Transition Economies: Performance and Challenges Jan Svejnar T he collapse of the Soviet political and economic system in the late 1980s, epitomized by the fall of the Berlin Wall in November 1989, culminated the dramatic economic slowdown experienced by the Soviet bloc countries over the preceding three decades. The resulting transition from central planning to a market economy has been difficult. The performance of the transition economies has fallen short of expectations for several reasons: advanced Western economies did unusually well in the 1990s, which raised the bar for perceptions of economic success; the economic problems associated with the transition were widely underestimated; and policymakers made a number of questionable choices. Nevertheless, progress has been made in a number of dimensions. In this paper, I provide an overall assessment of the strategies and outcomes of the first dozen years of the transition, as well as an outline of the principal challenges faced by these economies. In presenting data and examples, I focus primarily on comparing the experience of the five central European countries—the Czech Republic, Hungary, Poland, Slovakia and Slovenia—with the experience of Russia. The five central European countries have a combined population of over 65 million people and were the first to launch the transition. Russia, with its population of 145 million, is the principal country of the former Soviet Union and now of the Commonwealth of Independent States (CIS), which is made up of countries that were formerly republics of the Soviet Union, and it has had a very difficult experience with transition. I will also make a number of references to three other groups: the three Baltic countries of Estonia, Latvia and Lithuania, with a y Jan Svejnar is Executive Director of the William Davidson Institute, Everett E. Berg Professor of Business Administration and Professor of Economics, all at the University of Michigan, Ann Arbor, Michigan. He is also Chair of the Executive and Supervisory Committee, CERGE-EI, Prague, Czech Republic. Journal of Economic Perspectives—Volume 16, Number 1—Winter 2002—Pages 3–28 combined population of 7.5 million, which became part of the Soviet Union only at the outset of World War II and in the 1990s staged a relatively fast transition; the Balkan or southeast European countries of Albania, Bulgaria and Romania, combined population 34 million, which have not been affected by war or other conflicts; and Ukraine, as the second largest economy of the former Soviet Union and now the CIS, with its population of 50 million. I will not discuss, except in passing, the many other countries of the CIS: Armenia, Azerbaijan, Belarus, Georgia, Kazakhstan, Kyrgyzstan, Moldova, Tajikistan, Turkmenistan and Uzbekistan. I also will not focus on the countries of the former Yugoslavia, since their formative experiences of the 1990s involve war and civil strife rather than economic transition. The Soviet-style centrally planned system was relatively well suited to mobilizing resources for expanding existing productive activities during World War II and the postwar reconstruction, although it also suppressed human rights and imposed great human suffering. The Soviet bloc countries achieved a 4.5 percent annual growth rate in per capita GNP during the 1950s, exceeding the 3.7 percent rate of growth of a comparison group of market economies (Gregory and Stuart, 1997).1 However, the rigidities of the command economy made it much less suitable for invention, innovation and efficient allocation of resources, resulting in a long-term slowdown in the entire Soviet bloc since about 1960. While the comparison group of market economies averaged rates of growth of GNP per capita of 4.5 percent in the 1960s, 2.8 percent in the 1970s and 2 percent in the 1980s, the growth of per capita GNP of the Soviet bloc countries is estimated to have fallen to 3.6 percent in the 1960s, 2.8 percent in the 1970s and 0.8 percent in the 1980s. The fall of communism created expectations that the centrally planned economies, as they moved to a market system, would generate rapid economic growth and gradually catch up with middle-income developed countries. These expectations were tempered by anxiety over (presumably temporary) high rates of inflation that were being observed in Poland and in the disintegrating Yugoslavia in the late 1980s and by the knowledge that transition would not happen overnight. Strategies for Transition The policymakers in the former Soviet bloc formulated transition strategies that focused on macroeconomic stabilization and microeconomic restructuring, along with institutional and political reforms. The implementation of these strategies varied across countries in speed and specifics. A major debate took place about the merits of fast or “big bang” reform versus gradual reform. But as it turned 1 In Gregory and Stuart (1997), the Soviet bloc includes all the states of the Soviet Union, plus Bulgaria, Czechoslovakia, East Germany, Hungary, Poland and Romania. The market economies in the sample include Austria, Belgium, Canada, Denmark, France, Greece, India, Italy, Japan, the Netherlands, Norway, Spain, Sweden, Turkey, United Kingdom, United States and West Germany. 4 Journal of Economic Perspectives out, almost all the transition governments plunged ahead in rapid “big bang” style with what I will call Type I reforms. However, significant policy differences ensued in what I shall term Type II reforms, which only some governments carried out.2 Type I reforms typically focused on macro stabilization, price liberalization and dismantling the institutions of the communist system. The macroeconomic strategy emphasized restrictive fiscal and monetary policies, wage controls and, in most cases, also a fixed exchange rate. The micro strategy was to move quickly toward price liberalization, although a number of key prices, like those of energy, housing and basic consumption goods, often remained controlled along with wages and exchange rates. The institution governing the Soviet bloc trading area, the Council for Mutual Economic Assistance (CMEA), was abolished, and most countries opened up rapidly to international trade, thus inducing a more efficient allocation of resources based on world market prices. Most countries also quickly reduced direct subsidies to trusts and state-owned enterprises and allowed them to restructure or even break up. They removed barriers to the creation of new firms and banks and carried out small-scale privatizations. Moreover, early on, most governments broke up the “monobank” system, whereby a single state bank (or a system of tightly knit but nominally independent banks) functioned as a country’s central bank as well as a nationwide commercial and investment bank, and instead allowed the creation of new and independent banks. A final feature was the introduction of some elements of a social safety net. These changes caused a sizable reallocation of labor away from the state-run firms, some of which went to the new private firms and some of which ended up in nonemployment. The Type I reforms proved relatively sustainable and were associated with improving economic performance in central Europe (except the Czech Republic) and in the Baltic countries, whereas they were much less successful in Russia, the other countries of the Commonwealth of Independent States and the Balkans. Type II reforms involved the development and enforcement of laws, regulations and institutions that would ensure a successful market-oriented economy. These reforms include the privatization of large and medium-sized enterprises; establishment and enforcement of a market-oriented legal system and accompanying institutions; further in-depth development of a viable commercial banking sector and the appropriate regulatory infrastructure; labor market regulations; and institutions related to public unemployment and retirement systems. The differences in the ability of transition governments to carry out Type I and Type II reforms seemed to turn on two factors: their ability to collect taxes with which to finance public programs and their ability to minimize corruption and rent-seeking behavior. Type I reforms generally seek to cut off subsidies and to reduce centrally planned regulation. Since many transition governments had great 2 The “big bang” versus gradualism debate is also relevant in comparing the former Soviet bloc to China. China proceeded gradually even with respect to Type I reforms, and it also avoided the initial recession experienced by all transition economies in central and eastern Europe and the Commonwealth of Independent States. Jan Svejnar 5 difficulty in setting up a reliable tax system, cutting off subsidies and reducing the scope of government was almost forced upon them. However, Type II reforms emphasize that transition requires not only the withering away of an omnipresent dictatorial state, but also a creation of a reliable state apparatus that provides a level playing field for the market economy. Type II reforms require that government have some resources, at least enough to enforce market-friendly laws and to avoid being dominated or captured by special interests. While the full range of differences across countries in Type II reforms are difficult to capture, it is possible to give some sense of the differences across several areas: privatization, banking reform, labor and social institutions, and a marketoriented legal system. Remarkable differences exist across the transition economies in the strategy of privatizing large and medium-sized firms. Poland and Slovenia moved slowly in privatizing state-owned enterprises, relying instead on “commercialization,” where firms remained state-owned but were run by somewhat independent appointed supervisory boards rather than directly by the state, and on the creation of new private firms. Estonia and Hungary proceeded assiduously and surprisingly effectively with privatization of individual state-owned enterprises by selling them one by one to outside owners. This method of privatization was originally viewed by many strategists as being too slow. Yet it provided much-needed managerial skills and external funds for investment in the privatized firms; it generated government revenue and effective corporate governance; and it turned out to be relatively fast when carried out by determined governments. Russia and Ukraine opted for rapid mass privatization and relied primarily on subsidized management-employee buyouts of firms. This method had the advantage of speed, but it has led to poor corporate governance in that existing management usually was not able or willing to improve efficiency. The method also did not generate new investment funds and skills, and it provided little revenue for the government. Finally, the Czech Republic, Lithuania and, to a lesser extent, Slovakia carried out equal-access voucher privatization, whereby a majority of shares of most firms were distributed to citizens at large. While this approach may have been most fair and one of the best in terms of speed, it did not generate new investment funds, nor did it bring revenue to the government. Instead, it resulted in dispersed ownership of shares and, together with a weak legal framework, it resulted in poor corporate governance. The poor corporate governance often permitted managers or majority shareholders to appropriate profit or even assets of the firms (to “tunnel,” as it is sometimes said) at the expense of minority shareholders. In the development of a banking system, virtually all countries rapidly abolished the monobank system as part of Type I reforms. Some countries, such as Russia, allowed spontaneous growth of new banks from the bottom up, resulting in the creation of hundreds of banks virtually overnight. In central and eastern Europe, the process was much more government-controlled, but even there, dozens of small banks rapidly emerged in countries like the Czech Republic and Poland. While the banking systems differed in various ways, they shared some 6 Journal of Economic Perspectives discouraging patterns. Many of the small banks quickly collapsed. In most countries, large banks started the transition with a sizable portfolio of nonperforming enterprise loans, and upon restructuring, they rapidly accumulated new nonperforming loans. The large banks survived primarily because they were “too large to fail” and governments bailed them out. The need for repeated bailouts of banks has in the late 1990s led Hungary, the Czech Republic and Poland to privatize virtually all domestic banks to large western banks. Central Europe has thus become a laboratory for observing several attempts to introduce a competitive western banking system with virtually no local banks. The transition countries differed in the nature and speed of the development of labor and social regulations and institutions. By the end of 1991, all the central and eastern European countries developed relatively well-functioning unemployment compensation and social security benefit schemes, with the originally generous benefits becoming somewhat more modest over time (Ham, Svejnar and Terrell, 1998). In Russia and the other countries of the Commonwealth of Independent States, the official benefits were low to start with and decreased dramatically in real terms over time—and even the low official benefits were often not paid. Virtually no transition country succeeded in rapidly developing a legal system and institutions that would be highly conducive to the preservation of private property and to the functioning of a market economy, although some countries did much better than others. This lack of a market-oriented legal structure appears to have been the Achilles’ heel of the first dozen years of transition. Many policymakers underestimated the importance of a well-functioning legal system or believed too readily that free markets would take care of any major problems. In addition, many newly rich individuals and groups in the transition economies—especially those who contributed to the corruption of public officials—did not desire a strong legal system. The countries that have made the greatest progress in limiting corruption and establishing a functioning legal framework and institutions are the central European and Baltic countries, with the partial exception of the Czech Republic and Slovakia. In recent years, an important impetus for carrying out legal and institutional reforms in many of these countries has been the need to develop a system that conforms to that of the European Union as a prerequisite for accession to the EU. Performance of the Transition Economies Since 1989 The transition economies have not performed as well as many had expected. Economic performance has also varied widely across the transition countries, with the central European countries of Poland, Slovenia, Hungary, Slovakia and the Czech Republic generally performing better than the Baltic states of Estonia, Latvia and Lithuania and the Balkan states of Bulgaria and Romania, which in turn performed better than Russia, Ukraine and other countries in the Commonwealth of Independent States. Transition Economies: Performance and Challenges 7 Gross Domestic Product Calculating the evolution of GDP is difficult in the transition economies. Instead of GDP, the communist countries used “gross material product” to measure the size of their economies, a measure that ignored the production of services. Moreover, the communist economies were characterized by prices that did not reflect scarcity and consumer demand, thus making market valuations difficult. The dramatic growth in the number of small firms during the transition was not well-captured in the official statistics—to say nothing of the course of the underground economy in these countries both before and during the transition. National statistical offices and the international institutions have devoted significant resources to estimating GDP for the late 1980s and tracing out GDP accurately thereafter, but the early data obviously have to be interpreted with caution (Filer and Hanousek, 2000, this issue; Brada, King and Kutan, 2000). With the above caveats in mind, one may interpret the growth performance since 1989 as having been mildly to significantly disappointing in central Europe and poor to disastrous in eastern Europe and the Commonwealth of Independent States. Figure 1 provides GDP data for an illustrative set of countries. All of the transition economies experienced large declines in output at the start of the transition. The decline varied from 13 to 25 percent in central and eastern Europe; over 40 percent in the Baltic countries; and as much as 45 percent or more in Russia and even more in many of the other nations of the CIS, like the drop of almost 65 percent in Ukraine. While the central and eastern European countries reversed the decline after three or four years, in Russia and most of the CIS no turnaround was visible through most of the 1990s. Russia, for instance, suffered a continuous decline in GDP until 1996, showed signs of growth in 1997, but then went into another 5 percent decline during its 1998 financial crisis. All central European countries except for the Czech Republic have generated sustained economic growth since the early to mid-1990s. However, only in Poland has the rate of growth been sufficient to start closing the relative income gap with the advanced OECD economies back toward its initial 1989 level. By 2001, every transition economy had an even larger relative income gap with the advanced economies than had existed in 1989. What is the magnitude of the income gap? At 1999 exchange rates, GDP per capita ranged from $620 in Ukraine to $1,250 in Russia, $4,070 in Poland, $5,200 in the Czech Republic and $10,000 in Slovenia (EBRD, 2000). Comparable figures for the United States, the 15 European Union countries and Japan were $33,900, $22,560 and $32,600, respectively. The gap between the poor and rich countries is of course reduced when calculated in terms of purchasing power parity, but nonetheless, for most transition economies, the enormous absolute and relative income gaps will take decades to close. Note that since these income gap figures refer to almost one decade after price liberalization, they do not suffer from mismeasurement of inflation, as may have been the case in the early transition. The depth and length of the early transition depression was unexpected. A number of explanations have been offered: tight macroeconomic policies (Bha- 8 Journal of Economic Perspectives duri, Kaski and Levcik, 1993; Rosati, 1994); a credit crunch stemming from the reduction of state subsidies to firms and rise in real interest rates (Calvo and Coricelli, 1992); disorganization among suppliers, producers and consumers associated with the collapse of central planning (Blanchard and Kremer, 1997; Roland and Verdier, 1999); a switch from controlled to uncontrolled monopolistic structure in these economies (Li, 1999; Blanchard, 1997); difficulties of sectoral shifts in the presence of labor market imperfections (Atkeson and Kehoe, 1996); and the dissolution in 1990 of the Council for Mutual Economic Assistance (CMEA), which governed trade relations across the Soviet bloc nations. While each explanation contains a grain of truth, none is in itself completely convincing. All countries have gone through the decline, yet cross-country differences in initial conditions and the nature of reform are substantial enough to make one question the universal applicability of any single explanation. No explanation has strong empirical support across the board. What factors account for the persistent growth in Poland, Hungary, Slovakia and Slovenia since the early to mid-1990s, as compared to the recession experienced in the second half of the 1990s by the Czech Republic, Bulgaria and Romania, and the continuous decline in Russia and the other CIS countries? Again, no single explanation suffices. Geography alone does not explain the outcomes, as the western-most country, the Czech Republic, did much worse in the second half of the 1990s than countries further east, such as Hungary, Poland and Slovakia. In Figure 1 Real GDP Percentage Change Index (1989 ϭ Base) Sources: William Davidson Institute, based on OECD Economic Outlook, July 2001; EBRD Transition Report 2001 Update; and Davidson Institute staff calculations. Jan Svejnar 9 fact, the evolution of Czech GDP in the second half of the 1990s resembles that of Bulgaria and Romania. The extent to which countries pursued a combination of key Type II reforms provides some explanatory power. The four leading transition economies shown in Figure 1—Poland, Slovenia, Hungary and Slovakia—have pursued a relatively complete set of reforms, including maintaining relatively clear property rights and corporate governance. For example, Hungary and, to a lesser extent, Slovakia privatized most state-owned enterprises in a way that assigned clear property rights to the new owners. Poland and Slovenia proceeded more slowly with privatization, but both countries exposed the state-owned enterprises to competition and a risk of financial failure. In all four economies, the substantial creation of new private firms also contributed to growth. Other countries have carried out much more limited Type II reforms. The Czech Republic is notable because it was similar to the four leading economies, but it grossly neglected the need to establish a functioning legal framework and corporate governance of firms and banks. The privatization experience of the Czech Republic, Russia and Ukraine also suggests that mass privatization in the absence of a functioning legal system has strong negative effects on performance. The situation in Russia and other CIS economies has been further aggravated by the political and economic disintegration of the Soviet Union, including attempted coups, a greater presence of organized crime and the spread of aggressive rent seeking and corruption. Inflation A number of the transition economies experienced high inflation or hyperinflation as the communist system disintegrated. Poland, Slovenia, Albania, Bulgaria and Romania all experienced at least one year from 1990 to 1993 when consumer price inflation exceeded 200 percent; Estonia, Latvia and Lithuania all had one year with inflation around 1000 percent; and Russia, Ukraine and Kazakhstan experienced at least one year when inflation was above 2000 percent. Sometimes these bouts of inflation arose after lifting price controls; in other cases, the inflation grew out of financial sector crises. However, by the later part of the 1990s, Type I reforms had shown that they could reduce inflation rates with speed and effectiveness. The first column of Table 1 shows rates of inflation for a selected group of transition countries. The first group of countries are in central Europe, the second set represents the northern part of eastern Europe (Baltic countries), the third set represents the southern part of eastern Europe (Balkan countries), the fourth set represents Russia and other countries in the Commonwealth of Independent States; and the final panel offers some comparisons from the western European economies and the United States. By 2001, inflation rates in many transition economies were in single digits. Even countries that experienced very high rates of inflation during the 1990s—Russia, Ukraine, Kazakhstan and Bulgaria, for example—had inflation rates in the range of 9 to 35 percent by 2001. This outcome is 10 Journal of Economic Perspectives important because annual inflation of 40 percent or less does not seem to have a major negative impact on economic growth and consumer welfare (Bruno and Easterly, 1995; Fischer, Sahay and Vegh, 1996). Exchange Rates and Current Account Most transition economies devalued their currency as a means of export promotion and adopted a fixed exchange rate as part of macroeconomic stabilization. They also significantly reoriented their foreign trade away from the old Council for Mutual Economic Assistance arrangements and toward market economies. However, as domestic inflation exceeded world inflation in the 1990s, the Table 1 Current Macroeconomic Indicators Consumer Price Inflation (%) 2001 Current Account Balance (% of GDP) 2001 External Debt (% of GDP) 2000 Government Budget Balance (% of GDP) 2001 Private Sector Share (% of GDP) 2000 Unemployment (%) 2000 Central Europe Czech Republic 4.6 Ϫ5.1 46.5 Ϫ9.2 80 8.9 Hungary 9.4 Ϫ5.4 67.8 Ϫ3.5 80 6.5 Poland 6.6 Ϫ6.0 42.8 Ϫ3.0 70 16.1 Slovak Republic 7.1 Ϫ3.8 53.5 Ϫ4.0 75 18.6 Baltic Countries Slovenia 7.7 Ϫ3.0 33.4 Ϫ1.3 55 7.0 Estonia 6.2 Ϫ7.7 63.0 Ϫ0.5 75 13.7 Latvia 3.3 Ϫ7.1 66.2 Ϫ2.0 65 14.3 Lithuania 2.0 Ϫ6.4 43.8 Ϫ1.4 70 16.1 Balkan Countries Albania 4.0 Ϫ6.3 29.1 Ϫ9.2 75 17.1 Bulgaria 8.0 Ϫ5.2 86.0 Ϫ1.5 70 16.2 Romania 35.0 Ϫ3.9 27.8 Ϫ4.0 60 7.2 Commonwealth of Independent States Kazakhstan 8.7 2.0 67.6 Ϫ1.5 60 6.3 Russia 22.4 10.2 62.0 0.0 70 10.0 Ukraine 16.0 1.4 33.2 Ϫ3.0 60 4.2 Comparison Economies European Union 1.8 Ϫ0.4 na Ϫ0.2 na 8.2 United States 2.6 Ϫ4.2 na 1.5 na 4.0 Notes: Data for 2000 are estimates and 2001 are projections. Sources: Data in the first five columns are from: William Davidson Institute, based on EBRD Transition Report, various issues; IMF World Economic Outlook, May 2001; OECD Economic Outlook, July 2001; UN Transition at a Glance 2001; World Bank World Development Indicators 2001; and EIU-Datastream. Data for column six is from William Davidson Institute, based on ILO (2000), World Bank (2001), EBRD various issues, and OECD (2001), based on labor force surveys. Russian data from Sabirianova and Earle (2001) using LFS figures, reported in Goskomstat (2000c), Goskomstat (1999a) and OECD (2000). Kazahkstan value for 1999. Unless otherwise indicated, the data are generally annual averages of monthly, quarterly, or semiannual data. For full source information, see ͗http://www.wdi.bus.umich.edu͘. Transition Economies: Performance and Challenges 11 fixed exchange rates often became overvalued, leading in some cases to substantial current account deficits. For instance, Russia, Albania, Kazakhstan and Bulgaria all had at least one year between 1990 and 1993 when the current account deficit was 10 percent of GDP or greater. Most countries responded by devaluing their currencies again and adopting more flexible exchange rate regimes, although Bulgaria, Estonia and Lithuania have fixed their exchange rate through currency boards as a means of long-term economic stabilization. The second column of Table 1 shows that central and eastern Europe now has current account deficits of moderate size, which would be expected for countries that are seeking to attract a net inflow of foreign investment capital. However, Russia and the other economies of the Commonwealth of Independent States are often significant exporters of natural resources and are experiencing a net outflow of investment funds, as shown by their current account surpluses. External Debt and Financial Crises A number of transition countries started the 1990s with high foreign indebtedness. In Bulgaria, Hungary and Poland, external debt exceeded 50 percent of GDP in 1990. In Russia, external debt in 1990 was a whopping 148 percent of GDP. Other transition economies, such as Romania, Slovenia, the Czech Republic and Slovakia, had conservative regimes where foreign debt was less than 20 percent of GDP in 1990. These different initial conditions greatly affected the subsequent performance of these countries. For instance, high-debt Poland succeeded in renegotiating its debt, while high-debt Hungary serviced its debt in full. The Hungarian approach imposed a heavy fiscal burden and induced a number of policies, including the revenue-oriented form of large-scale privatization. By the mid-1990s, most of the highly indebted countries reduced their debt relative to GDP, while a number of the less indebted countries raised theirs. But since about 1996, foreign indebtedness appears to have risen in the relatively more indebted countries, especially Hungary and Russia. Indeed, Russia defaulted on its sovereign debt in 1998. Interestingly, while the Russian financial crisis had a major impact on the CIS countries that still have close trading relationships with Russia, it had relatively little impact on the countries of central and eastern Europe or on the Baltic nations, which had already reoriented most of their trade and commercial relationships to western Europe. The third column of Table 1 shows external debt as a share of GDP in 2000. All the countries in the table have external debt in excess of 25 percent of GDP, but leaving aside Bulgaria, none have external debt higher than 70 percent of GDP. This level of external debt is in line with a number of other developing and some developed countries. Unless accompanied by other destabilizing factors, such as a high proportion of short-term debt that may suddenly not be refinanced as investor sentiment shifts (as was the case in Russia), this level of debt is not especially alarming. 12 Journal of Economic Perspectives Budget and Taxes Since under communism the government owned almost everything, taxes and expenditures were transfers among centrally determined activities. The principal taxes were a tax on turnover (inputs plus output), along with other taxes on enterprises and payroll taxes. Tax rates changed often; indeed, in some countries, tax liabilities seemed more a matter of negotiation than a requirement (Tanzi and Tsibournes, 2000). Since most taxes were collected at the enterprise level, many citizens were unaware of the heavy tax burden in the communist economies and thus have resented the explicit taxes that have been introduced during the transition. As the transition unfolded, governments had to develop new fiscal institutions for collecting taxes. This institutional development was one of the hardest Type II reforms to achieve. While tax collection has been relatively effective in central and eastern Europe, Russia and some other countries of the Commonwealth of Independent States have faced significant declines in tax revenue, as many producers have been operating through barter and accumulating tax arrears. At the same time, the governments have been facing numerous public expenditures, including infrastructure and the new social safety net. The relative inability of Russia and the CIS nations to collect taxes is one reason why their social safety nets have been much weaker than those in central and eastern Europe. Many of the transition economies, especially those in central and eastern Europe, have higher tax rates than other countries at a similar level of GDP per capita. The highest tax burdens—35 percent to 42 percent of GDP—are found in central Europe among the most advanced economic reformers, who rely primarily on the payroll tax, value-added tax and personal income tax to finance government programs (Tanzi and Tsiboures, 2000). The relatively high ratios of taxes to GDP in transition economies have not prevented governments of many of these countries from running budget deficits. Thus, Albania, Bulgaria, the Czech Republic, Hungary, Lithuania, Kazakhstan, Russia, Slovakia and Ukraine have in a number of years had annual budget deficits in excess of 5 percent of GDP. The fourth column of Table 1 shows government budget balance as a share of GDP in 2001. The patterns in public revenues and expenditures reflect local factors as well as the mixed advice that the transition economies received from western countries and institutions. The International Monetary Fund and the World Bank have generally advised the transition economies to aim for balanced government budgets or to run only small budget deficits while increasing the size of the private sector and reducing the role of the government. The European Union also placed emphasis on low budget deficits and imposed a 3 percent upper bound on the size of the deficit relative to GDP as a precondition for entry into the union. However, the European Union also requires that countries applying for EU membership adopt a number of relatively costly social programs and structural measures, which places upward pressure on government expenditures. An especially problematic aspect of the public finances in many transition economies is the increasing strain from the pension system. The countries of Jan Svejnar 13 central and eastern Europe entered the transition with publicly funded pension systems, almost universal coverage of the population, low retirement ages (on average 60 for men and 55 for women), a high and growing ratio of retirees to workers, high payroll tax contribution levels and high levels of promised benefits relative to recently earned preretirement wages (World Bank, 1994; Svejnar, 1997). Moreover, most of these systems practice a perverse redistribution of benefits from lower-income workers to higher-income workers. The promises of these systems, which are largely pay-as-you-go, are not sustainable. Several countries, including Hungary, Poland, Latvia and Kazakhstan, have already moved to raise the retirement age and to supplement the public retirement system by a multipillar public/ private retirement system with a funded component. Russia and other CIS countries face less of a public sector burden with regard to retirement costs, because the level of government-promised retirement benefits is lower. Given the fiscal pressure under which most of the transition economies operate, it is interesting to note that their governments have collected very little revenue from privatization (Tanzi and Tsiboures, 2000). The average in central and eastern Europe, as well as in the former Soviet Union, was only about 5 percent of GDP. Hungary, which was most revenue oriented in its privatization, generated a total of about 14 percent of GDP, which is still a very modest figure when spread over several years. Privatization and Creation of New Firms In the early 1990s, most transition economies rapidly privatized small enterprises as part of their Type I reforms. This small-scale privatization was done mostly through local auctions. It was instrumental in creating small- and medium-sized enterprises in countries where most firms were, by ideological and practical design, either large or very large. Casual evidence suggests that this shift in ownership increased efficiency and quality of production. Parallel developments were the breakups of state-owned enterprises (which contributed to the growth in the number of firms), restructuring of firms and management and increased competition. Breakups of small, average and somewhat above-average size enterprises appear to have increased efficiency of both the remaining master enterprises and the spun-off units (Lizal, Singer and Svejnar, 2001). Some of the broken-up firms were then privatized. A large number of new (mostly small) firms were founded. These firms filled niches in demand and started to compete with existing state-owned enterprises and with imports. The growth of new firms has varied across countries. In general, it proceeded more quickly and smoothly in central Europe than in eastern Europe and the Commonwealth of Independent States. Gomulka (1994) and others attribute much of the success of the Polish economy to the rising production in the new firms. Finally, in most countries, the majority of private assets were generated through large-scale privatization, which differed in its method across countries. What is remarkable, however, is how quickly most countries generated private 14 Journal of Economic Perspectives ownership, irrespective of the particular privatization methods used. In 1990, the private sector had perhaps 20 to 25 percent of GDP in Hungary and Poland, but typically only 5 to 10 percent of GDP in other transition economies. But these figures increased very quickly. As early as 1994, the private sector was more than 30 percent of GDP in all of the transition economies and represented half or more of GDP in many countries, including Russia. The fifth column of Table 1 shows that by 2000 the private sector share of GDP was at or above 60 percent in all of the transition economies except Slovenia and in most of them it constituted 70 to 80 percent. The effect of privatization on economic performance is surprisingly hard to determine. At the country level, some of the fastest growing economies (Poland, Slovenia and also China) have been among the slowest to privatize. In a cross-country econometric study, Sachs, Zinnes and Eilat (2000) find that privatization does not by itself increase GDP growth, but they find a positive effect when privatization is accompanied by in-depth institutional reforms. Four recent surveys make a range of assessments: finding no systematically significant effect of privatization on performance (Bevan, Estrin and Schaffer, 1999); concluding cautiously that privatization improves firm performance (Megginson and Netter, 2001); and being fairly confident that privatization tends to improve performance (Shirley and Walsh, 2000; Djankov and Murrell, 2000). Clearly, the results are not conclusive. Many of the microeconometric studies suffer from serious problems: small and unrepresentative samples of firms; misreported or mismeasured data; limited controls for other major shocks that occurred at the same time as privatization; a short period of observations after privatization; and, above all, not controlling adequately for selectivity bias. Selectivity bias is likely to be a particularly serious problem, since better performing firms tend to be privatized first (Gupta, Ham and Svejnar, 2001). Thus, comparing the post-privatization performance of privatized firms to the performance of the remaining state-owned firms without controlling for selectivity bias, as many studies do, will erroneously attribute the superior performance of the privatized firms to privatization. Domestic and Foreign Investment The communist countries, like the east Asian tigers, were known for high rates of investment, often exceeding 30 percent of GDP. These investment rates slowed down to about 30 percent in the 1980s in a number of countries as governments yielded to public pressure for more consumer goods. The investment rates declined further to about 20 percent of GDP in the 1990s in a number of transition economies (EBRD, 1996), although countries such as the Czech and Slovak Republics maintained relatively high levels of investment. Unfortunately, much of this investment appears to have been allocated inefficiently—by the monobank system through the 1980s and by the inexperienced and often politicized or corrupt commercial banks in the 1990s (Lizal and Svejnar, 2002). Indeed, trends in foreign Transition Economies: Performance and Challenges 15 direct investment may provide a better measure of the attractiveness of investment in the transition economies than domestic investment figures. As Figure 2 shows, until 1997, Hungary was the only transition economy receiving a significant flow of foreign direct investment. Analysts usually attribute this success to the fact that Hungary was more hospitable to and had well-defined rules and regulations for foreign direct investment since the early 1980s. Starting in 1998, major foreign investments went to the Czech Republic, Poland and Slovakia. However, many countries of eastern Europe remain, along with Russia, rather unattractive to foreign direct investment. The rate of foreign direct investment appears to increase with several factors: the proximity of the perceived date of accession of a given country to the European Union; the desirability of the country’s political, economic and legal environment; and the availability of attractive privatization projects in the country. Employment Adjustment, Wage Setting and Unemployment State-owned enterprises in all the transition economies rapidly decreased employment and/or real wages in the early 1990s (Svejnar, 1999). In central Europe, the greatest initial reduction in industrial employment occurred in Hungary (over 20 percent), followed by Slovakia (over 13 percent), Poland (over 10 percent) and the Czech Republic (9 percent). The downward adjustment in industrial wages proceeded in reverse order and amounted to 24 percent in the Czech Republic, 21 percent in Slovakia and 1 percent in Poland. Hungarian real wages in industry actually rose by 17 percent (Basu, Estrin and Svejnar, 2000). In Russia and the rest of CIS, the adjustment brought a mixture of wage and employment adjustment (Desai and Idson, 2000), and the wage decline was more pronounced than in central and eastern Europe (Boeri and Terrell, this issue). As Basu, Estrin and Svejnar (1997, 2000) show, labor demand elasticities with respect to output and wages were significant in the more market-oriented pretransition economies, and they rose rapidly in central Europe as transition was launched. Depending on the institutional setting in a given country, the sharp decline in output at the start of the transition was hence absorbed more by employment or wage decreases. Figure 3 shows that in most transition economies, the employment decline reached 15 percent to 30 percent in the 1990s. A continuous decline is observed in Russia, Slovakia and Romania; an L-shaped pattern detected in Bulgaria, Hungary and Slovenia; a U-shaped pattern in Poland; and a sideways S-shaped pattern in the Czech Republic. When combined with the GDP data in Figure 1, the employment data suggest that restructuring in the transition economies involved an initial decline in labor productivity as output fell faster than employment and a subsequent rise in productivity as output and labor stopped declining. But a note of caution is in order here. With production shifting from large to small firms, the decline in employment (and output) may be less pronounced than suggested by the official data, since small firms are harder to capture in official statistics. Unemployment was unknown before the transition, but it emerged rapidly in 16 Journal of Economic Perspectives central and eastern European countries, except for the Czech Republic. Within two years after the start of the transition, the unemployment rate rose into double digits in most economies of central and eastern Europe. By 1993, for example, the unemployment rate reached 16 percent in Bulgaria and Poland, 12 percent in Hungary and Slovakia, 10 percent in Romania, 9 percent in Slovenia, but only 3.5 percent in the Czech Republic. The high unemployment rates reflected high rates of inflow into unemployment as firms laid off workers and relatively low outflow rates from unemployment as the unemployed found it hard to find new jobs. The Czech labor market was an ideal model of a transition labor market, characterized by high inflows as well as outflows, with unemployment representing a transitory state between old and new jobs (Ham, Svejnar and Terrell, 1998, 1999; Svejnar, 1999; Boeri, 2000). Unemployment rose more slowly in the Commonwealth of Independent States and the Baltic countries, as firms were slower to lay off workers and used wage declines and arrears as devices to hold on to workers. In 1993, for example, unemployment in Russia and Estonia still hovered near 6 percent. Over time, the patterns of unemployment have shown considerable differentiation. The Czech Republic was the only central European country to enter recession in the second half of the 1990s, and its unemployment rate correspondingly rose to 8 percent. The fast-growing economies of Poland, Hungary, Slovenia and, to a lesser extent, Slovakia managed to reduce their unemployment rates in Figure 2 Foreign Direct Investment Per Capita (net inflows in U.S. dollars recorded in the balance of payments, per capita) Sources: William Davidson Institute, based on EBRD Transition Report 2001 Update, World Bank Development Indicators 2001 and Davidson Institute staff calculations. Jan Svejnar 17 the late 1990s. Conversely, the Commonwealth of Independent States and the Baltic countries experienced gradual increases in unemployment as their transition proceeded. By 1997, unemployment rates in Russia and Estonia were near 10 percent. By 1999–2000, the unemployment rate rose again in Bulgaria, the Czech Republic, Poland, Slovakia and Slovenia. It stabilized in countries such as Hungary, Romania and Russia. As may be seen in column 6 of Table 1, with the exception of Hungary, Slovenia and Romania, transition economies in 2000 had relatively high unemployment rates that are at least as high as, and often significantly exceed, those observed in the European Union. While real wages in central and eastern Europe have increased by about 15 percent to 20 percent after their initial 25 percent decline in the 1989–1991 period, in Russia and a number of other CIS countries real wages declined until 1993 and stagnated or increased only moderately thereafter (Svejnar, 1999; EBRD, 2000). The trajectory of real incomes has thus been very different in the more- and less-advanced transition economies. The reduction in employment in the old state-owned firms along with the rise in unemployment and establishment of new firms have brought about considerable destruction and creation of jobs, as well as mobility of labor. Contrary to the main Figure 3 Employment Index (1989 ϭ base) Source: William Davidson Institute, based on U.N. Economic Commission for Europe, Statistical Division. 18 Journal of Economic Perspectives models of the transition process, Jurajda and Terrell (2001) show that job creation in new firms is not necessarily tightly linked to job destruction in the old firms, since many new jobs have been created even in economies (such as the Czech Republic) that experienced low rates of job destruction. Sabirianova (2000) provides a related structural insight that much of the labor mobility consisted of occupational rather than geographic change, with individuals moving from one occupation to another within regions, as jobs in old occupations were destroyed and opportunities in new occupations were created. Compared to the U.S. labor market, where individuals move more geographically than occupationally, the transition has led to more occupational rather than geographic mobility. Data on income distribution, expressed in the form of Gini coefficients, are summarized in Table 2.3 The communist countries had highly egalitarian income distributions. In central and eastern Europe, the Gini coefficients ranged from 20 in Czechoslovakia and Slovenia to 25 in Poland in the late 1980s. The 1988 Ukrainian Gini coefficient of 23 (based on survey data) and the 1991 Russian coefficient of 26 based on the registry wage data of the Russian Statistical Office (Goskomstat) suggest that income distribution was relatively egalitarian in the former Soviet Union as well. However, inequality increased during the 1990s, with the Gini coefficient reaching 26–34 in central and eastern Europe, 30 in Ukraine and 40 in Russia. These coefficients bring inequality in the transition economies into the range spanned by capitalist economies from the relatively egalitarian Sweden to the relatively inegalitarian United States and in line with developing countries such as India. However, while the central and eastern European data seem to reflect reality, the Russian and Ukrainian data may well understate the extent of inequality. In particular, the Goskomstat data are based on wages that firms are supposed to be paying to workers, but many Russian firms have not been paying contractual wages (Desai and Idson, 2000). In Table 2, a second row for Russia and Ukraine shows inequality based on survey data from the Russian Longitudinal Monitoring Survey of households. These data suggest that income inequality in Russia and Ukraine has reached much higher levels—a Gini coefficient of 47–50—which resembles the level of inequality found in developing economies with the most inegalitarian distribution of income, like Brazil. The relatively egalitarian structure of income distribution in central and eastern European countries has been brought about by their social safety nets, which rolled back inequality that would have been brought about by market forces alone (Garner and Terrell, 1998). Conversely, the Russian social safety net has been regressive—it has made the distribution of income more unequal than it would have been without it (Commander, Tolstopiatenko and Yemtsov, 1999). 3 The Gini coefficient varies from 0 to 100, with 0 representing a perfectly egalitarian distribution of income (every individual or household receiving the same income) and 100 denoting the most inegalitarian distribution (one person or household receiving all income). Transition Economies: Performance and Challenges 19 Life Expectancy A number of social indicators suggest that average living standards improved moderately during the transition in central Europe, improved slightly in the Baltic countries, remained about the same or declined slightly in the Balkan countries not involved in wars and declined in Russia and the CIS. The data on life expectancy presented in Table 3 display this pattern. For comparison, between 1989 and 1999, life expectancy at birth increased by about two years from 75 to 76.9 years in the United States and from 76.5 to 78.5 years in France. During the same period, life expectancy increased by one to three years in most central European countries; increased slightly in the Baltic countries; declined slightly in Albania, Bulgaria and Romania; and declined by 3.5 years in Russia, over three years in Ukraine and almost four years in Kazakhstan. The decline in life expectancy in Russia, Ukraine and Kazakhstan during the transition hence represents a major break from increasing life expectancies in the past. Disaggregated data indicate that the decline in life expectancy in the CIS countries is largely due to the early deaths of middle-aged males, who are presumably more exposed to stress and resort to heavy alcohol consumption. Table 2 Income Inequality: Gini Coefficients Late 1980s Early 1990s Late 1990s Year Gini Year Gini Year Gini Central Europe Czech Republic 1988 20.0 1992 23.0 1996 26.0 Hungary 1987 24.4 1992 26.0 1998 25.3 Poland 1987 25.0 1993 29.8 1998 32.7 Slovak Republic 1988 19.5 1993 21.5 1996 26.3 Slovenia 1987 19.8 1993 24.1 1996 26.1 Baltic Countries Estonia 1987–90 24.0 1993–94 35.0 1996–99 37.0 Latvia 1987–90 24.0 1995 31.0 1996–99 32.0 Lithuania 1987–90 23.0 1993–94 33.0 1996–99 34.0 Balkan Countries Bulgaria 1989 21.7 1993 33.3 1997 34.1 Romania 1989 23.3 1994 28.6 1997 30.5 Commonwealth of Independent States Russiaa 1991 26.0 1993 39.8 2000 39.9 Russiab 1992 54.3 1994 45.5 1996 51.8 Ukrainea — na 1996 33.4 1999 30.0 Ukraineb 1988 23.3 1995 47.0 — na Notes: a based on Goskomstat data; b based on survey data. Sources: William Davidson Institute based on various sources and Davidson Institute staff calculations. See the following website for full source information: ͗http://www.wdi.bus.umich.edu͘. Gini ϭ ¥j ϭ 1 n ¥i ϭ 1 n ͉yi Ϫ yj͉ 2n2 y៮ , where yi is income of person i, y៮ is mean income, and n is the number of persons. 20 Journal of Economic Perspectives Fertility Fertility data in Table 3 indicate that the number of births per woman declined dramatically in virtually all the transition economies in the 1990s, as compared to the counterpart numbers in western countries and to the trend in the 1980s. As of 1989, the transition and western countries had similar ranges of fertility rates, from 1.5 in Slovenia to 2.2 in Romania among the transition countries, and from 1.4 in Germany to 2.0 in the United States. In the 1990s, fertility rates declined modestly in western Europe and rose slightly in the United States. In contrast, in Russia and Ukraine, the fertility rates plummeted from about 2 to 1.3. The rate of decline is substantial in all the other transition economies. Marriage and Divorce Rates As may be seen from Table 4, marriage rates have been declining over time in most western as well as transition economies. Moreover, marriage rates in continental European countries have traditionally been lower than in the United Table 3 Life Expectancy and Fertility Life Expectancy at Birth (total years) Fertility rate (total births per woman) 1980 1989 1999 1980 1989 1999 Central Europe Czech Republic 70.3 71.7 74.6 2.07 1.87 1.17 Hungary 69.5 69.5 70.6 1.91 1.78 1.32 Poland 70.1 71.0 73.2 2.28 2.08 1.40 Slovak Republic 70.4 71.0 72.7 2.31 2.08 1.37 Slovenia 70.3 72.7 75.1 2.08 1.52 1.24 Baltic Countries Estonia 69.1 70.1 70.6 2.02 2.21 1.23 Latvia 69.1 70.1 69.8 2.00 2.05 1.11 Lithuania 70.7 71.5 72.1 1.97 1.98 1.35 Balkan Countries Albania 69.3 72.5 72.1 3.62 3.00 2.40 Bulgaria 71.4 71.8 71.1 2.05 1.90 1.13 Romania 69.1 69.5 69.5 2.43 2.20 1.32 Commonwealth of Independent States Kazakhstan 66.6 68.3 64.8 2.90 2.82 2.00 Russia 67.1 69.3 65.8 1.88 2.01 1.25 Ukraine 69.2 70.5 67.3 1.99 1.99 1.30 Comparison Countries France 74.3 76.5 78.5 1.95 1.79 1.77 Germany 72.6 — 77.0 1.44 1.42 1.35 United Kingdom 73.8 — 77.2 1.89 1.80 1.71 United States 73.66 75.02 76.91 1.84 2.01 2.06 Sources: William Davidson Institute, based on the World Bank World Development Indicators 2001, and the Global Market Information Database. Jan Svejnar 21 Kingdom and United States. But the rate of decline in marriage rates accelerated in most transition economies. In 1989, marriage rates in the Soviet republics and the Czech part of Czechoslovakia were in a range of 8 percent to 10 percent. By 2000, these transition economies recorded marriage rates of 3.3 percent to 6 percent. Conversely, the data in Table 4 indicate that the propensity to divorce does not seem to have been much affected by the transition. Indeed, while divorce rates rose in western European countries in the 1990s, they declined in many transition economies, including Bulgaria, Estonia, Latvia, Kazakhstan, Russia and Ukraine. Hence, while one might expect that the psychological stress and economic hardship of the transition would result in increased breakups of families, on the whole this has not been the case. The transition appears to have had a strong negative effect on marriage formation and fertility, but it has not destroyed existing marriages. Table 4 Marriage and Divorce Rates Marriage Rates (per 1000 inhabitants) Divorce Rate (per 1000 inhabitants) 1980 1989 2000 1980 1989 2000 Central Europe Czech Republic 7.6 8.6 4.3 2.6 3.0 3.1 Hungary 7.5 6.3 4.6 2.6 2.4 2.6 Poland 8.6 6.8 3.6 1.1 1.2 1.2 Slovak Republic 7.9 7.6 5.0 1.3 1.6 1.6 Slovenia 6.5 4.9 3.7 1.2 1.1 1.1 Baltic Countries Estonia 8.8 8.1 3.5 4.1 3.8 3.2 Latvia 9.8 9.0 3.3 5.0 4.2 2.5 Lithuania 9.2 9.4 5.0 3.2 3.3 3.3 Balkan Countries Albania — — — — — — Bulgaria 7.9 7.0 4.0 1.5 1.4 1.2 Romania 8.2 7.7 5.9 1.5 1.6 1.9 Commonwealth of Independent States Kazakhstan — 10.0 6.0 — 2.8 2.2 Russia 10.6 9.4 5.0 4.2 4.0 3.1 Ukraine 9.3 9.5 6.0 — 3.7 3.5 Comparison Countries France 6.2 5.0 4.9 1.5 1.9 2.0 Germany 6.3 — 5.4 1.8 2.0 2.4 United Kingdom 14.8 14.0 10.6 2.8 2.9 3.2 United States 10.5 9.7 8.5 5.2 4.7 4.6 Sources: William Davidson Institute, based on the World Bank World Development Indicators 2001, and the Global Market Information Database. 22 Journal of Economic Perspectives Attitudes People’s attitudes toward the transition provide interesting information that complements the evidence on behavior. Table 5 presents several findings from a 1999 study carried out by the Public Opinion Research Center (1999) on national random samples of 1,018 individuals in the Czech Republic, 1,523 individuals in Hungary and 1,111 individuals in Poland. These three countries are the most advanced transition economies. They have succeeded in joining OECD and NATO, and they are among the five front-runners for admission to the European Union. However, the findings reflect quite negative attitudes toward the benefits of the transition during the 1989–1999 decade. In all three countries, the majority of individuals feel that it was worthwhile to change the political and economic system, with the largest majority (67 percent) being found in Poland, where the political revolts in the 1980s were the strongest and the GDP growth in the 1990s the fastest. However, in each country many more people believe that the losses from transition exceeded the gains rather than the reverse. Similarly, in each country, more respondents feel that their “material conditions of living are now a little worse” rather than the reverse. The attitudinal survey hence provides a sobering assessment of how people in the most advanced transition economies feel about the benefits and costs of the transition. It is likely that the sentiment in the more poorly performing countries is even more pessimistic. Assessment The performance of the former Soviet bloc economies during the first twelve years of the transition has been disappointing. While many important structural transformations have taken place, the relative gap in per capita income between these countries and the advanced economies has widened. A major problem for the transition economies was clearly the initial recession that set them back relative to the advanced economies. In Russia, Ukraine and other CIS countries, this depression lasted almost a decade. Transition countries further east have on average performed worse than their more western counterparts, which suggests that geography-related initial conditions have been important in the transition process. The central European countries, located most to the west among the transition economies, have historically shared the same alphabet and religions, had similar educational and bureaucratic systems, and intensively traded and otherwise interacted with countries in western Europe. They, together with the Balkan countries, were under the Soviet system for only four decades, as compared to five decades in the case of the Baltic countries and seven decades in the countries of the Commonwealth of Independent States. Finally, the countries of central Europe were the first to aspire and be encouraged to prepare for entry to the European Union. The physical proximity and sense of historical belonging to Europe hence seems to have provided an important advantage for the “western” transition economies in moving from the Soviet-style system to a democratic and market-oriented system. However, Transition Economies: Performance and Challenges 23 the fact that the western-most transition economy, the Czech Republic, has performed worse than others since the mid-1990s indicates that geography does not provide a complete explanation and that policies do matter.4 4 An interesting counterfactual approach to assessing the validity of initial conditions versus policies as explanations is to ask how an aggressive effort by western countries would have affected the transition. For example, consider East Germany, which received enormous capital inflows from West Germany ($80–100 billion annually) to build modern infrastructure and also received a modern legal and institutional infrastructure by absorption into a united Germany. However, West Germany also feared a flood of businesses to low-wage East Germany and a flood of East Germans coming west for higher wages and welfare benefits. It thus passed a set of rules that raised labor cost per worker in eastern Germany from about 10 percent of the western German level to about 80 percent. This dramatic jump in labor cost, combined with relatively low labor productivity, made firms in eastern Germany retrench and forced many of them out of existence. Since the early 1990s, open and disguised unemployment in eastern Germany has been at about twice the level of unemployment in the central European transition economies. Any substantial western plan to assist transition countries would have offered lower subsidies and created less legal and institutional reform than occurred in East Germany, although the effects of such financial subsidies, institutional reforms and market access could nonetheless have been substantial. But such a plan might also have involved restrictions on labor leaving the transition economies or Table 5 Attitudes Toward Transition Question Country Responses Yes No Difficult to say From a temporal perspective, do you think that it was worthwhile to change the political and economic system? Czech Republic 55% 32% 13% Hungary 46% 40% 13% Poland 67% 24% 12% More gains than losses The same More losses than gains Difficult to say Have the changes taking place in your country since 1989 brought people more losses than gains? Czech Republic 23% 42% 31% 4% Hungary 15% 28% 45% 12% Poland 24% 30% 37% 8% Please compare your present situation with the situation before 1989 and say whether: A little better Neither better nor worse A little worse Difficult to say The opportunities of having an impact on the political life in the country are now: Czech Republic 20% 37% 20% 23% Hungary 41% 29% 14% 16% Poland 30% 44% 14% 12% Material conditions of living Czech Republic 30% 29% 33% 8% are now: Hungary 12% 16% 66% 6% Poland 25% 19% 46% 10% Your life is now generally: Czech Republic 35% 30% 29% 6% Hungary 18% 27% 49% 6% Poland 28% 23% 40% 9% Source: Public Opinion Research Center (1999). 24 Journal of Economic Perspectives Interestingly, the initial conditions had little impact on whether the countries carried out Type I reforms—macroeconomic stabilization, price liberalization, reduction of direct subsidies, breakup of trusts, state-owned enterprises and the monobank system, removal of barriers to the creation of new firms, carrying out small-scale privatization and introduction of a social safety net—which all transition economies carried out quickly. However, initial conditions did affect Type II reforms: large-scale privatization, further (in-depth) development of a commercial banking sector and effective tax system, labor market regulations and institutions related to the social safety net, and establishment and enforcement of a marketoriented legal system and accompanying institutions. The reform of greatest importance seems to be that countries that placed emphasis on the development of a functioning legal framework and corporate governance of firms, like Hungary, Poland and Slovenia, have performed better than those that did not, like the Czech Republic, Russia and Ukraine. On a related note, evidence suggests that large-scale privatization can be handled in a variety of ways, or even delayed, as long as the state-owned firms face the discipline of needing to earn their way without government bailouts and as long as new firms appear through new creation, breakups of old firms and foreign investment. When Will the Transition be Over? Since transition is a process, it is natural to ask when it is likely to be completed. The answer depends on how one defines the terminal point. A number of analysts are on record on this issue and their definitions differ considerably. Janos Kornai (1999) views the end of transition as a situation in which the communist parties have lost monopoly political power, the private sector accounts for the majority of GDP and the market is the dominant coordinator of economic activities. According to this sensible definition, rooted in a radical shift in political power and a fundamental structural change in the economy, the transition is in most countries over—and has been so for the last five years. From a different angle, Alan Gelb (1999) sees the end of transition as a state when the problems and the policy issues confronted by today’s “transition countries” resemble those faced by other countries at similar levels of development. This definition relies on notions of economic development and also makes good sense. Based on this definition, one may also argue that the transition is over. The fact that private sector analysts such as Morgan Stanley and publications such as The Economist increasingly place advanced transition countries into the general category of “emerging market economies” also supports this point of view. But whatever the logic of these arguments, most citizens of the transition demands that expensive social programs be enacted. Likely results would have been a faster rise in living standards for the employed, higher unemployment rates and more unequal income distributions in transition economies. The overall effect on economic growth and other performance indicators would have depended on which effects dominated. Jan Svejnar 25 countries do not feel that they have accomplished the transition. I believe that this is because most have been implicitly equating the transition with a process that will make them partners with the relatively advanced countries in the world in general and with western Europe in particular. Taking this aspect into account, I would define the end of transition as a state when these economies replace central planning by a functioning market system and when they generate rapid and sustainable rates of economic growth that enable them to interact with the more advanced market economies without major forms of protection. Estonia, Poland, the Czech Republic, Hungary, Slovenia and possibly Slovakia will presumably reach this stage in a few years when they fully enter the European Union. Others have a much longer way to go. y First drafts of all the papers in this symposium were originally presented at a Journal of Economic Perspectives conference at CERGE-EI, Prague, Czech Republic, on March 24, 2001, with funding from the Andrew W. Mellon Foundation. The present paper benefited from comments by Brad De Long, Saul Estrin, Jan Hanousek, Evzen Kocenda, Alan Krueger, Sergei Slobodyan, Timothy Taylor, Katherine Terrell, Michael Waldman and a number of participants at the symposium. I would especially like to thank Cristina Negrut for her valuable assistance with preparing the tables and figures for this paper. The author’s research benefited from the National Science Foundation Grant No. SES 0111783, ACE grant P98-1129-R and ACE grant P98-1008-R. References Atkeson, Andrew and Patrick J. Kehoe. 1996. “Social Insurance and Transition.” International Economic Review. May, 37:2, pp. 377–402. Basu, Swati, Saul Estrin and Jan Svejnar. 1997. “Employment and Wage Behaviour of Industrial Enterprises in Transition Economies: The Cases of Poland and Czechoslovakia.” Economics of Transition. 5:2, pp. 271–87. Basu, Swati, Saul Estrin and Jan Svejnar. 2000. “Employment and Wages in Enterprises under Communism and in Transition: Evidence from Central Europe and Russia.” William Davidson Institute Working Paper No. 114b. Bevan, Alan, Saul Estrin and Mark Schaffer. 1999. “Determinants of Enterprise Performance during Transition.” Centre for Economic Reform and Transformation (CERT) Working Paper 99/03, January. Bhaduri, Amit, K. Kaski and Friedrich Levcik. 1993. “Transition from the Command to the Market System: What Went Wrong and What to do for Now?” Mimeo, Vienna Institute for Comparative Economic Studies. Blanchard, Olivier J. 1977. The Economics of Post-Communist Transition. Oxford: Clarendon Press. Blanchard, Olivier J. and Michael Kremer. 1997. “Disorganization.” Quarterly Journal of Economics. 112:4, pp. 1091–126. Boeri, Tito. 2000. Structural Change, Welfare Systems and Labor Allocation. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Brada, Josef C., Arthur E. King and Ali M. Kutan. 2000. “Inflation Bias and Productivity Shocks in Transition Economies: The Case of the Czech Republic.” Economic Systems. 24:2, pp. 119–38. Bruno, Michael and William Easterly. 1995. 26 Journal of Economic Perspectives “Inflation Crises and Long-Run Growth.” NBER Working Paper No. 5209. Calvo, Guillermo A. and Fabrizio Coricelli. 1994. “Capital Market Imperfections and Output Response in Previously Centrally Planned Economies,” in Building Sound Finance in Emerging Market Economies. G. Caprio, D. Folkerts-Landau and T. Lane, eds. Washington, D.C.: IMF, pp. 257–94. Commander, Simon, Andrei Tolstopiatenko and Ruslan Yemtsov. 1999. “Channels of Redistribution: Inequality and Poverty in the Russian Transition.” Economics of Transition. 7:1, pp. 411– 65. Desai, Padma and Todd Idson. 2000. Work without Wages: Russia’s Nonpayment Crisis. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press. Djankov, Simeon and Peter Murrell. 2000. “Enterprise Restructuring in Transition: A Quantitative Survey.” Working Paper, University of Maryland. EBRD. 1996. Transition Report. London: European Bank for Reconstruction and Develop- ment. EBRD. 1997. Transition Report. London: European Bank for Reconstruction and Develop- ment. EBRD. 1998. Transition Report. London: European Bank for Reconstruction and Develop- ment. EBRD. 1999. Transition Report. London: European Bank for Reconstruction and Develop- ment. EBRD. 2000. Transition Report. London: European Bank for Reconstruction and Develop- ment. EBRD. 2001. Transition Report. London: European Bank for Reconstruction and Develop- ment. Filer, Randall K. and Jan Hanousek. 2000. “Output Changes and Inflationary Bias in Transition.” Economic System. 24:3, pp. 285–94. Fischer, Stanley, Ratna Sahay and Carlos Vegh. 1996. “Stabilization and Growth in Transition Economies: The Early Experience.” Journal of Economic Perspectives. Spring, 10:2, pp. 45– 66. Garner, Thesia and Katherine Terrell. 1998. “A Gini Decomposition Analysis of Inequality in the Czech and Slovak Republics During the Transition.” Economics of Transition. 6:1, pp. 23– 46. Gelb, Alan. 1999. “The End of Transition?” in When is Transition Over? Annette Brown, ed. Kalamazoo, Mich.: W.E. Upjohn Institute for Employment Research, chapter 2. Gomulka, S. 1994. “Obstacles to Recovery in Transition Economies,” in “Obstacles to Enterprise Restructuring in Transition.” P. Aghion and N. Stern, eds., EBRD Working Paper, No. 16. Gregory, Paul and Robert Stuart. 1997. Comparative Economic Systems. Boston: Houghton- Mifflin. Gupta, Nandini, John Ham and Jan Svejnar. 2001. “Priorities and Sequencing in Privatization: Theory and Evidence from the Czech Republic.” Working Paper No. 323, William Davidson Institute, September. Ham, John, Jan Svejnar and Katherine Terrell. 1998. “Unemployment and the Social Safety Net During Transitions to a Market Economy: Evidence from the Czech and Slovak Republics.” American Economic Review. December, 88:5, pp. 1117–142. Ham, John, Jan Svejnar and Katherine Terrell. 1999. “Women’s Unemployment During the Transition: Evidence from Czech and Slovak Micro Data.” Economics of Transition. 7:1, pp. 47–78. Jurajda, Sˇteˇpa´n and Katherine Terrell. 2001. “Optimal Speed of Transition: Micro Evidence from the Czech Republic and Estonia.” Working Paper No. 355, William Davidson Institute. Kornai, Janos. 1999. “Reforming the Welfare State in Postsocialist Economies,” in When is Transition Over? Annette Brown, ed. Kalamazoo, Mich.: W.E. Upjohn Institute for Employment Research, chapter 6. Li, Wei. 1999. “A Tale of Two Reforms.” RAND Journal of Economics. 30:1, pp. 120–36. Lizal, Lubomir, Miroslav Singer and Jan Svejnar. 2001. “Enterprise Break-ups and Performance During the Transition From Plan to Market.” Review of Economics and Statistics. 83:1, pp. 92–99. Lizal, Lubomir and Jan Svejnar. 2002. “Investment, Credit Rationing and the Soft Budget Constraint: Evidence from Czech Panel Data.” Review of Economics and Statistics. Forthcoming. Megginson, William and Jeffrey Netter. 2001. “From State to Market: A Survey of Empirical Studies on Privatization.” Journal of Economic Literature. June, 39:2, pp. 321–89. Public Opinion Research Center. 1999. “Was It Worthwhile? The Czechs, Hungarians and Poles on the Changes of the Last Decade.” Warsaw, Poland, November. Available at ͗http:// www.cbos.pl/ENGLISH/cbos_en.htm͘. Roland, Gerard and T. Verdier. 1999. “Transition and the Output Fall.” Economics of Transition. 7:1, pp. 1–28. Rosati, Dariusz. 1994. “Output Decline During Transition from Plan to Market.” Economics of Transition. 2:4, pp. 419–42. Transition Economies: Performance and Challenges 27 Sabirianova, Klara. 2000. “The Great Human Capital Reallocation: An Empirical Analysis of Occupational Mobility in Transitional Russia.” Working Paper No. 309, William Davidson Institute, October. Sabirianova, Klara and John Earle. 2001. “Coping with Crisis: Russian Labor Markets in Transition.” Working Paper. Sachs, Jeffrey, Clifford Zinnes and Yair Eilat. 2000. “The Gains from Privatization in Transition Economies: Is Change of Ownership Enough?” CAER II Discussion Paper 63, Harvard Institute for International Development. Shirley, Mary and Patrick Walsh. 2000. Public versus Private Ownership: The Current State of the Debate. Washington, D.C.: World Bank. Svejnar, Jan. 1997. “Pensions in the Former Soviet Bloc: Problems and Solutions,” in The Coming Global Pension Crisis. Conference Proceedings, Council on Foreign Relations. Available at ͗http://www.ciaonet.org/conf/ cfr01͘. Svejnar, Jan. 1999. “Labor Markets in the Transitional Central and East European Economies,” in Handbook of Labor Economics, Volume 3B. Orley Ashenfelter and David Card, eds. Amsterdam: North Holland, chapter 42. Tanzi, Vito and George Tsiboures. 2000. “Fiscal Reform over Ten Years of Transition.” IMF Working Paper WP/00/113. World Bank. 1994. Averting the Old Age Crisis. New York: Oxford University Press. 28 Journal of Economic Perspectives This article has been cited by: 1. Sam Hobbs, Dimitrios Paparas, Mostafa E. AboElsoud. 2021. Does Foreign Direct Investment and Trade Promote Economic Growth? Evidence from Albania. Economies 9:1, 1. [Crossref] 2. Shusen Qi, Duc Duy Nguyen. 2021. Government connections and credit access around the world: Evidence from discouraged borrowers. Journal of International Business Studies 52:2, 321-333. [Crossref] 3. Michael Danquah, Kunal Sen. 2021. Informal institutions, transaction risk, and firm productivity in Myanmar. Small Business Economics 6. . [Crossref] 4. Tatiana Dănescu, Maria-Alexandra Popa. 2020. Public health and corporate social responsibility: exploratory study on pharmaceutical companies in an emerging market. Globalization and Health 16:1. . [Crossref] 5. Batrancea Ioan, Rathnaswamy Malar Mozi, Gaban Lucian, Fatacean Gheorghe, Tulai Horia, Bircea Ioan, Rus Mircea-Iosif. 2020. An Empirical Investigation on Determinants of Sustainable Economic Growth. Lessons from Central and Eastern European Countries. Journal of Risk and Financial Management 13:7, 146. [Crossref] 6. Delgerjargal Uvsh, Scott Gehlbach, Peter V. Potapov, Catalina Munteanu, Eugenia V. Bragina, Volker C. Radeloff. 2020. Correlates of forest-cover change in European Russia, 1989–2012. Land Use Policy 96, 104648. [Crossref] 7. Martin Sivek, Jakub Jirásek, Pavel Kavina, Markéta Vojnarová, Tereza Kurková, Andrea Bašová. 2020. Divorce after hundreds of years of marriage: Prospects for coal mining in the Czech Republic with regard to the European Union. Energy Policy 142, 111524. [Crossref] 8. Viktor Kvĕtoň, Aleš Bĕlohradský, Jiří Blažek. 2020. The variegated role of proximities in acquisitions by domestic and international companies in different phases of economic cycles. Papers in Regional Science 99:3, 583-602. [Crossref] 9. Aleksandra Wąsowska. 2020. Organisational development in the context of radical institutional change: the case study of Poland’s Ursus. Business History 21, 1-26. [Crossref] 10. Josip Franić. 2020. Repression, voluntary compliance and undeclared work in a transition setting: some evidence from Poland. Post-Communist Economies 32:2, 250-266. [Crossref] 11. Päivi Aaltonen, Lasse Torkkeli, Maija Worek. The Effect of Emerging Economies Operations on Knowledge Utilization: The Behavior of International Companies as Exaptation and Adaptation 49-87. [Crossref] 12. Julia Dobreva. Building Sustainable Enterprises through Innovations in Bulgaria 1245-1266. [Crossref] 13. Piotr Zmyślony, Marek Nowacki. From Centrally Driven Variations to Market-Driven Development: Models of Urban Tourism Evolution in Poland 49-66. [Crossref] 14. Matevž Rašković, Desislava Dikova, Tricia P. McDougall-Covin. 2020. International business with Central and Eastern Europe: From tyranny of history to revisited laboratories of learning. Journal of Business Research 108, 417-420. [Crossref] 15. Daichi Yamada, Masato Hiwatari. 2020. Labor Migration and People’s Political and Economic Views in Transition Countries. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref] 16. Enn Lun Yong. 2019. Unemployment and the European Union, 2000–2017: structural exploration of distant past economic experience and future prosperity. Journal of Economic Structures 8:1. . [Crossref] 17. Ognjen Žurovec, Pål Olav Vedeld. 2019. Rural Livelihoods and Climate Change Adaptation in Laggard Transitional Economies: A Case from Bosnia and Herzegovina. Sustainability 11:21, 6079. [Crossref] 18. Mikale Williamson, Ramon Zabriskie, Jasmine Townsend, Peter Ward, Gilbert Fellingham, Irina Kuznetsova. 2019. The contribution of family leisure to family functioning and family satisfaction among urban Russian families. Annals of Leisure Research 22:5, 607-628. [Crossref] 19. Vera Butkouskaya, Joan Llonch-Andreu, María-Del-Carmen Alarcón-Del-Amo. 2019. Strategic antecedents and organisational consequences of IMC in different economy types. Journal of Marketing Communications 27, 1-22. [Crossref] 20. Tomáš Sirovátka, Martin Guzi, Steven Saxonberg. 2019. Support for Market Economy Principles in European Post-communist Countries during 1999-2008. Czech Sociological Review 55:3, 319-346. [Crossref] 21. Veland Ramadani, Robert D. Hisrich, Hyrije Abazi-Alili, Léo-Paul Dana, Laxman Panthi, Lejla Abazi-Bexheti. 2019. Product innovation and firm performance in transition economies: A multi-stage estimation approach. Technological Forecasting and Social Change 140, 271-280. [Crossref] 22. Zita Kelemen, Ildikó Kemény. 2019. A motivation based shopper typology for short term retail events. Society and Economy 41:1, 107-124. [Crossref] 23. Fadil Sahiti. Firm Growth Factors: A State of the Art Review and Research Issues 47-113. [Crossref] 24. Zlatko Nedelko, Vojko Potocan. Values and Managerial Behaviour in Slovenia: A Transforming Economy 89-128. [Crossref] 25. Ina Ganguli. 2018. Immigrant selection before and after communism. Economics of Transition 26:4, 649-694. [Crossref] 26. Torbjörn Becker, Anders Olofsgård. 2018. From abnormal to normal. Economics of Transition 26:4, 769-800. [Crossref] 27. Thi Thu Huong Le, Thi Thuy Hang Le. 2018. Privatization of neighborhood governance in transition economy: a case study of gated community in Phu My Hung new town, Ho Chi Minh City, Vietnam. GeoJournal 83:4, 783-801. [Crossref] 28. Valerija Botrić, Ljiljana Božić. 2018. Human Capital as Barrier to Innovation: Post-Transition Experience. International Journal of Innovation and Technology Management 15:04, 1850033. [Crossref] 29. Beata Javorcik, Naotaka Sawada. 2018. The ISO 9000 certification: Little pain, big gain?. European Economic Review 105, 103-114. [Crossref] 30. Mahmoud Alajaty, John R. Anchor. 2018. Transition economies in the Middle East: the Syrian experience. Post-Communist Economies 30:3, 382-394. [Crossref] 31. Joanna Tyrowicz, Lucas van der Velde. 2018. Labor reallocation and demographics. Journal of Comparative Economics 46:1, 381-412. [Crossref] 32. Kristína Bilková, František Križan, Marcel Horňák, Peter Barlík, Gabriel Zubriczký. 2018. Food and non-food retail change in a post-communist country:A case study of the Gemer region in Slovakia. Bulletin of Geography. Socio-economic Series 39:39, 7-20. [Crossref] 33. Marjan Nikolov. Macedonia: Local Government Efficiency and Ethnic Fragmentation 203-229. [Crossref] 34. Anca M. Voicu, Somnath Sen, Inmaculada Martinez-Zarzoso. The Fall of the “Iron Curtain”: Can the Central and East European Countries (CEECs) Face the Challenge of Trade-Restructuring and Integration? 43-65. [Crossref] 35. Martin Guzi, teppn Mikula. 2018. Reforms that Keep You Home: Migration in Transition Economies. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref] 36. Boban Stojanović. 2018. State, institutional infrastructure and transition engineering in Republic of Serbia. Ekonomika 64:2, 23-32. [Crossref] 37. Barry W. Ickes. Output Fall – Transformational Recession 9928-9939. [Crossref] 38. Fadil Sahiti, Helen Lawton Smith. 2017. An application of growth diagnostics on the growth of firms: with evidence from Kosovo firms. Journal of Innovation and Entrepreneurship 6:1. . [Crossref] 39. Nataša Trajkova-Najdovska, Snežana Radukić. 2017. Testing Instability in Growth Patterns in the Course of Transition: Evidence for Balkan Countries. Economic Themes 55:4, 451-463. [Crossref] 40. Vladislav Maksimov, Stephanie Lu Wang, Yadong Luo. 2017. Institutional imprinting, entrepreneurial agency, and private firm innovation in transition economies. Journal of World Business 52:6, 854-865. [Crossref] 41. Roberta Capello, Giovanni Perucca. 2017. Industrial restructuring in CEE regions: determinants of regional growth in the accession and in the crisis period. Journal of Baltic Studies 48:3, 309-329. [Crossref] 42. Rabindra Nepal, Tooraj Jamasb, Clement Allan Tisdell. 2017. On environmental impacts of marketbased reforms: Evidence from the European and Central Asian transition economies. Renewable and Sustainable Energy Reviews 73, 44-52. [Crossref] 43. Tomas Kliestik, Maria Misankova, Katarina Valaskova, Lucia Svabova. 2017. Bankruptcy Prevention: New Effort to Reflect on Legal and Social Changes. Science and Engineering Ethics 23. . [Crossref] 44. Ayaz Zeynalov. 2017. The gravity of institutions in a resource-rich country: the case of Azerbaijan. International Economics and Economic Policy 14:2, 239-261. [Crossref] 45. Robert Cull, Lixin Colin Xu, Xi Yang, Li-An Zhou, Tian Zhu. 2017. Market facilitation by local government and firm efficiency: Evidence from China. Journal of Corporate Finance 42, 460-480. [Crossref] 46. Nada Zupan, Katarzyna Dziewanowska, Alison Pearce. 2017. Wanting it all: the challenges of managing young talent in transition economies. Baltic Journal of Management 12:1, 63-85. [Crossref] 47. Martin Lux, Andreja Cirman, Petr Sunega. 2017. Housing restitution policies among post-socialist countries: explaining divergence. International Journal of Housing Policy 17:1, 145-156. [Crossref] 48. Elodie Douarin, Tomasz Mickiewicz. Moving Away from the Command Economy in Central and Eastern Europe and the Former Soviet Union 1-17. [Crossref] 49. Manlio Del Giudice. Emerging Markets: Institutional Problems and Entrepreneurial Models 105-132. [Crossref] 50. Milenko Petrovic. Chapter 2: Post-Communist Transition Under the Umbrella of Uneven EUropeanisation: East Central Europe, the Baltic States and the Balkans 41-74. [Crossref] 51. Friðrik Larsen. Overview of Liberalization 49-63. [Crossref] 52. Daniel Münich, Klára Svitáková. Employment in the Czech Republic: Trends During Economic Transition and the Global Recession 95-119. [Crossref] 53. Beth Davis-Sramek, Brian S. Fugate, Jason Miller, Richard Germain, Alexei Izyumov, Konstantin Krotov. 2017. Understanding the Present by Examining the Past: Imprinting Effects On Supply Chain Outsourcing in a Transition Economy. Journal of Supply Chain Management 53:1, 65-86. [Crossref] 54. Karel Zeman. 2016. Analysis of the Development of the Economic Condition and Efficiency of the Privatization Process of Banks in the Czech Republic. Politická ekonomie 64:7, 804-832. [Crossref] 55. Matylda Awedyk, Agnieszka Niezgoda. 2016. New opportunities for future tourism after 25 years of political and socioeconomic transformation – foresight in Poland’s tourism planning. Journal of Tourism Futures 2:2, 137-154. [Crossref] 56. Emanuele Strano, Vishal Sood. 2016. Rich and Poor Cities in Europe. An Urban Scaling Approach to Mapping the European Economic Transition. PLOS ONE 11:8, e0159465. [Crossref] 57. Armenak Antinyan. 2016. Reference Group Income and Subjective Well-Being: Empirical Evidence from Low-Income Transition Economies. Social Indicators Research 127:3, 1333-1348. [Crossref] 58. Dorota Witkowska. 2016. Comparison Of Women’s Situation In The Labour Market In The Former GDR And Poland. Comparative Economic Research. Central and Eastern Europe 19:2, 129-148. [Crossref] 59. Beth Davis-Sramek, Konstantin Krotov, Richard Germain. 2016. Predicting technology integration and performance in transition economies: insights from Russia. International Journal of Physical Distribution & Logistics Management 46:2, 128-152. [Crossref] 60. Nigel F. B. Allington, John S. L. McCombie. An Eastern European Perspective on the Recent Financial Crisis and an Examination of Poland’s Exceptionalism 195-231. [Crossref] 61. James K. Galbraith, Béatrice Halbach, Aleksandra Malinowska, Amin Shams, Wenjie Zhang. The University of Texas Inequality Project Global Inequality Data Sets, 1963–2008: Updates, Revisions and Quality Checks 7-39. [Crossref] 62. James K. Galbraith, Beatrice Halbach, Aleksandra Malinowska, Amin Shams, Wenjie Zhang, Edward N. Wolff. The University of Texas Inequality Project Global Inequality Data Sets, 1963–2008: Updates, Revisions and Quality Checks 98-135. [Crossref] 63. Klaus E Meyer, Mike W Peng. 2016. Theoretical foundations of emerging economy business research. Journal of International Business Studies 47:1, 3-22. [Crossref] 64. Adewole Musiliu Adeolu. 2016. The Limits of Market-Based Reforms. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref] 65. Julia Dobreva. Building Sustainable Enterprises through Innovations in Bulgaria 451-472. [Crossref] 66. Michaella Vanore, Melissa Siegel. 2015. The evolution of gendered migration trajectories from Moldova & Georgia. Comparative Migration Studies 3:1. . [Crossref] 67. Zohid Askarov, Hristos Doucouliagos. 2015. Spatial aid spillovers during transition. European Journal of Political Economy 40, 79-95. [Crossref] 68. Johan P. Mackenbach, Marina Karanikolos, Jamie Lopez Bernal, Martin Mckee. 2015. Why did life expectancy in Central and Eastern Europe suddenly improve in the 1990s? An analysis by cause of death. Scandinavian Journal of Public Health 43:8, 796-801. [Crossref] 69. Michael Touchton. 2015. Who commits to the rule of law? Constrained government and foreign direct investment in postcommunist states. East European Politics 31:4, 468-486. [Crossref] 70. Andrea Pavličková, Ajit Dayanandan. 2015. Social networks and emigration in Slovakia. Migration and Development 4:2, 220-231. [Crossref] 71. Rabindra Nepal, Tooraj Jamasb. 2015. Caught between theory and practice: Government, market, and regulatory failure in electricity sector reforms. Economic Analysis and Policy 46, 16-24. [Crossref] 72. Zohid Askarov, Hristos Doucouliagos. 2015. Aid and institutions in transition economies. European Journal of Political Economy 38, 55-70. [Crossref] 73. Bruno T. da Rocha. 2015. Let the markets begin: The interplay between free prices and privatisation in early transition. Journal of Comparative Economics 43:2, 350-370. [Crossref] 74. Mihály Tamás Borsi, Norbert Metiu. 2015. The evolution of economic convergence in the European Union. Empirical Economics 48:2, 657-681. [Crossref] 75. Nicholas Apergis. 2015. Labor Income Tax and Output in a Panel of Central and Eastern European Countries: A Long-Run Perspective. International Advances in Economic Research 21:1, 1-12. [Crossref] 76. Zohid Askarov, Hristos Doucouliagos. 2015. Development Aid and Growth in Transition Countries. World Development 66, 383-399. [Crossref] 77. Christopher A. Hartwell. Institutional Reform: Irresistible Forces and Immovable Objects 153-169. [Crossref] 78. Matthias Dauner, Stefan Voigt. Institutionen 47-62. [Crossref] 79. Ana Rincon-Aznar, Michela Vecchi, Francesco Venturini. Functional Income Distribution in European Transition Countries 59-92. [Crossref] 80. Ayaz Zeynalov. 2015. The Gravity of Institutions in Resource-Rich Country. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref] 81. Joan Costa-Font, Lucia Kossarova. 2015. Anthropometric Dividends of Czechoslovakia's Break Up. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref] 82. Sumei Zhang. 2014. Land-centered urban politics in transitional China – Can they be explained by Growth Machine Theory?. Cities 41, 179-186. [Crossref] 83. Thomas Vendryes. 2014. PEASANTS AGAINST PRIVATE PROPERTY RIGHTS: A REVIEW OF THE LITERATURE. Journal of Economic Surveys 28:5, 971-995. [Crossref] 84. Prema-chandra Athukorala, Swarnim Waglé. 2014. Trade Liberalisation and Export Performance in Transition: The Case of Georgia. The World Economy 37:12, 1669-1691. [Crossref] 85. Rabindra Nepal, Tooraj Jamasb, Clement Allan Tisdell. 2014. Market-related reforms and increased energy efficiency in transition countries: empirical evidence. Applied Economics 46:33, 4125-4136. [Crossref] 86. Gerardo Ángeles Castro, Diana Berenice Ramírez Camarillo. 2014. Determinants of tax revenue in OECD countries over the period 2001–2011. Contaduría y Administración 59:3, 35-59. [Crossref] 87. George A. Shinkle, Brian T. McCann. 2014. New product deployment: The moderating influence of economic institutional context. Strategic Management Journal 35:7, 1090-1101. [Crossref] 88. Annalisa Busetta, Ornella Giambalvo. 2014. The effect of women’s participation in the labour market on the postponement of first childbirth: a comparison of Italy and Hungary. Journal of Population Research 31:2, 151-192. [Crossref] 89. Walid Saffar. 2014. The political economy of share issue privatization: International evidence. Journal of Multinational Financial Management 24, 1-18. [Crossref] 90. Maria Rosaria Della Peruta. The Institutional Foundations of Transition and Emerging Economies 51-70. [Crossref] 91. James K. Galbraith, BBatrice Halbach, Aleksandra Malinowska, Amin Shams, Wenjie Zhang. 2014. UTIP Global Inequality Data Sets 1963-2008: Updates, Revisions and Quality Checks. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref] 92. Andrew Vonnegut. 2014. Institutions and Initial Conditions in Transition: Reconciling NeoInstitutional and Neo-Classical Conceptions. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref] 93. Tamara G. Nezhina. 2014. Examining the Causes of Systemic Corruption: The Case of Kazakhstan. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref] 94. Chiara Franco, Elisa Gerussi. 2013. Trade, foreign direct investments (FDI) and income inequality: Empirical evidence from transition countries. The Journal of International Trade & Economic Development 22:8, 1131-1160. [Crossref] 95. George A. Shinkle, Aldas P. Kriauciunas, Greg Hundley. 2013. Why pure strategies may be wrong for transition economy firms. Strategic Management Journal 34:10, 1244-1254. [Crossref] 96. Jesús Crespo-Cuaresma, Octavio Fernández-Amador. 2013. Business cycle convergence in EMU: A second look at the second moment. Journal of International Money and Finance 37, 239-259. [Crossref] 97. Ayana Seidimbek. 2013. Nazarbayev University: Integration of Western and Central Asian Educational Systems. Procedia - Social and Behavioral Sciences 89, 682-686. [Crossref] 98. Jesús Crespo-Cuaresma, Octavio Fernández-Amador. 2013. Business cycle convergence in EMU: A first look at the second moment. Journal of Macroeconomics 37, 265-284. [Crossref] 99. Ivana Malá. 2013. The Use of Finite Mixtures of Probability Distributions for Modelling the Distribution of the Duration of Unemployment in the Czech Republic. Acta Oeconomica Pragensia 21:5, 47-63. [Crossref] 100. Frank Neher. 2013. Markets wanted: expectation overshooting in transition economies. International Review of Economics 60:2, 187-219. [Crossref] 101. Ernesto Crivelli. 2013. Fiscal impact of privatization revisited: The role of tax revenues in transition economies. Economic Systems 37:2, 217-232. [Crossref] 102. Roberto Golinelli, Riccardo Rovelli. 2013. Did growth and reforms increase citizens' support for the transition?. European Journal of Political Economy 30, 112-137. [Crossref] 103. Sandra Blagojević, Jože P. Damijan. 2013. The impact of corruption and ownership on the performance of firms in Central and Eastern Europe. Post-Communist Economies 25:2, 133-158. [Crossref] 104. Audra I. Mockaitis, Laura Salciuviene, Pervez N. Ghauri. 2013. On What Do Consumer Product Preferences Depend? Determining Domestic versus Foreign Product Preferences in an Emerging Economy Market. Journal of International Consumer Marketing 25:3, 166-180. [Crossref] 105. Riccardo Rovelli, Anzelika Zaiceva. 2013. Did support for economic and political reforms increase during the post-communist transition, and if so, why?. Economics of Transition 21:2, 193-240. [Crossref] 106. David Lingelbach. 2013. Paradise postponed? Venture capital emergence in Russia. Critical perspectives on international business 9:1/2, 204-225. [Crossref] 107. Wendy Carlin, Mark Schaffer, Paul Seabright. 2013. Soviet power plus electrification: What is the long-run legacy of communism?. Explorations in Economic History 50:1, 116-147. [Crossref] 108. Jiří Večerník. 2013. The changing role of education in the distribution of earnings and household income. Economics of Transition 21:1, 111-133. [Crossref] 109. Anna Alon. 2013. Complexity and Dual Institutionality: The Case of IFRS Adoption in Russia. Corporate Governance: An International Review 21:1, 42-57. [Crossref] 110. . 397-464. [Crossref] 111. Davorin Kračun. 2013. Post Keynesian Model of Transition and Economic Performance in Slovenia. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref] 112. Miroslav Singer. 2013. A Comparison of the Rates of Growth of Post-Transformation Economies: What Can(Not) Be Expected From GDP?. Prague Economic Papers 22:1, 3-27. [Crossref] 113. Ernesto Crivelli. 2012. Local governments’ fiscal balance and privatization in transition countries 1. Economics of Transition 20:4, 677-703. [Crossref] 114. Aleksandra Gregorič, Katarina Zajc, Marko Simoneti. 2012. Agents’ response to inefficient judiciary: social norms and the law in transition. European Journal of Law and Economics 34:1, 147-172. [Crossref] 115. Iga Magda, David Marsden, Simone Moriconi. 2012. Collective Agreements, Wages, and Firms' Cohorts: Evidence from Central Europe. ILR Review 65:3, 607-629. [Crossref] 116. George A. Shinkle, Aldas P. Kriauciunas. 2012. The impact of current and founding institutions on strength of competitive aspirations in transition economies. Strategic Management Journal 33:4, 448-458. [Crossref] 117. Victor A. Beker. 2012. A Case Study on Trade Liberalization: Argentina in the 1990s. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref] 118. Hein Bogaard. 2012. Structural Economic Change and Foreign Acquisitions. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref] 119. Vinh Dang. 2012. Institutions and Efficiency in Transition Economies. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref] 120. Martijn Adriaan Boermans, Hein J. Roelfsema. 2012. The Effects of Internationalization on Innovation: Firm-Level Evidence for Transition Economies. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref] 121. Sandra Blagojevic, Joze P. Damijan. 2012. Impact of Private Incidence of Corruption and Firm Ownership on Performance of Firms in Central and Eastern Europe. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref] 122. Dalibor Rohac. 2012. What Have We Learned from Post-Communist Transitions?. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref] 123. Ernesto Crivelli. 2012. Local Governments’ Fiscal Balance, Privatization, and Banking Sector Reform in Transition Countries. IMF Working Papers 12:146, 1. [Crossref] 124. Nigel Swain. 2011. A Post-Socialist Capitalism. Europe-Asia Studies 63:9, 1671-1695. [Crossref] 125. Teodora Paligorova. 2011. Tournament Structure of Managerial Pay: Evidence from the Transition Period. Managerial and Decision Economics 32:6, 385-398. [Crossref] 126. Gábor Kertesi, Gábor Kézdi. 2011. Roma employment in Hungary after the post-communist transition1. Economics of Transition 19:3, 563-610. [Crossref] 127. Joseph Ofori-Dankwa, Scott D. Julian. 2011. Utilizing an Integrative Multilens Model. International Studies of Management & Organization 41:2, 5-25. [Crossref] 128. El-hadj Bah, Josef C. Brada, Taner Yigit. 2011. With a little help from our friends: The effect of USAID assistance on SME growth in a transition economy. Journal of Comparative Economics 39:2, 205-220. [Crossref] 129. Tommaso Nannicini, Andreas Billmeier. 2011. Economies in Transition: How Important Is Trade Openness for Growth?*. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics 73:3, 287-314. [Crossref] 130. Matjaž Koman, Ljubica Knežević Cvelbar, Anðelko Lojpur, Janez Prašnikar. 2011. Effects of Ownership and Management Changes on Productivity in Privatized Montenegrin Firms. Eastern European Economics 49:3, 5-25. [Crossref] 131. Narjess Boubakri, Jean-Claude Cosset, Omrane Guedhami, Walid Saffar. 2011. The political economy of residual state ownership in privatized firms: Evidence from emerging markets. Journal of Corporate Finance 17:2, 244-258. [Crossref] 132. Ana Lamo, Julián Messina, Etienne Wasmer. 2011. Are specific skills an obstacle to labor market adjustment?. Labour Economics 18:2, 240-256. [Crossref] 133. Larry W. Chavis, Leora F. Klapper, Inessa Love. Access to Bank Financing and New Investment: Evidence from Europe 115-132. [Crossref] 134. Nigel F. B. Allington, John S. L. McCombie. The Impact of the Subprime Financial Crisis on the Transition and Central Asian Economies: Causes and Consequences 159-181. [Crossref] 135. Mirela Xheneti. An Institutional Perspective 225-255. [Crossref] 136. Riccardo Rovelli, Anzelika Zaiceva. 2011. Individual Support for Economic and Political Changes: Evidence from Transition Countries, 1991-2004. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref] 137. Roberto Golinelli, Riccardo Rovelli. 2011. Did Growth and Reforms Increase Citizens’ Support for the Transition?. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref] 138. Ahmad Arslan, Jorma Larimo. 2010. Ownership Strategy of Multinational Enterprises and the Impacts of Regulative and Normative Institutional Distance: Evidence from Finnish Foreign Direct Investments in Central and Eastern Europe. Journal of East-West Business 16:3, 179-200. [Crossref] 139. Faith Hatani. 2010. Flexible strategy mix for central Europe: A process data analysis. Thunderbird International Business Review 52:6, 605-616. [Crossref] 140. Olivier Furrer, Carolyn P. Egri, David A. Ralston, Wade M. Danis, Emmanuelle Reynaud, Irina Naoumova, Mario Molteni, Arunas Starkus, Fidel León Darder, Marina Dabic, Amandine FurrerPerrinjaquet. 2010. Attitudes toward Corporate Responsibilities in Western Europe and in Central and East Europe. Management International Review 50:3, 379-398. [Crossref] 141. A. THORPE, R. VAN ANROOY. 2010. Strategies for the rehabilitation of the inland fisheries sector in Central Asia. Fisheries Management and Ecology 17:2, 134-140. [Crossref] 142. Patricia T. Young. 2010. Captured by Business? Romanian Market Governance and the New Economic Elite. Business and Politics 12:1, 1-38. [Crossref] 143. Alexei Izyumov. 2010. Human Costs of Post-communist Transition: Public Policies and Private Response. Review of Social Economy 68:1, 93-125. [Crossref] 144. George A Shinkle, Aldas P Kriauciunas. 2010. Institutions, size and age in transition economies: Implications for export growth. Journal of International Business Studies 41:2, 267-286. [Crossref] 145. Joanna Tyrowicz, Piotr Wójcik. Regional Dynamics of Unemployment in Poland A Convergence Approach 149-173. [Crossref] 146. Joanna Tyrowicz, Piotr Wójcik. Unemployment Convergence in Transition 236-259. [Crossref] 147. Enrico Marelli, Marcello Signorelli. Economic Growth and Structural Features of Transition: Theoretical Framework and General Overview 11-38. [Crossref] 148. Dimitris Kallioras, George Petrakos, Maria Tsiapa. The Emerging Economic Geography Setting in New EU Member States: A Comparative Account of Regional Industrial Performance and Adjustment 150-169. [Crossref] 149. Narjess Boubakri, Jean-Claude Cosset, Hamdi Ben Nasr. 2010. The Political Determinants of the Cost of Equity: Evidence from Newly Privatized Firms. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref] 150. Richard M. Bird. 2010. Local Government Finance: Trends and Questions. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref] 151. Joanna Tyrowicz, Piotr Wójcik. 2010. Some Stylized Facts on Unemployment Dynamics in Transition. Eastern European Economics 48:1, 5-22. [Crossref] 152. Alexandra Kaar, Alma Šehić. Information provision by public authorities and business partners in Southeast Europe: Effects on firm performance 249-271. [Crossref] 153. Julia Gray. 2009. International Organization as a Seal of Approval: European Union Accession and Investor Risk. American Journal of Political Science 53:4, 931-949. [Crossref] 154. Peter F. Orazem, Milan Vodopivec. 2009. Do Market Pressures Induce Economic Efficiency? The Case of Slovenian Manufacturing, 1994–2001. Southern Economic Journal 76:2, 553-576. [Crossref] 155. Saul Estrin,, Jan Hanousek,, Evžen Kočenda,, Jan Svejnar. 2009. The Effects of Privatization and Ownership in Transition Economies. Journal of Economic Literature 47:3, 699-728. [Abstract] [View PDF article] [PDF with links] 156. Richard A. Easterlin. 2009. Lost in transition: Life satisfaction on the road to capitalism. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization 71:2, 130-145. [Crossref] 157. Gianni De Fraja, Barbara M. Roberts. 2009. Privatization in Poland� What was the government trying to achieve?. Economics of Transition 17:3, 531-557. [Crossref] 158. Marjan Senjur. 2009. The transition experience in retrospect: the labour market transformation was vital. Post-Communist Economies 21:2, 175-189. [Crossref] 159. JIAHUA CHE. 2009. A Dynamic Model of Privatization with Endogenous Post-Privatization Performance. Review of Economic Studies 76:2, 563-596. [Crossref] 160. Andy Thorpe, Raymon van Anrooy, Bisheke N. Niyazov, Mairam K. Sarieva, John Valbo-Jørgensen, Andres Mena Millar. 2009. The collapse of the fisheries sector in Kyrgyzstan: An analysis of its roots and its prospects for revival. Communist and Post-Communist Studies 42:1, 141-163. [Crossref] 161. Jiří Večerník. 2009. Le revenu des ménages en République tchèque après 1989 Hausse et changement de structure des inégalités. Revue d’études comparatives Est-Ouest 40:01, 175-196. [Crossref] 162. Geoffrey Swain, Nigel Swain. Adapting to Capitalism Enthusiastically: Central Europe 233-258. [Crossref] 163. Narjess Boubakri, Jean-Claude Cosset, Omrane Guedhami, Walid Saffar. 2009. The Political Economy of Residual State Ownership in Privatized Firms: Evidence from Emerging Markets. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref] 164. Omrane Guedhami, Jean-Claude Cosset, Narjess Boubakri, Walid Saffar. 2009. The Political Economy of State Residual Ownership in Privatized Firms: Evidence from Emerging Markets. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref] 165. Vinh Dang. 2009. Institution and Efficiency in Transition Economies. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref] 166. Thomas Lange. 2008. Attitudes, attributes and institutions. Employee Relations 31:1, 81-97. [Crossref] 167. Karen Eggleston, Jian Wang, Keqin Rao. 2008. From plan to market in the health sector?. Journal of Asian Economics 19:5-6, 400-412. [Crossref] 168. Karen Macours, Johan F.M. Swinnen. 2008. Rural–Urban Poverty Differences in Transition Countries. World Development 36:11, 2170-2187. [Crossref] 169. Enrico Pennings. 2008. Privatization of real options. Journal of Comparative Economics 36:3, 489-497. [Crossref] 170. B. Hámori, K. Szabó, A. Derecskei, H. Hurta, L. Tóth. 2008. Competitive and cooperative attitudes in the transforming economy of Hungary. Acta Oeconomica 58:3, 263-294. [Crossref] 171. Juan Cristóbal Campoy, Juan Carlos Negrete. 2008. Rigidities and Inflationary Bias in a Monetary Union: The Consequences of EU Enlargement. Review of Development Economics 12:3, 636-654. [Crossref] 172. James Bessen, Michael J. Meurer. 2008. Do Patents Perform Like Property?. Academy of Management Perspectives 22:3, 8-20. [Crossref] 173. Irene Hanson Frieze, Josephine E. Olson. 2008. Review of Feinburg's Elusive Equality, Johnson and Robinson's Living Gender after Communism, and Wingfield and Bucur's Gender and War in Twentieth Century Eastern Europe. East European Politics and Societies: and Cultures 22:3, 693-701. [Crossref] 174. Milenko Petrovic. 2008. The role of geography and history in determining the slower progress of post-communist transition in the Balkans. Communist and Post-Communist Studies 41:2, 123-145. [Crossref] 175. Jochen A. Jungeilges, Theis Theisen. 2008. A comparative study of equity judgements in Lithuania and Norway. The Journal of Socio-Economics 37:3, 1090-1118. [Crossref] 176. Polona Domadenik, Janez Prašnikar, Jan Svejnar. 2008. Restructuring of firms in transition: ownership, institutions and openness to trade. Journal of International Business Studies 39:4, 725-746. [Crossref] 177. Alvaro Cuervo-Cazurra. 2008. Better the devil you don't know: Types of corruption and FDI in transition economies. Journal of International Management 14:1, 12-27. [Crossref] 178. Modestas Gelbuda, Klaus E. Meyer, Andrew Delios. 2008. International business and institutional development in Central and Eastern Europe. Journal of International Management 14:1, 1-11. [Crossref] 179. Alexei Izyumov, John Vahaly. 2008. Old Capital vs. New Investment in Post-Soviet Economies: Conceptual Issues and Estimates. Comparative Economic Studies 50:1, 79-110. [Crossref] 180. Anna Maria Ferragina, Francesco Pastore. 2008. MIND THE GAP: UNEMPLOYMENT IN THE NEW EU REGIONS. Journal of Economic Surveys 22:1, 73-113. [Crossref] 181. Josephine E. Olson, Irene Hanson Frieze. Transition from Communism . [Crossref] 182. Peter Murrell. Institutions and Firms in Transition Economies 667-699. [Crossref] 183. Barry W. Ickes. Output Fall – Transformational Recession 1-13. [Crossref] 184. R. Duane Ireland, Laszlo Tihanyi, Justin W. Webb. 2008. A Tale of Two Politico-Economic Systems: Implications for Entrepreneurship in Central and Eastern Europe. Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice 32:1, 107-130. [Crossref] 185. Michael J. Meurer, James E. Bessen. 2008. Do Patents Perform Like Property?. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref] 186. Alena Bicakova, Jiri Slacalek, Michal Slavik. 2008. Labor Supply after Transition: Evidence from the Czech Republic. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref] 187. Richard A. Easterlin. 2008. Lost in Transition: Life Satisfaction on the Road to Capitalism. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref] 188. Victor A. Beker. 2008. Trade Liberalization, Inequality and Unemployment: Lessons from the Argentine Case. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref] 189. Hamdi Ben Nasr, Narjess Boubakri, Jean-Claude Cosset. 2008. The Political Determinants of the Cost of Equity: Evidence from Newly Privatized Firms. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref] 190. Renáta Kosová. 2008. Do Foreign Firms Crowd Out Domestic Firms? Evidence from the Czech Republic. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref] 191. Renáta Kosová, Meghana Ayyagari. 2008. Does FDI facilitate Domestic Entry? Evidence from the Czech Republic. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref] 192. Wolfgang Aussenegg, Ranko Jelic. 2007. The Operating Performance of Newly Privatised Firms in Central European Transition Economies. European Financial Management 13:5, 853-879. [Crossref] 193. Alexei Izyumov, John Vahaly. 2007. New capital accumulation in transition economies: implications for capital-labor and capital-output ratios. Economic Change and Restructuring 39:1-2, 63-83. [Crossref] 194. John Bennett, Saul Estrin, Giovanni Urga. 2007. Methods of privatization and economic growth in transition economies. The Economics of Transition 15:4, 661-683. [Crossref] 195. Michał Myck, Leszek Morawski, Jerzy Mycielski. 2007. Employment fluctuations and dynamics of the aggregate average wage in Poland, 1996?2003. The Economics of Transition 15:4, 759-779. [Crossref] 196. Valery Lazarev, Paul Gregory. 2007. Structural convergence in Russia’s economic transition, 1990– 2002. Economic Change and Restructuring 40:3, 281-304. [Crossref] 197. Kanybek Nur-tegin. 2007. Do Transition Economies and Developing Countries Have Similar Destinies?. Atlantic Economic Journal 35:3, 327-342. [Crossref] 198. Laszlo Tihanyi, W. Harvey Hegarty. 2007. Political Interests and the Emergence of Commercial Banking in Transition Economies. Journal of Management Studies 44:5, 788-813. [Crossref] 199. Luca De Benedictis, Lucia Tajoli. 2007. Economic integration and similarity in trade structures. Empirica 34:2, 117-137. [Crossref] 200. Michael Peneder, Robert Stehrer. 2007. Neighbours in Transition. National Institute Economic Review 200, 96-104. [Crossref] 201. Josephine E. Olson, Irene H. Frieze, Sally Wall, Bozena Zdaniuk, Anuška Ferligoj, Tina Kogovšek, Jasna Horvat, Nataša Šarlija, Eva Jarošová, Daniela Pauknerová, Lan Anh Nguyen Luu, Mònika Kovacs, Jolanta Miluska, Aida Orgocka, Ludmila Erokhina, Olga V. Mitina, Ludmila V. Popova, Nijolė Petkevičiūtė, Mirjana Pejic-Bach, Slavka Kubušová, Maja Rus Makovec. 2007. Beliefs in Equality for Women and Men as Related to Economic Factors in Central and Eastern Europe and the United States. Sex Roles 56:5-6, 297-308. [Crossref] 202. Sumon Kumar Bhaumik, Saul Estrin. 2007. How transition paths differ: Enterprise performance in Russia and China. Journal of Development Economics 82:2, 374-392. [Crossref] 203. Pierluigi Montalbano, Alessandro Federici, Umberto Triulzi, Carlo Pietrobelli. Trade Openness and Vulnerability in Central and Eastern Europe 204-234. [Crossref] 204. Serguey Braguinsky, Roger Myerson. 2007. A macroeconomic model of Russian transition. Economics of Transition 15:1, 77-107. [Crossref] 205. John D. Sullivan, aleksandr shkolnikov, Kim Eric Bettcher. 2007. Business Associations, Business Climate, and Economic Growth: Evidence from Transition Economies. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref] 206. Geoffrey M. Hodgson. 2006. Institutions, Recessions and Recovery in the Transitional Economies. Journal of Economic Issues 40:4, 875-894. [Crossref] 207. Josephine E. Olson, Irene H. Frieze, Sally Wall, Bozena Zdaniuk, Nina Telpuchovskaya, Anuška Ferligoj, Tina Kogovšek, Jasna Horvat, Nataša Šarlija, Eva Jarošová, Daniela Pauknerová, Lan Anh Nguyen Luu, Mònika Kovacs, Jolanta Miluska, Aida Orgocka, Ludmila Erokhina, Olga V. Mitina, Ludmila V. Popova, Nijolė Petkevičiu-te, Mirjana Pejic-Bach, Maja Rus Makovec. 2006. Economic Influences on Ideals About Future Jobs in Young Adults in Formerly Socialist Countries and the United States. Cross-Cultural Research 40:4, 352-376. [Crossref] 208. Paul Frijters, Ingo Geishecker, John P. Haisken-DeNew, Michael A. Shields. 2006. Can the Large Swings in Russian Life Satisfaction be Explained by Ups and Downs in Real Incomes?. Scandinavian Journal of Economics 108:3, 433-458. [Crossref] 209. WOLFGANG RÜDIG. 2006. Is government good for Greens? Comparing the electoral effects of government participation in Western and East-Central Europe. European Journal of Political Research 45:s1, S127-S154. [Crossref] 210. Aldas Kriauciunas, Prashant Kale. 2006. The impact of socialist imprinting and search on resource change: a study of firms in lithuania. Strategic Management Journal 27:7, 659-679. [Crossref] 211. Thorsten Beck, Luc Laeven. 2006. Institution building and growth in transition economies. Journal of Economic Growth 11:2, 157-186. [Crossref] 212. János Kornai. 2006. The great transformation of Central Eastern Europe. Economics of Transition 14:2, 207-244. [Crossref] 213. Steven Stillman. 2006. Health and nutrition in Eastern Europe and the former Soviet Union during the decade of transition: A review of the literature. Economics & Human Biology 4:1, 104-146. [Crossref] 214. Aleksander Aristovnik. 2006. Current Account Adjustments in Selected Transition Countries. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref] 215. Wolfgang Aussenegg, Ranko M. Jelic. 2006. Operating Performance of Newly Privatized Firms in Central European Transition Economies. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref] 216. Aleksander Aristovnik. 2006. Current Account Sustainability in Selected Transition Countries. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref] 217. Karen Macours, Johan F. M. Swinnen. 2006. Rural Poverty in Transition Countries. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref] 218. János Kornai. 2006. The great transformation of central and eastern Europe: success and disappointment. Politická ekonomie 54:4, 435-466. [Crossref] 219. Alexei Izyumov, Sofia Alterman. 2005. The General Rate of Profit in a New Market Economy: Conceptual Issues and Estimates. Review of Radical Political Economics 37:4, 476-493. [Crossref] 220. Klaus E Meyer, Mike W Peng. 2005. Probing theoretically into Central and Eastern Europe: transactions, resources, and institutions. Journal of International Business Studies 36:6, 600-621. [Crossref] 221. Luka Juvancic, Emil Erjavec. 2005. Intertemporal analysis of employment decisions on agricultural holdings in Slovenia. Agricultural Economics 33:2, 153-161. [Crossref] 222. Frédéric Carluer. 2005. Dynamics of Russian regional clubs: The time of divergence. Regional Studies 39:6, 713-726. [Crossref] 223. Nada Zupan, Robert Kaše. 2005. Strategic human resource management in European transition economies: building a conceptual model on the case of Slovenia. The International Journal of Human Resource Management 16:6, 882-906. [Crossref] 224. Narjess Boubakri, Jean-Claude Cosset, Omrane Guedhami. 2005. Postprivatization corporate governance: The role of ownership structure and investor protection. Journal of Financial Economics 76:2, 369-399. [Crossref] 225. John Marangos. 2005. A Political Economy Approach to the Neoclassical Gradualist Model of Transition. Journal of Economic Surveys 19:2, 263-293. [Crossref] 226. Zuobao Wei, Feixue Xie, Shaorong Zhang. 2005. Ownership Structure and Firm Value in China's Privatized Firms: 1991–2001. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 40:1, 87-108. [Crossref] 227. Jovo Ateljevic, Tony O'Rourke, Zdravko Todorovic. 2004. Entrepreneurship and SMEs in Bosnia and Herzegovina. The International Journal of Entrepreneurship and Innovation 5:4, 241-253. [Crossref] 228. Marko Pahor, Janez Prašnikar, Anuška Ferligoj. 2004. Building a corporate network in a transition economy: the case of Slovenia. Post-Communist Economies 16:3, 307-331. [Crossref] 229. 2004. Review of periodical literature published in 2002. The Economic History Review 57:1, 161-220. [Crossref] 230. Werner Lachmann. Wirtschaftsordnung 29-94. [Crossref] 231. Michael Engelschalk. Creating a Favorable Tax Environment for Small Business 275-311. [Crossref] 232. Xiao-Yuan Dong, Louis G. Putterman, Bulent Unel. 2004. Enterprise Restructuring and Firm Performance: A Comparison of Rural and Urban Enterprises in Jiangsu Province. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref] 233. Sharon Eicher. 2004. Is Kazakhstan a Market Economy Yet? Getting Warmer... SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref] 234. Giovanni Facchini, Maria Luigia Segnana. 2003. Growth at the EU periphery: the next enlargement. The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance 43:5, 827-862. [Crossref] 235. Vera Adamchik, Thomas Hyclak, Arthur King. 2003. The wage structure and wage distribution in Poland, 1994‐2001. International Journal of Manpower 24:8, 916-946. [Crossref] 236. Mike W Peng, Trevor Buck, Igor Filatotchev. 2003. Do outside directors and new managers help improve firm performance? An exploratory study in Russian privatization. Journal of World Business 38:4, 348-360. [Crossref] 237. Anastassios D. Karayiannis, Allan E. Young. 2003. Entrepreneurial Activities in a Veblenian Type Transition Economy. The American Economist 47:2, 40-51. [Crossref] 238. Guillaume Cheikbossian. 2003. Property rights, rent-seeking and aggregate outcomes in transition economies. Economic Systems 27:3, 271-288. [Crossref] 239. Christa Hainz. 2003. Bank competition and credit markets in transition economies. Journal of Comparative Economics 31:2, 223-245. [Crossref] 240. John Haltiwanger, Hartmut Lehmann, Katherine Terrell. 2003. Job Creation and Job Destruction in Transition Countries. The Economics of Transition 11:2, 205-219. [Crossref] 241. Peter Murrell. The Relative Levels and the Character of Institutional Development in Transition Economies 41-67. [Crossref] 242. Saul Estrin, Sumon K. Bhaumik. 2003. Why Transition Paths Differ: Russian and Chinese Enterprise Performance Compared. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref] 243. Neven T. Valev, John A. Carlson. 2003. Tenuous Financial Stability. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref] 244. Stefan H. Lutz, Oleksandr Talavera. 2003. Do Ukrainian Firms Benefit from FDI?. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref] 245. Jiahua Che. 2003. The Life Cycle of Government Ownership. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref] 246. Heinz Handler. 2003. Structural Reforms in the Candidate Countries and the European Union. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref] 247. Paulo Barelli, Samuel D. Pessoa. 2002. A Model of Capital Accumulation and Rent-Seeking. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref] 248. Peter Murrell. 2002. The Relative Levels and the Character of Institutional Development in Transition Economies. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref] 249. Peter Murrell. 2002. Institutions and Firms in Transition Economies. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref] 250. Peter Murrell. Institutions and Firms in Transition Economies 667-699. [Crossref] 251. Anna Maria Ferragina, Francesco Pastore. Regional Unemployment in the OST Literature 33-87. [Crossref] 252. Polona Domadenik, Maja Vehovec. Enterprise Defensive Restructuring: Cross-country Evidence within Transitional Settings 165-178. [Crossref] 253. Geoffrey M. Hodgson. Fifteen Years of Economic Transition 89-95. [Crossref]