6. DUCHODOVÁ POLITIKA Obsah 6.1. Bismarck a Beveridge 6.2. Rovnice 6.3. Case study: Německo 6.1. Bismarck a Beveridge On 20 March 1884, Otto von Bismarck declared: [...] the actual complaint of the worker is the insecurity of his existence; he is unsure if he will always have work, he is unsure if he will always be healthy and he can predict that he will reach old age and be unable to work. If he falls into poverty, and be that only through prolonged illness, he will find himself totally helpless being on his own, and society currently does not accept any responsibility towards him beyond the usual provisions for the poor, even if he has been working all the time ever so diligently and faithfully. The ordinary provisions for the poor, however, leave a lot to be desired [...] Health Insurance Bill of 1883 Accident Insurance Bill of 1884 Old Age and Disability Insurance Bill of 1889 Bismarckovské důchodové systémy Ø Penze jsou zamýšleny jako náhrada pracovních výdělků ve stáří Ø Proto zde existuje silná vazba mezi individuálně odvedenými příspěvky z mezd a individuálními penzemi Ø Nároky akumulovány pomocí záznamů odpracovaných let a výdělků – bodový systém (Německo, Francie) nebo pomocí NDC – příspěvky jsou virtuálně úročeny (Švédsko, Itálie) Ø Výrazné odchylky od mezigenerační rovnosti → dřívější a málo početné generace získávají vyšší výnos Ø V některých zemích (Itálie, Francie) odlišný režim (dřívější odchod, vyšší penze) pro některé zaměstnanecké skupiny (státní zaměstnanci, horníci, železničáři) Ø Nízký podíl soukromých penzijních výdajů – crowding out efekt? Beveridgovské důchodové systémy Ø Nízká vazba mezi individuálními příspěvky do systému a individuálními penzemi Ø Skladba penzí: - základní (Nizozemí, Nový Zéland) - vícepilířové (Kanada, Irsko, Japonsko, Švýcarsko, V. Británie) - unifikované, nelineární (USA) Ø Silné přerozdělování v rámci jedné generace Shrnutí: Bismarck x Beveridge Mezigenerační (ne)rovnost The internal rate of return is then computed as that rate of return at which the present value of the (negative) stream of contributions paid is equal to the present value of the (positive) stream of pension benefits. Veřejné a soukromé penzijní výdaje Geografická klasifikace PS 1) Skandinávské (DK, FIN, NOR, SWE) 2) Kontinentální (AT, BE, FRA, GER) 3) Jižní (ITA, GRE, SPA, PT) 4) Anglo-Sax (AUS, CAN, IRL, NZ, UK, USA) 5) Ostatní (JAP, LUX, NED, SWITZ) 6) Vychodoevrospké (CZ, SK, PL, HU) 6.2. Rovnice Účetní rovnováha PAYG důchodového systému PŘÍJMY = VÝDAJE t ● Nw ● w = Nb ● B t = daňová sazba placená zaměstnavatelem i zaměstnancem (payroll tax rate paid by employers and employees) Nw = počet pojištěných osob (přispěvovatelů) v daném roce ( number of covered workers employed in a year) w = průměrná mzda pojištěnce během roku (average wages of covered workers during the year) Nb =počet důchodců pobírajících dávky (number of retirees receiving benefits) B = průměrný důchod (average benefits paid to retirees) t = (Nb/Nw) ● (B/w) Demografický vývoj Demografie (OADR) a důchodci/zaměstnaní (Nb/Nw) Důchodci/Zaměstnaní (N[b]/N[w]) Tabulka: Nb; Nw v populaci starší 15 let (%). Rok 2005 OADR a N[b]/N[w] Rok 2005. OADR x Nb/Nw Rok 2006 Důchodový věk a míry zaměstnanosti Zaměstnaní (Nw)/ Důchodci (Nb) Náhradový poměr (B/W) Demografie (OADR), trh práce (SR=Nw/Nb) a náhradový poměr (B/W) Efektivní daňová sazba (t) Efektivní daňová sazba (t) t (%) = Nb/Nw ● B/w PE (%) – pensions as percentage of GDP; wgs (%) = PE/t OADR x PE (2006) PE…podíl penzí na HDP (%) Nb/Nw x B/W Rezervy systému (1) Rezervy systému (2) Demografie a hospodářská politika Spolehlivé prognózy…? 6.3. Case study: Německý důchodový systém Zdroj: Borsch-Supan, A. – Wilke, Ch. (2004): THE GERMAN PUBLIC PENSION SYSTÉM: HOW IT WAS, HOW IT WILL BE. NBER Working paper 10525 The German Public Pension System (1) „The German pension system was the first formal pension system in the world, designed by Bismarck almost 120 years ago. It has been very successful in providing a high and reliable level of retirement income in the past at reasonable contribution rates, and it became a model for many social security systems around the world. It has survived two major wars, the Great Depression, and more recently, unification. It has been praised as one of the causes for social and political stability in Germany. Times have changed, however, and these days, this system is under severe pressure from population aging and adverse incentive effects. This paper addresses how this prototypical system emerged and where it will go.“ The German Public Pension System (2) „As opposed to other countries such as the United Kingdom and the Netherlands, which originally adopted a Beveridgian social security system that provided only a base pension, public pensions in Germany were from the start designed to extend the standard of living that was achieved during work life also to the time after retirement. Thus, public pensions are roughly proportional to labor income averaged over the entire life course and feature only few redistributive properties. The German pension system is therefore called „retirement insurance“ rather than „social security“ as in the United States, and workers used to understand their contributions as „insurance premia“ rather than „taxes“. The insurance character is strengthened by institutional separation: the German retirement insurance system is not part of the government budget but a separate entity. This entity is subsidized by the federal government. Rationale for this subsidy – about 30 percent of expenditures – are so-called “noninsurance benefits” such as benefits paid to German immigrants after opening the iron curtain Any surplus, however, remains in the system. It is not transferable into a “unified budget” such as in the United States.“ The German Public Pension System (3) The German retirement insurance started as a fully funded system with a mandatory retirement age of 70 years when male life expectancy at birth was less than 45 years. Today, life expectancy for men is more than 75 years but average retirement age is less than 60 and even lower in East Germany. The system converted to a de facto pay-as-you-go system when most funds were invested in government bonds between the two world wars. After a long and arduous debate, the German Bundestag decided in 1957 to convert the system gradually to a pay-as-you-go scheme. The remainder of the capital stock was spent about 10 years later. Since then, the German system is purely pay-as-you-go with a very small reserve fund lasting less than 14 days of expenditures in Spring 2004. The German Public Pension System (4) A second historical reform took place in 1972. It made the German pension system one of the most generous of the world. The retirement behavior visible in current data is mainly influenced by the reform. The 1972 system is generous in two respects. First, the system has a high replacement rate, generating net retirement incomes that are currently about 70 percent of pre-retirement net earnings for a worker with a 45-year earnings history and average lifetime earnings. This is substantially higher than, e.g., the corresponding U.S. net replacement rate of about 53 percent. The high initial level of public pensions was exacerbated by indexation to gross wages. Second, the 1972 reform abolished the mandatory retirement age of 65 years for those with a long service life5 in favor of a flexible choice during a “window of retirement” between age 63 and 65, with no actuarial adjustments. Adding to these very generous early retirement provisions were easy ways to claim disability benefits and low mandatory retirement ages for women and unemployed, further increasing the number of beneficiaries and extending the “window of retirement” between 60 and 65. The German Public Pension System (5) The German Public Pension System (6) The German Public Pension System (7) The German Public Pension System (8)