layoff rate. Therefore, this section will analyze the determinants of the layoff rate as a prelude to our analysis of cyclical unemployment. Even in periods of growing aggregate employment, a significant fraction of the labor force is laid off every month. Positive layoffs in periods of growing employment reflect the variance of employment demand within the economy: Even when most firms are hiring new workers, there are always some firms issuing layoffs. While this simple observation is widely recognized, the importance of the dispersion in hiring conditions in determining the aggregate layoff rate is not as well understood. Far fewer layoffs would be generated in an economy where employment was growing at 2 percent per year in all firms than would be generated in an economy where employment was growing at 8 percent per year in half of all firms and by -4 percent in the remaining firms, despite the fact that both economies would have identical aggregate growth rates. Many factors determine the level of hiring done by individual firms. Changes in product demand, changes in capital and raw material costs, and changes in wage rates influence firms' hiring decisions. Rather than model these factors explicitly, we will divide the factors that affect firm hiring into two components: those that affect all firms in the economy and those that are specific to individual firms. More specifically, we will assume that the net hiring rate of a typical firm, ht, is equal to the aggregate hiring rate, Ht, plus a random disturbance, et: ht=Ht + et. l Here, Etis assumed to be distributed with mean zero and variance o-, according to the density function f(E I 0ot); o-t is a measure of the dispersion of employment demand conditions throughout the labor market. Shocks to the economy that have differing impacts on firms, such as a rise in oil prices, will lead to an increase in ot. Net hiring, ht, which may be positive or negative, is equal to the This content downloaded from 147.251.185.127 on Wed, 18 Mar 2015 11:05:45 UTC All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions ; c tS 0) a)v SvsotcO0 Cq CqG qInOt )S tot- t- x r) t- 0 su~~~~~~~CGMi CMC >sOO 0>? <0 n cq oXq0C:00 z 04 X C)o C=O C, n "t Ln vc t- x (0 78i This content downloaded from 147.251.185.127 on Wed, 18 Mar 2015 11:05:45 UTC All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions 782 JOURNAL OF POLITICAL ECONOMY difference between accessions to and layoffs from the firm: t= (it - It (2) If we further assume that all separations from the firm are either layoffs or quits, we also have ht = Aet + qt, (3) where zAetis the rate of change of employment and qtis the quit rate. Finally, we will assume that firms do not simultaneously hire and lay off workers. While this assumption is not literally true (firms may wish to change the composition of their employment, which would lead to simultaneous hiring and layoffs), it is a reasonable approximation for the majority of firms if we do not include discharges for cause in our definition of layoffs. The layoff and accession rates of the firm can now be expressed as: It = max (0, -ht), (4) at = max (0, ht). (5) Given these assumptions, we can derive the aggregate layoff rate as a function of Ht and o-t. Appealing to the law of large numbers, we assume that the aggregate layoff rate equals the expected layoff rate of a typical firm: rHt Lt = E (it IHt, 0Ut) - (Ht + E)f(E I ot)d e= g(Ht, ort), (6) where 19glaHt=- Pt(E o-t)dE =-F(-Ht , t)>-) (7) ag/art > 0, (8) and F( ) is the cumulative distribution function associated with the density functions( ). The aggregate accession rate,At, can be similarly derived as At = Ht + g(Ht, Ut). Figure 1 depicts a graphical derivation of A and L from the f() distribution. The shaded area of theft distribution, to the left of zero, is the truncated density function of firms having H + E <0 . The mean of this truncated density function is -L. Similarly, A is the mean of the unshaded positive portion off1. Increasing o-spreads the distribution from ft to f2. Firms that had been laying off workers prior to the increase in o-now increase their layoffs by an amount exactly equal to the increase in accessions in firms that are hiring. Shifting to the left (a decline of H) decreases all firms' net hiring by the amount of the shift. Those firms laying off workers now increase their layoffs. Firms This content downloaded from 147.251.185.127 on Wed, 18 Mar 2015 11:05:45 UTC All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions CYCLICAL UNEMPLOYMENT 783 1 < 02 f~ 2 -L2 -Li 0 H Al A2 al = 0a2 > HI >H2 -L2 H2 -LI 0 A2 HI Al FI(G. 1.-Derivation of L from theft distribution having accessions reduce their hiring. Those firms that had accessions less than the shift now lay off workers. A heuristic explanation can be given for the magnitude of the first derivative of the g( ) function given in equation (7). An increase of dH in H causes all firms to increase their desired hiring by dH. For all firms experiencing layoffs, there will be adH reduction of layoffs. For firms that are hiring, there is no reduction in layoffs. Thus the aggregate change in layoffs is just -dH multiplied by the fraction of firms experiencing layoffs, F(-H C(T). Table 2 presents estimates of several linearized versions of equation (6), using the manufacturing layoff rate as the dependent variable. The variable STtserves as a proxy for (otand is defined as the variance of ZAet+ qt among the 21 two-digit manufacturing industries: Tt = | cj[zeit + qit (AEt + Qt)]2j, where ct is the ith industry's 1968 share of total manufacturing employment. Note that all variables are in rate form. The equations in table 2 were estimated using both monthly and quarterly data by Cochrane-Orcutt least squares. The estimation results strongly support the hypothesized relationship between Lt, Ht, and St given by equations (6)-(8). The estimated t-statistics on the St coefficient ranged from 7.9 to 13.7, which indicates a significantly positive relationship between the variance of hiring conditions and the aggregate layoff rate. The Ht coefficients This content downloaded from 147.251.185.127 on Wed, 18 Mar 2015 11:05:45 UTC All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions (3 C) C)O 5 5 0 00 00 ) C () 03 00 00 00 t o n i O4 G0 - 04 cq c) - Cq 04 0404040400i 0n 0 O (4) 00 - 04 -ar oo C(' (000-00 00 0 000? ._ Z ' O OOOO? 04 t 0H . I I I.I I I 00 00 'tooc :c< oc ot C4 0t0' .- 0 , CO (0 &0417.-P- 0r 04kCo Ocr) i t_ t_~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~c 0 oo- Z - -t -n 5)r 0 o04~4~0oo* o C' b' o ~- ~o ~-~ 00 ~~-~- ~- ~- 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 CO 0~~~~~~~~~~~~=~ 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 o~~ 0>?00 > ,szs;sz o o o o o~~~~~~~~~~~~~~*S S o< S a a a a r~~~~~~~~~* 0ZZ osro 784 This content downloaded from 147.251.185.127 on Wed, 18 Mar 2015 11:05:45 UTC All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions CYCLICAL UNEMPLOYMENT 785 ranged from -.289 to -.391 (without the H2 term), which is consistent with equation (7). A random increase of one manufacturing job will lower manufacturing layoffs by one with approximate probability '3 and will increase manufacturing accessions by one with approximate probability 2/3. The relatively good fit and high significance of Ht and St in estimation is not particularly surprising. The g( ) function was derived primarily from identities, the assumption of a relatively stable ) distribution over time, and the assumption that firms do not simultaneously hire and lay off workers. No other behavioral assumptions were required. The estimation also required St to be a reasonable proxy for STt; a sufficient condition for this is that the firm-specific hiring terms, E, be correlated within industries. While the estimates in table 2 have little behavioral content, and thus are better thought of as conditional expectations than as structural estimation, they do point out the inadequacies of explaining layoffs (and, as we shall show, unemployment) by purely aggregate measures. Most empirical macro models have equations explaining employment growth but pay little attention to the sectoral composition of that growth. The results of this section suggest that an attempt to explain layoffs by aggregate employment growth alone ignores an important determinant of the cyclical pattern of layoffs. III. Unemployment Two types of factors determine the level of unemployment in the economy: those that influence the size of the flow into unemployment and those that determine the duration of individual unemployment spells. An important feature of the model below is that sectoral shifts of demand which would have no impact on the level of unemployment or income if labor allocation were instantaneous will have an impact when it takes time for laid-off workers to be reemployed. Unemployment is simply the time it takes workers displaced from contracting firms to find employment in expanding firms. The quantity of unemployment generated by shifts of employment demand will thus depend on the speed with which workers find new jobs. If workers have strong firm or industry attachments, due in part to firmand industry-specific skills and to wage premiums associated with seniority, they are reluctant to seek employment in other sectors of the economy. Thus the process of adjustment to sectoral shifts tends to be slow and typically involves significant unemployment before labor adjusts fully to new patterns of employment demand. In this section, an attempt will be made to measure directly the impact of dispersion in employment demand on aggregate unemThis content downloaded from 147.251.185.127 on Wed, 18 Mar 2015 11:05:45 UTC All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions 786 JOURNAL OF POLITICAL ECONOMY ployment. In the first part of this section, a reduced-form unemployment equation is derived from a simple flow model of the unemployment process. The equation is then estimated, and the impact of sectoral shifts on cyclical unemployment is assessed. The starting point of our analysis is the flow identity AUt = Olt-02t, (9) where Oltis the flow into unemployment in period t, 02t is the flow out of unemployment in period t, and AUt is the change in the unemployment rate. All labor market variables will be expressed as rates throughout this section. The flow into unemployment consists of three components: layoffs, quits that have not found employment prior to leaving their last job (less than 40 percent of total quits according to Mattila [1974]), and labor force entrants. We model the flow into unemployment as Olt = Lt + ao + a1Qt + qlt, (10) where eq is a random disturbance and the last three terms in (10) are designed to capture the nonlayoff flow into unemployment. Layoffs in the model will be determined by a linearized version of equation (6): Lt = bo- b1(Et + Qt) + b2ft + q2t- ( 1) The level of voluntary labor turnover is given by Qt = O- ClUt + 273t- (12) The common assumption that quits vary inversely with labor market tightness, as measured by Ut, is embodied in (12). A somewhat more general version of (12) would make Qt a function of St and a measure of unexpected monetary growth, DMR, but this generalization will not affect the final specification of the unemployment equation that will be estimated later in this section. In an economy where prices and wages adjust rapidly, where little uncertainty exists about the distribution of prices and wages in the economy, and where firm-specific skills and worker-firm attachments are relatively unimportant, the distribution of time it takes unemployed workers to find employment would be relatively constant. One possible way of modeling the flow out of unemployment under these assumptions would be to assume a constant probability p of finding a job in every period. In this case the flow out of unemployment would be a constant fraction of last period's unemployment, 02t = pUt-IThese assumptions, however, are not very realistic, and they run counter to the popular practice of modeling unemployment duration as a function of unanticipated inflation. There is a strong theoretical This content downloaded from 147.251.185.127 on Wed, 18 Mar 2015 11:05:45 UTC All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions CYCLICAL UNEMPLOYMENT 787 foundation in recent search and contract theories of unemployment, as well as considerable empirical support, for the hypothesis that unanticipated inflation or unanticipated monetary policy affects unemployment duration. We will therefore make 02t a function of unanticipated monetary policy, in addition to last period's unemployment: k 02t = pUt-1 + E aiDMRt-i + 4t, (13) i=O where DMR is Barro's' measure of unanticipated monetary policy. We chose the DMR series, rather than constructing an entirely new series on expectational errors, because it works well in explaining unemployment movements and because many readers are familiar with its construction and properties, which facilitates comparison of the model estimated in this section with existing studies. The final equation necessary to close the model is the identity: Et + Ut 1. (14) Equations (9)-(14) can be solved to yield a dynamic reduced-form equation for the unemployment rate in terms of the exogenous variables of the model o-and DMR and the predetermined variable Ut-: k Ut= Bo + Blut - X X1DMRt-i+ B2Ut-1 + met- (15) i=O Equation (15) gives the specification of the unemployment equation that will be estimated in this paper. It should be noted that, while an attempt has been made in this section to derive (15) from structural relationships, it is similar to more ad hoc unemployment equations that have been estimated elsewhere in the literature (see, e.g., Sargent 1973 or Barro 1977), with the exception of the St term. It is the inclusion of St that distinguishes (15) from previous models and, given the simplified derivation of (15), a more ad hoc interpretation of its origins may be appropriate. Table 3 presents estimates of several versions of equation (15), using annual data for the nonagricultural economy over the postwar period. Again it was necessary to construct a proxy for St; however, here the proxy had to measure sectoral shifts beyond those in manufacturing industries. The variable (it was constructed using the common 11-industry decomposition of aggregate employment according to the following formula: x (A logXat - A log Xt)2j TIhe DMR series used in estimation was up(late(1 from Barro (1981). A description of the series can be found in Barro (1977). This content downloaded from 147.251.185.127 on Wed, 18 Mar 2015 11:05:45 UTC All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions (0o o~ to 0 01 ~ 0 0 -010 O(C _ 00o - t - Q0 in cq It in 01 mP- 0c -_ 00j (0 00 00 0- t- C) cqo ooo (00100 ~00 1- 00 ' (000c r; o oo on o _ o o H * * _ _ Ct& 00_CJ?. 00. - 0 00l (o 04sr --o , N4 * ( 6 0* *. *_ 0 ' qn 0xQ :)C )Q - I _ C _ X O o o-r~0) 0 -4t - SxC 00 C S --- mi)-- 0- t00-I-- ;~~~~~~~- C; 4 603 r- cr; C S : I I "-I I I I I mo~~ * -rc0ooo C CC&00&(000~~~C) C 0~~~~~?0I - In ? s0 jG l- - _ I - I CO E~~~~~~~~~~~~ 788 This content downloaded from 147.251.185.127 on Wed, 18 Mar 2015 11:05:45 UTC All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions CYCLICAL UNEMPLOYMENT 789 where xitis employment in industry i and Xtis aggregate employment. Figure 2 contains a plot of the constructed 5rtseries along with the unemployment rate; actual values for the constructed series appear in table 4. A time trend was also included in the equations to capture demographic and other changes that may have occurred in the labor market over the period. All coefficient estimates are of the correct sign and are highly significant with the exception of coefficients for some of the longer lags of St and DMRt. Further, the estimates are quite robust to changes in the sample period and changes in specification. Equation (15) may be solved for Ut(with Ut-, eliminated) in terms of infinite lags on o-t,DMRt, and m*t.Equation (4) of table 3 excludes Ut, and includes longer lags on 0rtand DMRt. Although Ut, is highly significant and clearly belongs in the model, its exclusion does not alter the signs or statistical significance of the other included variables, as is so often the case in simple time-series models. In addition, the estimated long-run ot multiplier is not terribly sensitive to the inclusion of Ut-1: In equations (1) and (3), with Ut-1 included, the long-run 5rtmultipliers are 105 and 118, respectively. In equation (4), with Ut-1excluded, the long-run multiplier is 88. One characteristic of particular interest in the estimates is the effect of excluding Sr from the equation. While the fit of the equation worsens considerably when 5ris dropped, the magnitudes of the DMR coefficients change relatively little. This result follows from the fact that Sris virtually orthogonal to DMR. Consider the following regression of 6rton its own lagged values and current and lagged values of DMR: rt .024 - .051Srt-l + .033t-2 - .108DMRt - .045DMRt-1, (.005) (.193) (.106) (.171) (.170) R2= .035, R2 -.103. 7 |- 00a0 .03 .02 1950 1955 1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 FIGJ. 2 This content downloaded from 147.251.185.127 on Wed, 18 Mar 2015 11:05:45 UTC All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions 79( JOURNAL OF POLITICAL ECONOMY TABLE 4 UNEMPLOYMENT SERIES DETREN DED YEAR Ut U* Ut-U* Ut U* &t 1948 3.8 ... ... ... ... .0262 1949 5.9 5.3 .6 6.9 6.3 .0482 1950 5.3 5.0 .3 6.3 6.0 .0251 1951 3.3 5.3 -2.0 4.2 6.2 .0461 1952 3.0 4.1 -1.1 3.9 5.0 .0138 1953 2.9 3.9 - 1.0 3.7 4.7 .0283 1954 5.5 5.4 .1 6.2 6.1 .0508 1955 4.4 4.5 -.1 5.0 5.1 .0147 1956 4.1 3.8 .3 4.7 4.4 .0186 1957 4.3 4.0 .3 4.8 4.5 .0248 1958 6.8 5.5 1.3 7.2 5.9 .0489 1959 5.5 4.9 .6 5.8 5.2 .0160 1960 5.5 4.2 1.3 5.7 4.5 .0181 1961 6.7 4.6 2.1 6.9 4.8 .0282 1962 5.5 4.3 1.2 5.5 4.4 .0148 1963 5.7 4.0 1.6 5.7 4.1 .0156 1964 5.2 4.0 1.2 5.1 4.0 .0158 1965 4.5 4.1 .4 4.3 3.9 .0149 1966 3.8 4.3 -.5 3.6 4.1 .0194 1967 3.8 4.7 -.9 3.5 4.4 .0216 1968 3.6 4.7 - 1.1 3.2 4.3 .0157 1969 3.5 4.7 - 1.2 3.0 4.2 .0157 1970 4.9 5.7 -.8 4.3 5.2 .0347 1971 5.9 6.5 -.6 5.3 5.8 .0325 1972 5.6 5.8 -.2 4.9 5.1 .0133 1973 4.9 5.5 -.6 4.1 4.8 .0192 1974 5.6 5.6 -.0 4.7 4.8 .0196 1975 8.5 7.9 .6 7.5 6.9 .0583 1976 7.7 7.1 .6 6.7 6.1 .0138 1977 7.0 6.3 .7 5.9 5.2 .0171 1978 6.0 6.2 -.2 4.8 5.0 .0200 1979 5.8 6.1 -.3 4.5 4.9 .0165 1980 7.1 6.7 .4 5.7 5.4 .0284 Virtually none of the variance of ort is explained by its own lagged values or by DMR. We can thus strongly reject Granger causality of 6rt by DMR, which lends some support to our assumption that o-is truly exogenous. Further support of the hypothesis that o- is exogenous is provided by the low explanatory power of the other included variables in the unemployment equation: (rt = .042 - .013036t - .094DMRt - .128DMRt(.009) (.198) (.156) (.165) - .0032Ut1- 6.4E - 5T, (.0022) (3.OE - 4) R2= .173, R2 = .020. This content downloaded from 147.251.185.127 on Wed, 18 Mar 2015 11:05:45 UTC All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions CYC(LICAL UNEMPLOYMENT 791 IV. The Natural Rate The regression results of Sections II and III suggest that the process of labor reallocation in response to the shifting pattern of employment demand is a significant source of cyclical unemployment. In this section, a measure of the unemployment induced by the fluctuations of o-t will be constructed and discussed. Since the widespread acceptance of the natural rate hypothesis, economists have come to view cyclical unemployment as deviations of unemployment from some relatively stable natural rate. The natural rate is thought of as the level of frictional unemployment (necessary to carry out the continuous process of labor allocation) that would occur in a steady state when agents correctly perceive the distribution of prices and wages throughout the economy. The view that the natural rate is relatively constant and that it is the unemployment necessary to accommodate the process of labor reallocation seems to conflict with the regression results. The latter would seem to indicate strong cyclical patterns in the volume of required labor allocation. Part of the source of this contradiction stems from the variety of meanings given to the term "natural rate." In much of the microfoundation literature (see, e.g., Lucas and Prescott 1974), equilibrium unemployment arises because firms face continuous fluctuations in demand for their products even when aggregate demand is stable. There is nothing in this literature to suggest that the equilibrium unemployment will be time invariant. Rather, we would expect periods of rapidly shifting demand-whether induced by changes in taste, import prices, technological change, or whatever-to be associated with increases in the natural, or equilibrium, rate of unem- ployment. In much of the recent equilibrium business cycle literature, these events, which might be thought of as leading to shifts of demand and increases of the natural rate, are modeled as aggregate supply shocks. Unemployment is viewed as consisting of three components: a relatively constant natural rate, unemployment associated with expectational errors, and unemployment associated with supply shocks. Given this characterization, it may not be unreasonable to view the natural rate as constant or evolving slowly over time as a result of changes in the demographic and institutional characteristics of the labor market. Here, however, the term "natural rate" must be given a somewhat different interpretation, that is, the level of unemployment associated with the average or typical quantity of labor reallocation required within the economy. Events that require unusual labor reallocation lead to deviations from, rather than shifts of, the natural rate. In what follows we will construct a measure of the natural rate that This content downloaded from 147.251.185.127 on Wed, 18 Mar 2015 11:05:45 UTC All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions 792 JOURNAL OF POLITICAL ECONOMY is more closely related to the microfoundations concept than the business cycle model concept. In terms of the unemployment equation (15), we will define the natural rate as that level of unemployment that would have existed if current and past values of DMRt and mthad been identically zero. It is given by the equation ZB2(Bo + Bl-t-i + B3Tt-), (16) i=O where B3 is the coefficient of the time trend variable T. A series for the natural rate was calculated using the estimates of equation (3) in table 3. They are presented along with the actual values of Ut and (rtin table 4 and figure 2. While equation (16) makes U* a function of the infinite history of (it, the weights die off so quickly that only a few years of lagged data are necessary to construct reasonable approximations. Nevertheless, the requirement of previous observations of (rtprecludes estimating U* over the entire sample. The U* series varies significantly over the 1949 and 1980 period, tracking movements in Ut reasonably well. Over half of the variance in Ut can be explained by U*; the simple correlation between Ut and U* is .74. Of course, part of the reason for the high correlation between Ut and U* is that they both have trended upward over the postwar period. Column 5 of table 3 presents a constructed natural rate series using the formula given in equation (16), but replacing the value of the time trend with its average value over the period. It is thus a detrended measure of the natural rate that reflects only fluctuations due to current and lagged values of 6rt.The correlation of this series with the detrended unemployment series is .60. The pattern of Ut and U*, revealed in figure 2, points out the variety of sources of cyclical unemployment. Unemployment over the seventies is particularly well explained by U*, which suggests that real factors influencing the natural rate were the major source of cyclical unemployment. This observation is consistent with the popular view that supply shocks were responsible for much of the cyclical activity of the last decade. In marked contrast, unemployment over the sixties is characterized by significant deviations from U*. In 7 of the 8 years between 1956 and 1963, monetary growth was below its expected level, as indicated by DMR, which resulted in unemployment significantly above the natural rate in the late fifties to early sixties. In 5 of the 6 years between 1964 and 1969, monetary growth was above its expected level, which resulted in unemployment below the natural rate in the late sixties. V. Concluding Remarks While explicit consideration of stabilization policy is beyond the scope of this paper, there are policy implications in its findings. Our analyThis content downloaded from 147.251.185.127 on Wed, 18 Mar 2015 11:05:45 UTC All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions CYCLICAL UNEMPLOYMENT 793 sis suggests that much of the unemployment of the seventies could not have been avoided through aggregate monetary and fiscal policies. Such policies may have been successful in delaying or smoothing the cyclical pattern of unemployment, but since inadequate demand was not the source of unemployment, aggregate demand policies were not an appropriate cure. This is in marked contrast to the early sixties, where our estimates suggest that unemployment was well above the natural rate, due in part to several years of lower-than-anticipated monetary growth (as measured by DMR) or, more generally, to a contractionary set of aggregate demand policies. The inability of aggregate demand policies to eliminate unemployment induced by "real"factors does not rule out a role for all policy. Targeted demand policies, or supply-side policies aimed at easing the transition of workers from declining to growing sectors of the economy, or policies to stimulate productivity in declining sectors may be appropriate. The nontrivial task of analyzing stabilization policy within a disaggregated framework would seem to be a productive line for future research. The model developed in this paper does not claim to give a total description of the operation of labor markets or the process of unemployment. It does, however, suggest some of the limitations of aggregate models that do not explicitly account for the multisectoral character of production and employment and the imperfect shortrun mobility of resources between sectors. It also suggests that nonmonetary factors, whether viewed as supply shocks or as shifts of the natural rate, have been an important source of cyclical unemployment and deserve greater attention in the business cycle literature. References Barro, Robert J. "Unanticipated Money Growth and Unemployment in the United States." A.E.R. 67 (March 1977): 101-15. . "Intertemporal Substitution and the Business Cycle." J. Monetary Econ. 14 (suppl., Spring 1981): 237-68. Hall, Robert E. "A Theory of the Natural Unemployment Rate and the Duration of Employment."J. MonetaryEcon. 5 (April 1979): 153-69. Lucas, Robert E., Jr., and Prescott, Edward C. "Equilibrium Search and Unemployment." J. Econ. Theory7 (February 1974): 188-209. Mattila, J. Peter. "Job Quitting and Frictional Unemployment." A.E.R. 64 (March 1974): 235-39. Phelps, Edmund S., et al. Microeconomic Foundations of Employment and Inflation Theory.New York: Norton, 1970. Sargent, Thomas J. "Rational Expectations, the Real Rate of Interest and the 'Natural' Rate of Unemployment." Brookings Papers Econ. Activity, no. 2 (1973), pp. 429-72. This content downloaded from 147.251.185.127 on Wed, 18 Mar 2015 11:05:45 UTC All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions