WORKING PAPER SERIES 2 Kamil Dybczak: Generational Accounts in the Czech Republic WORKING PAPER SERIES Generational Accounts in the Czech Republic Kamil Dybczak 2/2006 CNB WORKING PAPER SERIES The Working Paper Series of the Czech National Bank (CNB) is intended to disseminate the results of the CNB's research projects as well as the other research activities of both the staff of the CNB and collaborating outside contributor, including invited speakers. The Series aims to present original research contributions relevant to central banks. It is refereed internationally. The referee process is managed by the CNB Research Department. The working papers are circulated to stimulate discussion. The views expressed are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the official views of the CNB. Printed and distributed by the Czech National Bank. Available at http://www.cnb.cz. Reviewed by: Radka Štiková (Czech National Bank) Roberto Cardarelli (International Monetary Fund) Marek Mora (European Commission) Project Coordinator: Vladimír Bezděk Czech National Bank, May 2006 Kamil Dybczak Generational Accounts in the Czech Republic Kamil Dybczak Abstract The government intertemporal budget constraint states that all public liabilities have to be financed by either current or future generations. The generational accounting approach incorporates the expected demographic development and the parameters of the current fiscal policy into the intertemporal government budget constraint. By contrast with the public debt and deficit, the indicators based on generational accounting are forward looking and provide us with additional information about the current fiscal policy. To assess the sustainability of public budgets we constructed the first set of generational accounts for the Czech Republic. We found that a representative living agent obtains more benefits than he/she pays in taxes in 2004, i.e. the generational account of this representative agent is negative. In addition, the total amount of the government liabilities resulting from the current fiscal policy pursued to 2150 reaches about 300% of GDP in 2004. Finally, the costs of postponed adjustment of government revenues and expenditures seem to be considerable. We conclude that the present fiscal policy is not sustainable, i.e. public budgets in the Czech Republic should be stabilized by changing the current system of taxes and benefits to reflect potential demographic development. JEL Codes: H61, E62. Keywords: Fiscal sustainability, generational accounting. Kamil Dybczak, Czech National Bank (kamil.dybczak@cnb.cz). This work was supported by Czech National Bank Research Project No. B5/2003. The author is deeply indebted to Vladimír Bezděk for valuable discussions and suggestions. The comments provided by Roberto Cardarelli, Narcisa Kadlčaková, Marek Mora, Ondřej Schneider, Kateřina Šmídková and Radka Štiková are highly appreciated. The views expressed are those of the author and do not necessarily reflect the official views of the Czech National Bank. The usual disclaimer applies. 2 Kamil Dybczak Nontechnical Summary The government intertemporal budget constraint states that all public liabilities have to be financed by either current or future generations. Since the size and the structure of these generations vary over time, even unchanged fiscal policy can generate a different per capita lifetime burden of a representative current and future agent. The generational accounting approach incorporates the expected demographic development and the parameters of the current fiscal policy into the intertemporal government budget constraint. Afterwards, based on this methodology, different indicators of fiscal sustainability are derived. By contrast with the public debt and deficit, these indicators are forward looking and provide us with additional information about the current fiscal policy. Unlike the previous studies of fiscal sustainability in the Czech Republic, the generational accounting approach captures sustainability from both the aggregate macroeconomic and representative agent's point of view. In our analysis both the residual and the sustainability approaches were implemented. We found no effect of different values of the discount rate, labour productivity growth and combinations thereof on the main results of our analysis. A representative living agent obtains more benefits than he/she pays in taxes in 2004, i.e. the generational account of this representative agent is negative. By contrast, a representative agent not yet born will face the opposite situation. Thus, the present fiscal policy is not sustainable, owing to the unequal treatment of current and future representative agents. In addition, if the discount rate equals 5% and productivity grows at 2% per year, we quantified the total amount of the government liabilities resulting from the current fiscal policy pursued to 2150 at about 300% of GDP in 2004. Thus, taking into account future demographic development and a strict indexation rule, the fiscal policy appears to be unsustainable. Finally, we found the costs of postponed adjustment of government revenues and expenditures to be considerable and rising over time. To summarise, we found the system of revenues and expenditure in the Czech Republic to be facing structural problems. So, even when the discount rate and labour productivity growth are set propitiously, the system of public finances remains unsustainable. In addition, the negative impact of demographic changes will aggravate the development of public finances in the future. According to the present analysis, the public budgets in the Czech Republic should be stabilized by changing the current system of taxes and benefits to reflect potential demographic development. Generational Accounts in the Czech Republic 3 1. Introduction The government provides a number of public services and commodities, such as health care, education, infrastructure etc. Some people take advantage of consuming them more than others. For example, education expenditures are aimed mainly at young people, while older people do not take advantage of the public education system at all. By contrast, pensioners receive retirement pensions which are not addressed at young people, etc. Since public services and commodities are consumed differently through the lifespan, it follows that the amount of public expenditure is affected by the size and structure of the population. At the same time, all expenditures have to be financed. The main part of government revenues comes from taxes and wealth sales. Unfortunately, government wealth is limited in general, i.e. privatization revenues are at the government's disposal to only a limited extent. Usually other revenue sources are also restricted.1 Thus, the major part of expenditures has to be financed by taxes. This means that agents finance public services (commodities) indirectly through taxes. As in the case of expenditures, the total amount of public revenues depends on the size and the structure of the population. Generally speaking, people pay taxes and receive benefits according to their position in the life cycle. If we divide society into three age groups (young, middle-aged, old), then only the middle- aged pay more into the public budgets than they receive. By contrast, the young and the old contribute to the public budgets to a very limited extent. Thus, a representative agent of a certain age is either a net contributor or a net beneficiary. This idea comes from the life cycle hypothesis.2 From our point of view it is important that people pay taxes and receive transfers differently over their lifespan. Based on these arguments, it follows that the size and structure of the population decisively affect the balance of public budgets. In fact, the government does not have to pay all its expenditure immediately using just tax revenues and privatization receipts. Where the government's expenditures exceed its revenues, it takes out a loan or issues bonds. Still, these obligations will have to be repaid one day. From the generational point of view this means that the use of alternative ways of financing results in shifts in the financial burden from current to future generations, i.e. so-called `intergenerational redistribution'. Thus, current fiscal policy affects the net wealth not only of generations alive at present but also of generations not yet born. Unfortunately, neither the commonly used public budget deficit nor public debt records any intergenerational shifts or the way in which current fiscal policy influences the net wealth of a representative current and future agent. One of the tools which can be used to assess intergenerational balance or imbalance is so-called `generational accounting'. This approach reflects the long-term implications of current fiscal policy arrangements for intergenerational redistribution and fiscal sustainability taking into account the expected demographic development. Thus generational accounting can provide us with additional information about the current state of 1 Although seigniorage can be an important part of public revenue, we do not include it in our analysis. This reflects the Czech reality. In the past the Czech National Bank (CNB) did not transfer seigniorage to the government because it was making losses. Moreover, since the CNB has accumulated a large stock of debt, the same fact holds for the near future. 2 See Modigliani (1963). 4 Kamil Dybczak fiscal policy and its potential implications next to the standard fiscal indicators. This methodology was developed by Auerbach, Gokhale and Kotlikoff in 1991. The main issue was to quantify the impact of a government policy on the net wealth of current and future generations. As a result, the tool is used as an instrument for assessing the sustainability of the current settings of public finances taking into account the expected demographic development. It is important to note that generational accounts do not provide the exact level of future government deficits. This is definitely not a forecasting tool. The goal is to compare the present value of the growth-adjusted lifetime burden faced by a representative current and future agent on condition that the intertemporal budget constraint holds. Alternatively, it is possible to calculate the total amount of the government liabilities stemming from the current fiscal policy proceeds indefinitely. Moreover, alternative scenarios could help to identify potential ways of improving the intergenerational imbalance. The sustainability of various tax and expenditure variants could be assessed by the same token. The classical generational accounting methodology evaluates taxes and transfers as monetary flows. Alternatively, generational accounts can be defined as a utility balance that results from the interaction between individuals and the public sector. In this case we would have to assess the individual's utility (disutility) of each component of net taxes over time. In our study we follow the monetary approach, since deciding on the utility of each public item seems very speculative. There is some criticism of the generational accounting methodology from both the theoretical and practical points of view.3 We would like to stress that generational accounting is not a generational equilibrium model based approach, but just an indicator based on a trend projection. On the contrary, this projection is elaborate, introducing some economic theory and expected demographic development. Using the generational accounting methodology we can infer what situation would arise if the present fiscal policy stayed unchanged provided that the rest of the economy does not react. The results can identify the intergenerational redistribution which would result from the government's current financing and spending decisions. The purpose of this paper is to assess the sustainability of the present fiscal policy in the case of the Czech Republic using the generational accounting methodology. Whereas generational accounts have been widely used for more than a decade worldwide, this is the first version of the generational accounts for the Czech Republic.4 Some authors have improved the generational accounts method, but we present more or less the original version without applying any special technique. In what follows, sections 2, 3 and 4 review the standard methodological framework of generational accounting. Section 2 discusses the theoretical framework of generational accounting. The third section specifies the variables and the parameters necessary to calculate the generational accounts of the current generations. Section 4 presents two main methods of assessing fiscal sustainability. In sections 5, 6 and 7, applied data and empirical results are presented. 3 See, for example, Auerbach, Gokhale and Kotlikoff (1994), who provide an extensive response to the critique of the method of generational accounting. 4 An overview of the application of generational accounting in different countries is provided by Auerbach, Kotlikoff and Leibfritz (1998). Generational Accounts in the Czech Republic 5 2. Intertemporal Public Budget Constraint The government intertemporal budget constraint says that the present value of current and future government revenues has to be equal to the sum of the present value of current and future government purchases and the level of net debt. In other words, net public debt Dt plus the present value of all net government purchases Gt,y have to be financed by the present value of the lifetime net taxes Nt,k paid by both current and future generations. Put formally, the government intertemporal budget constraint is stated as follows: (1) where Gt,y stands for the present value of year y net public purchases in period t (base year).5 Gt,y is calculated as the present value of the difference between public expenditures and revenues not affected by the size of the population. Dt is defined as the public debt in year t less the present value of expected privatization revenues.6 Finally, Nt,k denotes the present value of net taxes which will be paid through the life cycle by agents born in year k.7 It is obvious that the first item on the left hand side corresponds to the sum of the present values of all net taxes paid by currently living agents from now to the end of their lives. The second item on the left hand side tallies with the cumulative present value of lifetime net taxes of agents not yet born. The following section discusses all the variables step by step.8 Contrary to Gt,y, Nt,k denotes the present value of the difference between public revenues and expenditures affected by the size of the population. The distinction between public revenues and expenditures whose development is or is not affected by the size of the population is a standard procedure for generational accounting construction. 3. Specifications and Projections of Variables and Parameters 3.1 Lifetime Net Taxes of Current Generations The standard concept of generational accounting draws a line between the current and future generations. In the great majority of applied studies, generational accounts are constructed as a forward-looking indicator. This means that we reflect only the current and expected development of population size and structure. It follows that the total net taxes of currently living generations in present terms do not take into account the development of taxes and transfers before the base 5 All the fiscal data (Gt,y, Dt and total Nt,k) come from GFS 2004 (consolidated public budgets). For details see Appendix I. 6 Sometimes government net wealth Wt is used instead of net public debt, with the opposite sign. Because of the lack of data on government net wealth in the Czech Republic we prefer the variable Dt. Arguments can be found in section 5.4. 7 The symbolism is similar to Bonin (1997). Another, probably widely used, specification comes from Auerbach, Kotlikoff and Liebfritz (1998). 8 Although we distinguish between genders in the results, we suppress sex subscripts in all equations. = +=-= +=+ ty tyt tk kt t Ltk kt DGNN , 1 ,, 6 Kamil Dybczak year.9 Put differently, since generational accounts are constructed as a forward-looking indicator we do not cover the development of net taxes over the whole lifecycle for all currently living generations. In fact, the only current generation which we follow over the whole lifespan is the youngest one, i.e. the one born in the base year t.10 The current generations are defined as all agents who live in the present. Let t be the base year and L be the maximum length of life, then current agents were born between t-L and t. Thus, the present value of all net taxes paid by currently living agents is quantified over the period from t to t+L, i.e. until the youngest agent (born in the base year t) from the current generations dies. The first term on the left hand side in (1) can be expressed as: (2) where Pi,k is the number of people born in k and still living in i. Next, ti,k represents the absolute level of the net taxes paid in period i by a representative agent born in k. The discount rate r converts future net taxes to the base year. We presume that r is constant over the whole period. To quantify the total net taxes of currently living generations in present terms, according to formula (2), we need a projection of demographic development as well as the projection of the net taxes paid in period i by a representative agent born in year k. On the one hand, the demographic projection is usually received from the national statistical office or other institution and accepted as it is. On the other hand, the base-year age-specific per capita taxes and transfers tl i,k of type l are projected by applying the constant (time invariant) growth rate g.11 It is usually assumed, for projection purposes, that the growth rate g should reflect labour productivity growth, i.e. age- and gender-adjusted per capita taxes and transfers grow at the rate of labour productivity. Thus, applying constant g does not alter the shape of the particular average absolute tax and transfer age profiles. It follows that the share of the corresponding items in the income of a representative agent of the same age and gender is constant over time, i.e. all individuals of the same age and gender face the same lifetime net tax rate.12 tl i,k can be calculated for different k in each year i using the formula (4). (3) 9 Gokhale J., Page B. (1997) calculated total net taxes of all current generations taking into account demography together with taxes and benefits also before the base year. 10 Later in this section we will show that this is the only generation out of the currently living population whose generational account will be used for evaluating the sustainability of the current fiscal policy. 11 Just as in the case of r we assume g to be constant over the whole period, but alternative scenarios are presented in section 6. 12 Introducing this assumption seems to be the standard approach to generational accounts. By contrast, reflecting potential changes in age-specific profiles as a result of population ageing could make the projections more reliable. + + =-=-= = Lkt Ltk t Ltk ktN ti i-t ki,ki,, r)(1Pt tgt l jkt jl kjt -+ += ,, )1( Generational Accounts in the Czech Republic 7 where tl i,k expresses the average tax or transfer of type l of the representative agent born in k in year i.13 If tl i,k is positive (negative) then the item represents a tax (transfer) paid (obtained). We should stress that the key lies in deciding what taxes and transfers are influenced by the number of people and the age structure of the population.14 It seems almost impossible to specify the components of net taxes precisely, since both the revenue and expenditure sides of the public budgets contain a wide variety of items. For some of them it is hard to decide which group they should belong to. Thus a close examination of the individual items is necessary. Finally, aggregating all the taxes and transfers of type l, we get the absolute net taxes of a representative agent born in k in year i, i.e. ti,k .15 (4) It is worth noting that neither in the residual approach nor in the sustainability approach16 is the total present value of the net taxes of the current generations restricted. Whatever approach we choose, the total present value of the net taxes of the current generations is quantified using the same procedure, i.e. formula (2) is applied. 3.2 Generational Accounts of Current Generations The length of the remaining lifespan (k+L-t) of currently living agents varies in the base year because of different k. Thus, the present values of the remaining lifetime net taxes of currently living generations born in k, defined as Nt,k, are not directly comparable among themselves. But it is possible to compare the net taxes in present value terms of a representative agent of age i-k in the base year t. Finally, we define a year t account of a generation born in k as the present value of taxes paid minus the present value of transfers obtained throughout the rest of the life divided by the number of agents in the base year t. Generational accounts for different k are calculated according to formula (5) and labelled as GACUR t,k. (5) The expression Pi,k/Pt,k in formula (5) represents the ratio of the population born in k and still alive in i to the base year t, i.e. it can be called a survival probability. Since the population dies out, it is clear that Pi,kj.17 Using equation (2) we can present the generational account equivalently as shown in formula (6). Put differently, the generational account stands for the present value net taxes of a representative agent born in k and still living in t. 13 Section 5 provides a detailed description of the different types of taxes and transfers. The data used for estimation purposes are described as well. In addition, Appendix II presents figures of different tl . 14 The inputs to the generational accounts will be discussed in section 5. 15 Taxes are treated in positive terms and transfers in negative terms. 16 Both the residual and sustainability approaches are discussed in detail in section 4. 17 This effect can be mitigated by migration. P r)(1Pt , ti i-t ki,ki, , kt Lk CUR ktGA + + = = = l l kiki tt ,, 8 Kamil Dybczak P , , , kt ktCUR kt N GA = (6) where Nt,k represents the present value of the lifetime net taxes which are paid by individuals born in k and still living in the base period t. Identically to the end of the preceding subsection, we would like to note that the quantification of the generational accounts of currently living generations is not influenced by the following either residual or sustainability approach. 3.3 Government Purchases It should be pointed out that Gt,y has a different meaning than government consumption in the national accounts. According to the generational accounts methodology, Gt,y is defined as the balance of expenditure and revenue items which do not count towards net taxes. In other words, Gt,y is composed of revenues and expenditures whose size does not depend on the size of the living population. The projection method of government purchases is similar to the one discussed before in relation to the projection of age-specific tax and transfer profiles. The projection is even simpler, because it is not necessary to estimate the amount relating to the specific age group. The total amount is projected using the similar growth rate g as in the case of the age-specific tax and transfer profiles. 4. Intergenerational Imbalance and Fiscal Sustainability Appraisal The theoretical concept of generational accounting is widely accepted. But there are several ways of constructing generational accounts. Many countries now publish their generational accounts complete with the methodology used. The main idea is uniform, but important partial differences can still be found. To assess the intergenerational imbalance (sustainability of public finances), different indicators based on the generational accounting methodology can be constructed. In the following sections, two major approaches will be discussed ­ the residual and the sustainability approach. But alternative ways can also be applied.18 4.1 Residual Approach and Generational Accounts of Future Generations The present fiscal situation can be resolved by introducing alternative adjustments. First, the net taxes of the present agents can be modified. Second, the government has the possibility of reducing the actual and potential level of its purchases. Third, the government might not want to solve the unfavourable situation immediately, i.e. it can defer solving the problem to the future. As a consequence, the total net taxes of future agents are implicitly increased. In the residual approach we assume that the government is not willing to change the current settings of the system for the time being. As a result, all the changes needed to attain fiscal sustainability will be faced by future generations. 18 For example, Cardarelli, Sefton and Kotlikoff (1999) consider a necessary change in government purchases or a change in the specific net tax rate to close the sustainability gap as alternative indicators of intergenerational imbalance/fiscal sustainability. Generational Accounts in the Czech Republic 9 The residual approach proceeds in the following steps. First, the total present value of the net taxes of all currently living agents is calculated, applying no constraint on its value, using formula (2). Second, the present value of expected net public debt and net public purchases is calculated. Finally, the intertemporal budget constraint is applied to calculate the sum of the present value of the net taxes of future agents. Since the intertemporal budget constraint must hold, the sum of the present value of the net taxes of all future generations is calculated as a residual, as presented in equation (7). Hence in the residual approach all fiscal parameters have already been fixed except the ones which influence the total present value of the net taxes of future generations. This is the only variable which can vary. Put differently, a current fiscal policy that improves current agents' wealth will ceteris paribus burden future generations in the negative direction, and vice versa. (7) The size and structure of future generations vary over time. In addition, labour productivity is increasing. Thus, it is not possible to directly compare the absolute levels of the present value of the total lifetime net taxes of the currently living and future generations as calculated using formulas (2) and (7). Indeed, we have to reflect expected demographic development as well as the growing labour productivity if we want to compare the fiscal burden which will be faced by a representative current and future agent. We have already presented the way in which the generational accounts of currently living generations are computed using formula (5) or (6). There is only one current generation which we follow over the whole lifespan, i.e. the youngest one. Its generational account (GACUR t,t ) will be compared with the generational accounts of future generations. There are few ways of calculating future generational accounts. Usually the generational accounts of future agents are assumed to be equal except for a productivity growth adjustment.19 Taking into account these assumptions the generational account of a representative future agent is calculated as follows: (9) Because the generational accounts of both generations (GACUR t,t , GAFUT k,k) reflect the expected lifetime growth-adjusted net tax payments of a representative agent discounted to the base year, they are directly comparable. In the residual approach, the condition for examining the sustainability of a particular fiscal policy is based on comparing the growth-adjusted net taxes of current and future representative agents. It follows that different treatment of current and future generations from the point of view of the net taxes of a representative agent is a criterion for deciding about the size and direction of the 19 Unfortunately, introducing the above assumptions, the residual approach does not enable us to express anything about redistribution within future generations. += - += + + = 1 ,, 1 , )1( )1( tk tk FUT kkkk tk kt r g GAPN -= = += -+= t Ltk kt ty tyt tk kt NDGN ,, 1 , 10 Kamil Dybczak intergenerational redistribution. In other words, comparing the value of GACUR t,t and GAFUT k,k reflects the intergenerational shifts necessary to sustain public budgets. It means that when applying the residual approach a fiscal strategy which affects current and future agents differently (GACUR t,t GAFUT k,k), is called intergenerationally imbalanced. Because intergenerational shifts are necessary to ensure the validity of the intertemporal budget constraint, such a fiscal policy is also called unsustainable. Looking at the problem from the other perspective, we see that a sustainable fiscal policy will not lead to any intergenerational redistribution and GACUR t,t = GAFUT k,k. 4.2 Sustainability Approach The sustainability approach looks at current and future generations in the same manner. This means that the total lifetime net taxes of current and future generations are constructed using the same procedure, i.e. using formula (2) and its modification for future generations. Consequently, the total lifetime net taxes of all generations are constructed without applying the intertemporal budget constraint. The sustainability approach takes into consideration the overall demographic development of all generations. The sustainability approach slightly modifies the budget constraint. The items of the budget constraint in formula (10) are constructed in the same way as in the residual approach except for the sum of the total present value of net taxes of future generations. The criterion of fiscal sustainability is the so-called `sustainability gap'.20 It is defined as the total amount of the government liabilities resulting from the current fiscal policy pursued indefinitely, i.e. the imbalance in the intertemporal budget constraint. Alternatively, the sustainability gap equals the total present value of lacking public revenues which is desired to fulfil the intertemporal public budget constraint. On the one hand, if the sustainability gap is positive the present value of all potential public expenditures exceeds the present value of all public revenues. Thus, the gap shows the size of the liabilities that the government will have to redeem. On the other hand, a negative sustainability gap indicates a government intertemporal surplus and the option of reducing net taxes. (10) where N't,k indicates the total present value of the net taxes of future agents resulting from pursuing the present fiscal policy indefinitely. Because the sustainability approach does not distinguish between current and future generations, we can simulate the impact of a tax or a transfer on both living and future generations. But at the same time, by contrast with the residual approach, we know nothing about intergenerational redistribution. Since the absolute present value of the sustainability gap is hard to interpret, it is recommended to relate the sustainability gap to GDP. This ratio can be used for international comparison. As in the previous approach the final result should not be used as a forecast of public indebtedness. 20 It is possible to find other names for this indicator; for example, Cardarelli, Sefton and Kotlikoff (1999) call it the `intertemporal budget gap'. DNNGSG t tk kt t Ltk kt ty ytt +--= +=-= = 1 ,,, Generational Accounts in the Czech Republic 11 5. General Data Description In creating generational accounts for the Czech Republic, we follow the standard procedure. The empirical evaluation of the intertemporal budget constraint requires projections of population, taxes, transfers, government purchases and the initial value of net public debt. At the same time the value of parameters g and r has to be set. We start with the 2004 data. The main data sources used are the FoS UK (Faculty of Sciences, Charles University, Prague) population projection21 the CZSO (Czech Statistical Office) household budget survey and the MF (Ministry of Finance) government financial statistics. 5.1 Demography Generational accounting is based on a long-term population projection, i.e. demography plays a key role in determining the size of the intergenerational imbalance. Because generational accounts (GACUR t,,k and GAFUT k,k) are defined as per capita net taxes in present terms, the value is influenced by the size of the generation. Since the size of future generations is expected to fall in the coming decades, the total amount of net taxes Nt,k is divided by a smaller number Pk,k. In other words, the accumulated public debt will have to be financed by a smaller number of people. In addition, the structure of the population critically influences the absolute amount of net taxes. The original idea presented in the previous sections assumes that all government obligations have to be financed over an infinite time horizon. In practice it is not realistic to project all the necessary data to infinity. It is presumed that a nearly 150-year time horizon is long enough.22 There are important differences between males and females. Women live longer than men on average, but there are other distinctions which significantly affect the generational accounts. For example, due to wage discrimination, the wage of the average woman is not as high as that of the average man, so direct taxes and social security contributions are also different. In addition, the amount of indirect taxes differs as a result of the different consumption behaviours of the two genders. 5.2 Age-Specific Revenues and Expenditures23 The main part of the revenue and expenditure age profiles was taken from the Household Budget Survey 2002. In our particular case we constructed age-specific profiles just using year 2002 data. First, it is difficult to acquire and treat the data. Second, we believe that a change in age-specific profiles needs strong incentives and moreover takes more years. Thus, we found no major flaws using just one year observations. The raw data is rather erratic, but a still apparent age-specific profile can be recognized. Following the generational accounting literature and trying to make our analysis and figures more tractable we filtered all the data using an HP filter. Again, the filtering does not influence the results of our analysis. After that, the relative age profiles were calculated and recalculated to fit the actual budget data.24 21 Burcin B. and Kučera T. (2004). 22 Thanks to discounting, the present value of all variables beyond this period is negligible. 23 Bonin (1997) shows that using terms `Age-specific' and `Non-age-specific' could be misleading. We acknowledge this argument, but continue using them because of their broad utilization. 24 For detailed information, see Appendix II ­ Age-Specific Taxes and Transfers 12 Kamil Dybczak We are conscious of the fact that many important relations proposed by the economic theory are neglected when constructing generational accounts. Nevertheless, we did not apply any sophisticated projection method. Instead, we projected all net taxes using formula (4) presented in the previous section. Once more, we would like to stress the role of generational accounts as a ceteris paribus indicator of intergenerational imbalance and fiscal sustainability. There is uncertainty about future productivity growth and the discount rate. Moreover, it is hard to choose specific values for r and g. So, we introduced a set of both parameters into our empirical analysis. This seems to be the standard approach to generational accounting in order to show the sensitivity of the results to adjustment in the values of g and r. The value of r is influenced by the government revenues and expenditure risk, which is hard to judge from today's perspective.25 In the case of labour productivity growth we mainly took into account long-run factors and the convergence of the Czech economy to the EU average. We calculated generational accounts for current and future generations and the sustainability gap using variant g (0.01, 0.02, 0.03) and r (0.03, 0.05, 0.07). 5.2.1 Revenues Using the 2004 GFS methodology the total government revenues (expenditures) amounted to CZK 1,062 (1,160) billion. The ratio of age-specific revenues (expenditures) to total revenues (expenditures) is about 94 (87) %.26 For the empirical evaluation of the generational accounts, gathering the age-specific profiles of taxes and transfers of both genders is necessary. Taxes and transfers are broken down into several categories. First, public revenue and expenditure items, whose size depends on the number and age of people, have to be identified. In the case of the Czech Republic the following revenue items have been chosen: Value Added Tax (VAT) (19.3%)27 Excises (E) (9%) Personal Income Tax (PIT) (12.6%) Social Security Contributions (SSC) (36.6%) Inheritance Tax (IT) (1.4%) Corporate Income Tax (CIT) (11.3%) Other Age-Specific Revenues (OR) (3.7%) Second, all public budget revenue items are assigned to individual age groups on the basis of the Household Budget Survey 2002. The only exception is Corporate Income Tax, which is treated like a tax on labour income (Personal Income Tax), i.e. the relative age profiles of both personal and corporate income taxes are identical.28 The idea behind this argument is that the burden of corporate income tax is ultimately carried mainly by employees, followed by consumers and shareholders. 25 Lau (2000) applied a varying discount rate according to age for different agents. 26 For details see Appendix II ­ General Government Operations, 2004. 27 The number indicates the percentage of the total revenue. 28 Some working papers elaborate on Corporate Income Tax more sophisticatedly. See, for example, Auerbach and Chang (2003) or see Cardarelli R., Sefton J. and Kotlikoff L. J. (1999) for details. Generational Accounts in the Czech Republic 13 When inspecting the age-specific profiles we clearly see that the personal income tax and social contributions paid by an individual depend on his/her age. It is evident that agents aged between 18 and 60 earn more than children and pensioners, so the direct taxes paid by this specific age group are the highest. Since private consumption evolves in line with income, the same conclusion holds for indirect taxes. Thus, value added tax and excises also depend heavily on the age of the individual. 5.2.2 Expenditures We found the following expenditure items to be age specific: Old-Age Pensions (P) (19.9%) Disability Pensions (DP) (4.2%)29 Unemployment Benefits (UB) (3.4%) Education Expenditures (EE) (10%) Health Expenditures (HE) (15.1%) Sickness Benefits (SB) (2.1%) Other Social Expenditures (OSE) (5.8%) Other Age-Specific Expenditures (OE) (26.5%). The data concerning all forms of pension benefits comes from the Czech Social Security Administration database. The information on Education Expenditures was provided by the Ministry of Education, Youth and Sports. The General Health Insurance Company provided the health care data. As in the case of revenue, the remaining age-specific expenditure profiles were obtained from the Household Budget Survey 2002. It is assumed that Other Age-Specific Revenues and Other Age-Specific Expenditures are distributed evenly over all age groups. First, in a few cases it is hard to even recognize if there is any age-specific profile. Second, it is difficult to obtain all the profiles. Our study shows that the largest part of age-specific expenditures is other age-specific expenditures, i.e. with a flat age profile. This could appear unsatisfactory at first sight, but we have to bear in mind that this item is the sum of expenditures on General Public Services, Defence, Housing, Public Order and Safety. In our view it is impossible to quantify which age group uses more/less of these public expenditures. So, for example, we assume that the level of expenditure on defence depends on the size of the population, but not on its age structure. 29 Other forms of pension benefits (survivor's pensions) were assigned to old-age. 14 Kamil Dybczak 5.3 Government Purchases Government purchases were quantified as a balance of non-age-specific expenditures and non- age-specific revenues. The ratio of non-age-specific revenues (expenditures) to total revenues (expenditures) is about 6.0 (12.9) %.30 We detected the following revenue items: Property Income (2.5%) Capital Revenue (1.1%) Grants (2.4%) and the following expenditure items: Fuel and Energy (0.2%) Agriculture and Forestry (2.5%) Mining and Mineral Resources (0.2%) Transport and Communications (10.0%) not to be dependent on the number of people and their age. The absolute amount of Gt is CZK 86 billion in 2004, i.e. the value of non-age-specific expenditures exceeds that of non-age- specific revenues by CZK 86 billion in 2004. 5.4 Public Net Wealth and Net Debt The last but not least item from the intertemporal budget constraint is government net wealth or public net debt. There is no difference in applying either net wealth or net debt, but finding the appropriate number is not as easy as it seems at first sight. Net wealth is defined as the part of assets financed entirely by own resources. In other words it is a potential source of privatization revenues. In fact, it is difficult to determine the actual market price of public assets.31 To summarize, the evaluation of public assets is definitely not an easy task. In the case of the Czech Republic the most important government assets are non-financial assets. They comprise fixed assets such as roads, public buildings, land and so forth. Unfortunately, the size and value of that public property has not been precisely specified in the Czech Republic yet.32 The key issue is whether and to what extent these fixed assets could be sold to raise lacking revenues. In addition, it is hard to imagine that the government would sell all of its assets.33 30 For details see Appendix II ­ General Government Operations, 2004. 31 As an alternative, some authors try to estimate the market value of public net wealth as the sum of the present value of the financial flows from public assets. 32 Public finances have been growing in deficit since 1995. Regardless of this unfavourable development, net public wealth has been rising continually according to the CZSO. Government wealth is rising not because of prudent government financial policy, but due to evolving accounting procedures at the CZSO with respect to the recording of public assets. 33 To overcome this problem some authors estimate the value of government wealth that can be privatized. See, for example, Gál R.I., Simonovits A., Szabó M. and Tarcali G. (2000). Generational Accounts in the Czech Republic 15 In our view, government net wealth according to the national accounts overestimates the value of property which can really be privatized. Unfortunately, no such estimate is available for the Czech Republic. As a result, we define Dt as gross public debt less actual privatization revenues and less the expected present value of future privatization revenues for the next few years.34 6. Results Following the standard generational accounting methodology, we quantified the first set of generational accounts for the Czech Republic. The analysis covers the entire public sector during the period from 2004 to 2150. Because of the differences between the sexes we calculated the generational accounts separately for males and females. Following the structure of the theoretical part, the generational accounts of the currently living agents were computed at the beginning. Consequently, they were applied when both the residual and the sustainability approach were followed. Tables 1 and 2 show the present value of the remaining lifetime taxes and transfers of a representative agent when labour productivity growth is set to 2% and the discount rate to 5%. The different columns represent particular tax and revenue items. Finally, the generational accounts of current generations are defined as the sum of all columns in Tables 1 and 2. Table 1: Generational Accounts and their Components for Females (2004, thousand CZK) Age VAT E PIT SSC IT CIT OR P DP SD UB OSE EE HE OE GA2004 0 599 243 260 769 37 234 136 -368 -77 -62 -108 -260 -739 -483 -1298 -1117 5 660 281 301 891 42 271 135 -427 -89 -71 -125 -259 -760 -498 -1286 -933 10 690 304 326 963 46 293 127 -450 -95 -77 -136 -252 -591 -498 -1219 -571 15 720 333 356 1054 49 320 121 -478 -104 -85 -151 -242 -363 -506 -1155 -130 20 751 364 403 1196 54 362 118 -535 -117 -93 -159 -230 -134 -531 -1127 321 25 720 356 428 1275 54 384 111 -577 -125 -88 -140 -207 0 -530 -1059 602 30 673 339 438 1308 53 394 104 -640 -134 -75 -117 -182 0 -533 -997 631 35 640 329 440 1303 54 395 101 -751 -148 -66 -99 -156 0 -564 -970 508 40 583 308 403 1167 54 362 95 -846 -156 -58 -80 -118 0 -578 -912 224 45 529 282 337 940 53 303 89 -967 -157 -50 -60 -79 0 -591 -856 -227 50 459 240 245 656 49 220 81 -1085 -142 -36 -37 -51 0 -580 -779 -758 55 384 193 143 365 43 128 73 -1213 -115 -20 -13 -37 0 -559 -701 -1329 60 309 152 55 127 37 49 65 -1169 -92 -6 0 -29 0 -527 -620 -1649 65 244 120 12 19 29 10 56 -1005 -73 0 0 -25 0 -480 -531 -1624 70 192 93 0 0 22 0 46 -802 -54 0 0 -20 0 -410 -436 -1369 75 148 71 0 0 17 0 36 -598 -36 0 0 -13 0 -326 -342 -1043 80 112 53 0 0 13 0 27 -423 -21 0 0 -7 0 -248 -257 -752 85 80 38 0 0 10 0 19 -290 -12 0 0 -5 0 -183 -184 -527 90 55 26 0 0 7 0 13 -188 -8 0 0 -4 0 -131 -127 -355 95 39 18 0 0 5 0 9 -116 -6 0 0 -3 0 -92 -89 -233 100 16 7 0 0 2 0 4 -41 -3 0 0 -1 0 -37 -36 -90 Note: Value Added Tax (VAT), Excises (E), Personal Income Tax (PIT), Social Security Contributions (SSC), Inheritance Tax (IT), Corporate Income Tax (CIT), Other Age-Specific Revenues (OR), Old-Age Pensions (P), Disability Pensions (DP), Unemployment Benefits (UB), Education Expenditures (EE), Health Expenditures (HE), Sick Benefits (SB), Other Social Expenditures (OSE), Other Age-Specific Expenditures (OE). 34 The estimates of current and future privatization revenues come from the document: Projection of Revenues and Expenditure in 2006. The document offers a rough estimate of privatization revenues in 2006 and 2007. 16 Kamil Dybczak Table 2: Generational Accounts and their Components for Males (2004, thousand CZK) Age VAT E PIT SSC IT CIT OR P DP SD UB OSE EE HE OE GA2004 0 572 231 361 1068 36 325 143 -358 -81 -68 -118 -262 -747 -526 -1363 -789 5 624 265 416 1230 41 374 140 -413 -93 -78 -134 -262 -760 -522 -1337 -509 10 642 283 444 1313 44 399 131 -426 -99 -84 -145 -248 -588 -501 -1248 -83 15 663 307 482 1425 47 433 122 -441 -106 -92 -159 -229 -359 -495 -1167 432 20 687 333 543 1611 51 488 117 -482 -118 -100 -167 -210 -132 -515 -1121 987 25 658 326 577 1716 51 518 109 -510 -124 -95 -147 -186 0 -521 -1043 1330 30 616 311 582 1729 50 523 102 -562 -134 -82 -124 -163 0 -541 -977 1331 35 592 307 567 1667 50 509 100 -670 -152 -71 -109 -143 0 -598 -953 1096 40 535 286 505 1449 49 453 92 -747 -162 -61 -89 -114 0 -621 -880 695 45 481 266 438 1210 48 393 85 -855 -170 -54 -70 -81 0 -648 -814 228 50 414 233 351 935 44 315 76 -956 -163 -44 -48 -52 0 -646 -725 -266 55 344 195 251 655 39 226 67 -1102 -141 -28 -23 -35 0 -634 -640 -826 60 273 155 140 362 33 126 58 -1186 -106 -11 0 -24 0 -599 -556 -1335 65 212 119 43 113 27 38 49 -1100 -77 0 0 -16 0 -545 -472 -1608 70 162 90 0 14 21 0 41 -899 -53 0 0 -9 0 -467 -387 -1488 75 122 68 0 0 14 0 32 -689 -33 0 0 -4 0 -376 -307 -1174 80 92 51 0 0 10 0 25 -515 -19 0 0 -3 0 -288 -238 -884 85 69 39 0 0 7 0 19 -377 -11 0 0 -2 0 -212 -179 -647 90 51 29 0 0 6 0 14 -255 -6 0 0 -2 0 -155 -132 -450 95 37 21 0 0 4 0 10 -156 -4 0 0 -1 0 -112 -96 -297 100 15 8 0 0 2 0 4 -51 -2 0 0 0 0 -44 -38 -107 Note: Value Added Tax (VAT), Excises (E), Personal Income Tax (PIT), Social Security Contributions (SSC), Inheritance Tax (IT), Corporate Income Tax (CIT), Other Age-Specific Revenues (OR), Old-Age Pensions (P), Disability Pensions (DP), Unemployment Benefits (UB), Education Expenditures (EE), Health Expenditures (HE), Sick Benefits (SB), Other Social Expenditures (OSE), Other Age-Specific Expenditures (OE). The same, but aggregated, information is depicted in Figure 1. The horizontal axis represents the age of the agent in 2004. The vertical axis depicts the average remaining lifetime net tax burden (generational account) of each current generation. In other words, the vertical axis shows the cumulated present value of all taxes and transfers which is paid by a representative agent of different age between 2004 and the end of his/her life. To be more specific, the average male who is 30 years old in 2004 will pay taxes and receive transfers for an additional 70 years. As a result he accumulates a surplus whose present value is about CZK 1,331,000 in 2004. Put differently, such a male on average pays CZK 1,331,000 more on taxes than he receives in benefits over the rest of his life (between years 30 to 100), without taking into account previous taxes paid and expenditures received (between years 0 and 29). By contrast, an average male at the age of 70 in 2004 accumulates a deficit of CZK 1,488,000 over the next 30 years, i.e. the government pays him CZK 1,488,000 more than he pays in taxes (between years 70 and 100). To help the reader get through all the numbers easily it is important to realize where all the characteristics can be found. Since we are interested in comparing the accounts of current and future generations, we only take into account generations that last a whole life cycle. In the case of currently living generations there is only one possibility, i.e. we concentrate on the generation which came into existence in 2004. The generational account of agents born in 2004 of both sexes can be found in the first row and the last column of Tables 1 and 2 (-1117 and -789). Actually, the last columns of Tables 1 and 2 are depicted in Figure 1. The overall generational account, which neglects the differences between the sexes, is a weighted average of the generational accounts of males and females (the dashed line). Since Tables 1 and 2 and Figure 1 show calculations based on the growth rate set to 2% and the discount rate set to 5%, the same numbers can also be found in Table 3. Generational Accounts in the Czech Republic 17 Figure 1: Generational Accounts of Current Generations by Gender (2004, thousand CZK) -2000 -1500 -1000 -500 0 500 1000 1500 2000 0 3 6 9 12 15 18 21 24 27 30 33 36 39 42 45 48 51 54 57 60 63 66 69 72 75 78 81 84 87 90 93 96 99 ThousandsofCZK Male Female Total It is possible to draw some important conclusions using the tables and the figure. The significant part of Figure 1 lies below zero. This means that the significant part of the current population gets more from the public budget than it pays in taxes during its remaining lifetime. In other words, only people aged approximately from 12 to 45 (in 2004) will produce a positive difference between remaining lifetime taxes and transfers. By contrast, the rest of the population will generate a deficit. If we take into account population ageing and the worsening age structure, the current system of taxes and transfers looks unsustainable even when checking the figure visually. The generational account of a representative agent who was born in 2004 is negative, i.e. the agent will obtain more from the public budget than he/she will pay over his/her entire lifespan. When the discount rate equals 5% and labour productivity growth equals 2%, the generational account of a representative agent born in 2004 is CZK -948,000. In other words, each agent born in 2004 will on average cumulate a lifetime deficit whose present value in 2004 is CZK -948,000. If the government cannot finance these deficits using extra revenue sources, intergenerational shifts of the fiscal burden are expected. So, even without quantifying the generational accounts of future generations and the sustainability gap we can say that the current fiscal policy leads to an intergenerational redistribution of the fiscal burden and should be changed. The difference between the male and female generational accounts seems to be important. We admit that addressing the differences between the sexes is not the main goal of our analysis. Nevertheless, it is interesting to realize how differences in position on the labour market, consumption behaviour etc. can influence the sustainability of public finances. Figure 1 shows that the average man born in 2004 accumulates a lifetime deficit lower than that of the average woman by almost CZK 330,000 in terms of the year 2004. When building generational accounts, we explicitly assume that age- and gender-adjusted absolute per capita taxes and transfers grow in relation to labour productivity growth. Moreover, to make the different generational accounts comparable we have to discount future values to the base year 18 Kamil Dybczak 2004. Thus, the present value of future taxes and transfers depends heavily on the size of the discount rate and the labour productivity growth rate.35 Introducing different values of the two key parameters affects the results as shown in Table 3. Table 3: Generational Accounts of Current and Future Generations under Different Scenarios (thousand CZK) g (%) 1 2 3 r (%) 3 5 7 3 5 7 3 5 7 GA current -1081 -902 -862 -1497 -948 -883 -2629 -1090 -904 GA future 2761 2021 1682 4655 2910 2122 8534 4512 2849 Sustainability gap (%GDP) 454 211 131 797 297 131 1608 460 214 When testing the sensitivity of fiscal sustainability with respect to g and r, we found the following conclusions. Increasing productivity growth leads to the gap between public expenditures and revenues broadening.36 Putting it simply, both taxes and transfers are indexed by the same measure. So the gap, whether positive or negative, grows at the same rate if the structure and size of the population are not changing. Unfortunately, in the case of the Czech Republic the gap is negative, and demographic development will make the situation even worse. The higher the discount rate the lower the generational account of current generations. The same conclusion applies to the size of the generational account of future generations and to the sustainability gap. Since the discount rate is used to translate future values into present terms, a higher r improves the current value of future deficits. In all cases of different g and r the present value of the net tax burden of a representative agent is negative, i.e. this agent obtains more transfers than pays in taxes over his/her whole lifetime. By contrast, the generational accounts of future generations, calculated using the residual approach, are positive. This implies that next generations will face the opposite situation to currently living generations from the tax and transfer point of view. The higher generational account of future generations indicates that the present fiscal policy is not sustainable and should be changed. If the structure of public revenues and expenditures is held fixed and the demography develops in accordance with our projection, we estimate the sustainability gap to be positive regardless of the combination of g and r. The sustainability gap indicates the size of the adjustment needed to achieve fiscal sustainability, i.e. it is defined as the accumulated present value of future deficits owing to changes in demography parameters and unchanged fiscal policy between 2004 and 2150.37 For example, if the discount rate equals 5% and productivity grows at 2%, the government accumulates debt of 297% of 2004 GDP between 2004 and 2150, as presented in Table 3. If g increases by just 1 percentage point to 3%, the ratio of the sustainability gap to GDP rises to 460% ceteris paribus. It seems that indexation of taxes and benefits is an important factor for the potential development of public finances. 35 The problems of choosing g and r are discussed in section 5.2. 36 The sentence holds if revenues and expenditures are strictly indexed on labour productivity growth. Under this condition and applying our approach we could say that productivity growth does not help. But we have to be cautious. It is tempting to say that this paper finds the current fiscal policy settings to be unsustainable when indexed to productivity growth. Again we have to stress that our approach lacks the reaction of the rest of the economy to fiscal policy and vice versa. 37 The level of the sustainability gap is presented in relation to GDP. Generational Accounts in the Czech Republic 19 Since the beginning of the 1990s generational accounts have been constructed for many countries all over the world. To give the reader some idea about the situation in other countries we present part of the results from Auerbach, Kotlikoff and Leibfritz (1998) and Gál, Simonovits, Szabó and Tarcali (2000).38 All the results are calculated setting g to 1.5% and r to 5%. Table 4: Sustainability Gaps in Different Countries (% of GDP) Baseline scenario No Demographic Change Zero Initial Debt United States 159 22 97 Japan 337 77 309 Germany 156 -8 81 Italy 223 18 98 Sweden -31 -67 -45 Belgium 107 63 -218 Hungary 424 119 384 Czech Republic 248 152 226 Note: In the case of the Czech Republic the base year is set to 2004. The rest of the data relates to 1995. Comparing the results on the sustainability gap to GDP in Table 4 for different countries, we can draw the following conclusions. First, The No Demographic Change scenario indicates how large the sustainability gap would be if the size and structure of the population remain stable. Table 4 demonstrates that changing demography seems to be a significant factor which negatively affects the intergenerational imbalance in all the countries. Second, leaving aside the impact of public debt alleviates the intergenerational imbalance. But its extent, except in the case of Belgium, appears to be substantially smaller than that of changing demography. The equivalent outcome holds in the case of the Czech Republic, i.e. the impact of changing population size and structure exceeds the impact of zero initial debt. Third, in the case of the Czech Republic the difference between the Baseline scenario and the No Demographic Change value seems to be smaller. It appears that there are other important factors in addition to worsening demographic conditions. As already mentioned, the intergenerational imbalance would not disappear with higher labour productivity growth. This indicates that the system of taxes and transfers in the Czech Republic faces structural problems, i.e. under the current set-up of public revenues and expenditures the system of public finances is predetermined to generate deficit financing.39 In addition, the impact of demographic factors aggravates the fiscal/ intergenerational imbalance. To sketch the potential impact of intentional adjustments in taxes and transfers, we present mechanistic simulations of the impact of a variation in selected age-specific profiles on intergenerational redistribution and fiscal sustainability. On the revenue side a 10% increase in the age-specific profile of value added tax (VAT) and personal income tax (PIT) is introduced. On the expenditure side a 10% decrease in the age-specific profile of old-age pensions (P) and health expenditures (HE) is introduced. In other words a representative agent will pay/obtain 10% 38 We are conscious of the fact that the generational accounts methodology is not unified. In addition, the results concerning countries other than the Czech Republic are almost ten years old. This means that important changes relating to demography and fiscal policy could have occurred since that time. 39 Even if no negative demographic factors come into effect. See, for example, Bezdek, Dybczak and Krejdl (2003). 20 Kamil Dybczak more/less in absolute terms compared to the baseline scenario.40 The results are presented in Table 5. Indeed, all of the presented scenarios improve the intergenerational imbalance and fiscal sustainability indicators. The improvement appears to be significant, but not sufficient. The combination of all the refinements reduces the ratio of the sustainability gap to GDP by almost 100 percentage points. This is still not enough to solve the problems of intergenerational redistribution and fiscal sustainability. We should stress again the pure mechanistic nature of these results. Table 5: The Impact of a 10% Adjustment in Taxes and Transfers (thousand CZK) Baseline VAT PIT P HE TOTAL GA current -948 -889 -917 -912 -897 -771 GA future 2910 1613 1673 1535 1604 1079 Sustainability gap (%GDP) 297 275 284 269 274 204 Finally, Table 6 presents information about the impact of changing demographic factors on the generational accounts of future agents. The results indicate the present value of the growth- adjusted net taxes of a representative future agent which guarantees fiscal sustainability.41 According to our calculations, it is evident that the generational account of the future agent increases over time in the case of the Czech Republic. Moreover, if no changes in taxes and transfers are undertaken, the per capita burden of future agents necessary to restore fiscal sustainability will almost double during the next 15 years. Table 6: Growth-Adjusted Generational Accounts of Future Generations in Different Years (thousand CZK) 2004 2009 2014 2019 GA future 1782 2265 2845 3531 base year=100 100 127 160 198 The timing of fiscal reform is therefore a very important factor from the intergenerational point of view, since the population is getting smaller and older. In other words, the number of people really facing the burden accumulated by previous generations is decreasing. This implies that the government should not hesitate too long with revising the current system if it wishes to sustain fiscal policy without dramatic changes in taxes and transfers of future generations. The costs of delayed action seem to be considerable. 40 As well as in most of the presented results g=2% and r=5%. 41 The results are calculated by applying the residual approach. For details see section 4. Generational Accounts in the Czech Republic 21 7. Conclusions We have presented the first set of generational accounts for the Czech Republic. By contrast with traditional indicators such as the budget deficit and public debt, generational accounts are forward looking and provide us with information about potential intergenerational redistribution and the sustainability of public finances. The generational accounting approach captures sustainability from both the aggregated macroeconomic and representative agent's point of view. We show that the present fiscal policy is not sustainable, owing to the unequal treatment of current and future representative agents. According to our analysis a representative living agent born in 2004 obtains more benefits than he/she pays in taxes over the rest of his/her life. By contrast, a representative agent not yet born will face the opposite situation. Moreover, the total amount of government liabilities resulting from the current fiscal policy pursued to 2150 reaches about 300% of GDP in 2004. Thus, taking into account future demographic development and a strict indexation rule, fiscal policy appears to be unsustainable. Finally, according to our results, the costs of postponed modification of taxes and benefits seem to be considerable, because of the worsening demographic factors. References AUERBACH A. J., GOKHALE J., AND KOTLIKOFF L. J. (1994): "Generational Accounting: A Meaningful Way to Evaluate Fiscal Policy". Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 8, Pages 73­94. AUERBACH A. J., KOTLIKOFF L. J., AND LEIBFRITZ W. (1998): "Generational Accounting Around the World". IMES, Discussion paper No. 98-E-2. AUERBACH A. J. AND CHANG Y. J. (2003): "Generational Accounting in Korea". NBER WP 9983. BANCA D'ITALIA (2000): Public Finance Workshop on Fiscal Sustainability. BEZDEK V., DYBCZAK K., AND KREJDL A. (2003): "Czech Fiscal Policy: Introductory Analysis". CNB WP, No. 7. BONIN H. (1997): Generational Accounting, Theory and Application, Springer, ISBN 3540422668. BONIN H. AND PATXOT C. (2004): "Generational Accounting as a Tool to Assess Fiscal Sustainability: An Overview of the Methodology". IZA DP No. 990, January. BURCIN B. AND KUČERA T. (2004): "Projekce vývoje obyvatelstva České republiky na období 2066-2150", Praha. CARDARELLI R., SEFTON J., AND KOTLIKOFF L. J. (1999): "Generational Accounting in the UK". NIESR DP 147. CBO (1995): Who Pays and When? An Assessment of Generational Accounts, CBO Study. FERNÁNDEZ-ANSOLA J., GANELLI G., TAMIRISA N., AND TULADHAR A. (2005): Czech Republic Selected Issues, IMF, July. 22 Kamil Dybczak EUROPEAN COMMISSION (2000): Generational Accounting in Europe. GÁL R.I., SIMONOVITS A., SZABÓ M., AND TARCALI G. (2000): Generational Accounts in Hungary, mimeo. GOKHALE J., PAGE B., AND STURROCK J. R. (1997): Generational Accounts for the United States, Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Vol. 33, No. 4. KOTLIKOFF L. J. (2001): "Generational Policy". NBER WP 8163. KOTLIKOFF L. J. AND LIEBFRITZ W. (1998): "An International Comparison of Generational Accounts". NBER WP6447. LAU M. I. (2000): "Generational Accounting and Individual Discount Rates". CEBR WP 7. LEVY J. AND DORÉ O. (1998): "Generational Accounting for France". IMF WP 98/14. RAFFELHÜSCHEN B. (1999): "Generational Accounting in Europe". Directorate-General for Economic and Financial Affairs, Study N6. RELE TER H. (1997): "Generational Accounts for the Dutch Public Sector". CPB, Research memorandum No. 135. Generational Accounts in the Czech Republic 23 Appendix I General Government Operations, 2004 (GFS 1986 Methodology) (billions of CZK) TAX REVENUE 963 General Public Services 78 Income Profits & Capital Gains Tax 253 Defense 51 Individual 133 Public Order & Safety 39 Corporate 120 Education 116 Social Security Contributions 388 Health 175 Taxes on Property 15 Social Security & Welfare 356 Domestic Taxes On Goods & Services 302 old age pension 231 General Sales, Turnover & Value-Added Taxes 182 sick benefits 25 Excises 96 social security benefits 33 Taxes on Special Services 1 other benefits 43 Taxes on Use of Goods & Services 16 passive employment policy 7 Other Taxes on Goods & Services 7 welfare 15 Taxes on International Trade & Transactions 4 Other 10 Import Duties 4 Housing & Community Amenities 84 Other Taxes 0 Recreation, Cultural & Religious Affairs & Services 30 NONTAX REVENUE 62 Fuel and Energy 3 Entrepreneurial & Property Income 27 Agriculture, Forestry, Fishing and Hunting 29 Administrative Fees & Charges, Nonind.and Incidental Sales 24 Mining & Mineral Resources, Manufacturing & Construction 3 Fines & Forfeits 4 Transportation & Communication 116 Other Nontax Revenue 7 Other Economic Affairs & Services 36 CAPITAL REVENUE 12 Other Expenditures 45 GRANTS 25 TOTAL REVENUE 1 062 TOTAL EXPENDITURE 1 160 DEFICIT -98 DEBT 659 Age Specific Revenue 998 Age Specific Expenditure 1 010 Income Profits & Capital Gains Tax 253 General Public Services 78 Social Security Contributions 388 Defense 51 Taxes on Property 15 Public Order & Safety 39 Domestic Taxes On Goods & Services 302 Education 116 Taxes on International Trade & Transactions 4 Health 175 Other Taxes 0 Social Security & Welfare 356 Administrative Fees & Charges 24 Housing & Community Amenities 84 Fines & Forfeits 4 Recreation, Cultural & Religious Affairs & Services 30 Other Nontax Revenue 7 Other Economic Affairs & Services 36 Other Expenditures 45 Non-age specific revenue 64 Non-age specific expenditure 150 Entrepreneurial & Property Income 27 Fuel and Energy 3 Capital Revenue 12 Agriculture, Forestry, Fishing and Hunting 29 Grants 25 Mining & Mineral Resources, Manufacturing & Cons 3 0 0 Transportation & Communication 116 TOTAL REVENUE 1 062 TOTAL EXPENDITURE 1 160 24 Kamil Dybczak Appendix II Age-Specific Taxes and Transfers (thousand CZK) The major part of the age-specific profiles of a representative male and female were calculated using the Household Budget Survey 2002 provided by the Czech Statistical Office. Data concerning all forms of pension benefits comes from the Czech Social Security Administration database. Data reflecting Education Expenditures was provided by the Ministry of Education, Youth and Sports. Finally, the General Health Insurance Company provided the health care data. The presented age-specific taxes and transfers give us an idea of people's behaviour during their lifecycle. Moreover, we can infer from their level and shape how people contribute to the public budget or benefit from public transfers depending on their age. For example, the amount of direct taxes (Personal Income Tax and Social Security Contributions) depends on an individual's wage rate and employment. First, in the neoclassical framework, the real wage rate is a function of labour productivity. Many factors can influence the productivity of labour, but we assume it depends mainly on the stock of human capital accumulated by an employee, i.e. experience accumulated over time. Generally, young people increase the stock of their human capital more easily than older people. Moreover, the stock of capital depreciates over time, and if no new experience is added the capital stock decreases. This implies that an employee becomes less productive and his/her real wage rate potentially falls. Usually, older people are not capable of adjusting to new conditions and their stock of human capital just decreases due to depreciation. In other words, the real wage rate seems to depend on the age of the employee, i.e. it increases with age for the young and decreases for the old. Second, people start working after finishing at least the statutory level of education. Usually, they stop working after reaching retirement age. Thus, when applying the provided arguments the shape of the age-specific profiles of direct taxes can be explained. It follows that the amount of personal income tax and social security contributions paid by an individual depends on his/her age. The shape of the age-specific profiles of indirect taxes can be explained as follows. The consumption of a representative agent develops according to his/her needs and the level of his/her income. As a result, the amount of indirect taxes (VAT and Excises) is either low or zero for children. Then, as income increases, the amount of goods consumed increases, as does the amount of indirect taxes. Finally, as an agent retires, he/she starts consuming accumulated savings and lowers consumption. The government redistributes income among individuals using public expenditures and transfers. In many cases public expenditures and transfers depend on the size and age structure of the population. It follows that age-specific profiles of different public expenditure items can be constructed as well. For example, the government provides retired people with old-age pensions. If an individual does not reach a certain age, he/she cannot consume these pensions. By contrast, the government finances a substantial part of education expenditures, but after reaching a specific age, an individual has to finance education by himself. Next, government health expenditures are affected by the sickness rate of different age groups. Usually, the government pays more for children and old people, since their sickness rate is higher than that of people of productive age. Generational Accounts in the Czech Republic 25 VAT 0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100 1 8 15 22 29 36 43 50 57 64 71 78 85 92 99 1000CZKperperson Male Female EXCISES 0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100 1 8 15 22 29 36 43 50 57 64 71 78 85 92 99 1000CZKperperson Male Female PERSONAL INCOME TAX 0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100 1 8 15 22 29 36 43 50 57 64 71 78 85 92 99 1000CZKperperson Male Female 26 Kamil Dybczak SOCIAL SECURITY CONTRIBUTIONS 0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100 1 8 15 22 29 36 43 50 57 64 71 78 85 92 99 1000CZKperperson Male Female INHERITANCE TAX 0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100 1 8 15 22 29 36 43 50 57 64 71 78 85 92 99 1000CZKperperson Male Female CORPORATE INCOME TAX 0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100 1 8 15 22 29 36 43 50 57 64 71 78 85 92 99 1000CZKperperson Male Female Generational Accounts in the Czech Republic 27 OTHER AGE-SPECIFIC REVENUES 0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100 1 8 15 22 29 36 43 50 57 64 71 78 85 92 99 1000CZKperperson Male Female OLD-AGE PENSION -100 -90 -80 -70 -60 -50 -40 -30 -20 -10 0 1 8 15 22 29 36 43 50 57 64 71 78 85 92 99 1000CZKperperson Male Female DISABILITY PENSION -100 -90 -80 -70 -60 -50 -40 -30 -20 -10 0 1 7 13 19 25 31 37 43 49 55 61 67 73 79 85 91 97 1000CZKperperson Male Female 28 Kamil Dybczak UNEMPLOYMENT BENEFITS -100 -90 -80 -70 -60 -50 -40 -30 -20 -10 0 1 7 13 19 25 31 37 43 49 55 61 67 73 79 85 91 97 1000CZKperperson Male Female OTHER SOCIAL BENEFITS -100 -90 -80 -70 -60 -50 -40 -30 -20 -10 0 1 8 15 22 29 36 43 50 57 64 71 78 85 92 99 1000CZKperperson Male Female SICK BENEFITS -100 -90 -80 -70 -60 -50 -40 -30 -20 -10 0 1 8 15 22 29 36 43 50 57 64 71 78 85 92 99 1000CZKperperson Male Female Generational Accounts in the Czech Republic 29 EDUCATION EXPENDITURES -100 -90 -80 -70 -60 -50 -40 -30 -20 -10 0 1 8 15 22 29 36 43 50 57 64 71 78 85 92 99 1000CZKperperson Male Female HEALTH EXPENDITURES -100 -90 -80 -70 -60 -50 -40 -30 -20 -10 0 1 8 15 22 29 36 43 50 57 64 71 78 85 92 99 1000CZKperperson Male Female OTHER EXPENDITURES -120 -110 -100 -90 -80 -70 -60 -50 -40 -30 -20 -10 0 1 8 15 22 29 36 43 50 57 64 71 78 85 92 99 1000CZKperperson Male Female CNB WORKING PAPER SERIES 2/2006 Kamil Dybczak: Generational accounts in the Czech Republic 1/2006 Ian Babetskii: Aggregate wage flexibility in selected new EU member states 14/2005 Stephen G. Cecchetti: The brave new world of central banking: The policy challenges posed by asset price booms and busts 13/2005 Robert F. Engle: Jose Gonzalo Rangel The spline GARCH model for unconditional volatility and its global macroeconomic causes 12/2005 Jaromír Beneš: Tibor Hlédik Michael Kumhof David Vávra An economy in transition and DSGE: What the Czech national bank's new projection model needs 11/2005 Marek Hlaváček: Michael Koňák Josef Čada The application of structured feedforward neural networks to the modelling of daily series of currency in circulation 10/2005 Ondřej Kameník: Solving SDGE models: A new algorithm for the sylvester equation 9/2005 Roman Šustek: Plant-level nonconvexities and the monetary transmission mechanism 8/2005 Roman Horváth: Exchange rate variability, pressures and optimum currency area criteria: Implications for the central and eastern european countries 7/2005 Balázs Égert: Luboš Komárek Foreign exchange interventions and interest rate policy in the Czech Republic: Hand in glove? 6/2005 Anca Podpiera: Jiří Podpiera Deteriorating cost efficiency in commercial banks signals an increasing risk of failure 5/2005 Luboš Komárek: Martin Melecký The behavioural equilibrium exchange rate of the Czech koruna 4/2005 Kateřina Arnoštová: Jaromír Hurník The monetary transmission mechanism in the Czech Republic (evidence from VAR analysis) 3/2005 Vladimír Benáček: Jiří Podpiera Ladislav Prokop Determining factors of Czech foreign trade: A cross-section time series perspective 2/2005 Kamil Galuščák: Daniel Münich Structural and cyclical unemployment: What can we derive from the matching function? 1/2005 Ivan Babouček: Martin Jančar Effects of macroeconomic shocks to the quality of the aggregate loan portfolio 10/2004 Aleš Bulíř: Kateřina Šmídková Exchange rates in the new EU accession countries: What have we learned from the forerunners 9/2004 Martin Cincibuch: Jiří Podpiera Beyond Balassa-Samuelson: Real appreciation in tradables in transition countries 8/2004 Jaromír Beneš: David Vávra Eigenvalue decomposition of time series with application to the Czech business cycle 7/2004 Vladislav Flek, ed.: Anatomy of the Czech labour market: From over-employment to under-employment in ten years? 6/2004 Narcisa Kadlčáková: Joerg Keplinger Credit risk and bank lending in the Czech Republic 5/2004 Petr Král: Identification and measurement of relationships concerning inflow of FDI: The case of the Czech Republic 4/2004 Jiří Podpiera: Consumers, consumer prices and the Czech business cycle identification 3/2004 Anca Pruteanu: The role of banks in the Czech monetary policy transmission mechanism 2/2004 Ian Babetskii: EU enlargement and endogeneity of some OCA criteria: Evidence from the CEECs 1/2004 Alexis Derviz: Jiří Podpiera Predicting bank CAMELS and S&P ratings: The case of the Czech Republic 12/2003 Tibor Hlédik: Modelling the second-round effects of supply-side shocks on inflation 11/2003 Luboš Komárek: Zdeněk Čech Roman Horváth ERM II membership ­ the view of the accession countries 10/2003 Luboš Komárek: Zdeněk Čech Roman Horváth Optimum currency area indices ­ how close is the Czech Republic to the eurozone? 9/2003 Alexis Derviz: Narcisa Kadlčáková Lucie Kobzová Credit risk, systemic uncertainties and economic capital requirements for an artificial bank loan portfolio 8/2003 Tomáš Holub: Martin Čihák Price convergence: What can the Balassa­Samuelson model tell us? 7/2003 Vladimír Bezděk: Kamil Dybczak Aleš Krejdl Czech fiscal policy: Introductory analysis 6/2003 Alexis Derviz: FOREX microstructure, invisible price determinants, and the central bank's understanding of exchange rate formation 5/2003 Aleš Bulíř: Some exchange rates are more stable than others: Short-run evidence from transition countries 4/2003 Alexis Derviz: Components of the Czech koruna risk premium in a multiple- dealer FX market 3/2003 Vladimír Benáček: Ladislav Prokop Jan Á. Víšek Determining factors of the Czech foreign trade balance: Structural Issues in Trade Creation 2/2003 Martin Čihák: Tomáš Holub Price convergence to the EU: What do the 1999 ICP data tell us? 1/2003 Kamil Galuščák: Daniel Münich Microfoundations of the wage inflation in the Czech Republic 4/2002 Vladislav Flek: Lenka Marková Jiří Podpiera Sectoral productivity and real exchange rate appreciation: Much ado about nothing? 3/2002 Kateřina Šmídková: Ray Barrell Dawn Holland Estimates of fundamental real exchange rates for the five EU pre-accession countries 2/2002 Martin Hlušek: Estimating market probabilities of future interest rate changes 1/2002 Viktor Kotlán: Monetary policy and the term spread in a macro model of a small open economy CNB RESEARCH AND POLICY NOTES 5/2005 Jan Stráský: Optimal forward-looking policy rules in the quarterly projection model of the Czech National Bank 4/2005 Vít Bárta: Fulfilment of the Maastricht inflation criterion by the Czech Republic: Potential costs and policy options 3/2005 Helena Sůvová: Eva Kozelková David Zeman Jaroslava Bauerová Eligibility of external credit assessment institutions 2/2005 Martin Čihák: Jaroslav Heřmánek Stress testing the Czech banking system: Where are we? Where are we going? 1/2005 David Navrátil: Viktor Kotlán The CNB's policy decisions ­ Are they priced in by the markets? 4/2004 Aleš Bulíř: External and fiscal sustainability of the Czech economy: A quick look through the IMF's night-vision goggles 3/2004 Martin Čihák: Designing stress tests for the Czech banking system 2/2004 Martin Čihák: Stress testing: A review of key concepts 1/2004 Tomáš Holub: Foreign exchange interventions under inflation targeting: The Czech experience 2/2003 Kateřina Šmídková: Targeting inflation under uncertainty: Policy makers' perspective 1/2003 Michal Skořepa: Viktor Kotlán Inflation targeting: To forecast or to simulate? CNB ECONOMIC RESEARCH BULLETIN November 2005 Financial stability May 2005 Potential output October 2004 Fiscal issues May 2004 Inflation targeting December 2003 Equilibrium exchange rate Czech National Bank Economic Research Department Na Příkopě 28, 115 03 Praha 1 Czech Republic phone: +420 2 244 12 321 fax: +420 2 244 14 278 http://www.cnb.cz e-mail: research@cnb.cz