microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. microtitle.jpg microedition.jpg varianname.jpg 20 Cost Minimization microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Cost Minimization uA firm is a cost-minimizer if it produces any given output level y ³ 0 at smallest possible total cost. uc(y) denotes the firm’s smallest possible total cost for producing y units of output. uc(y) is the firm’s total cost function. microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Cost Minimization uWhen the firm faces given input prices w = (w1,w2,…,wn) the total cost function will be written as c(w1,…,wn,y). microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› The Cost-Minimization Problem uConsider a firm using two inputs to make one output. uThe production function is y = f(x1,x2). uTake the output level y ³ 0 as given. uGiven the input prices w1 and w2, the cost of an input bundle (x1,x2) is w1x1 + w2x2. microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› The Cost-Minimization Problem uFor given w1, w2 and y, the firm’s cost-minimization problem is to solve subject to microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› The Cost-Minimization Problem uThe levels x1*(w1,w2,y) and x1*(w1,w2,y) in the least-costly input bundle are the firm’s conditional demands for inputs 1 and 2. uThe (smallest possible) total cost for producing y output units is therefore microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Conditional Input Demands uGiven w1, w2 and y, how is the least costly input bundle located? uAnd how is the total cost function computed? microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Iso-cost Lines uA curve that contains all of the input bundles that cost the same amount is an iso-cost curve. uE.g., given w1 and w2, the $100 iso-cost line has the equation microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Iso-cost Lines uGenerally, given w1 and w2, the equation of the $c iso-cost line is i.e. uSlope is - w1/w2. microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Iso-cost Lines c’ º w1x1+w2x2 c” º w1x1+w2x2 c’ < c” x1 x2 microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Iso-cost Lines c’ º w1x1+w2x2 c” º w1x1+w2x2 c’ < c” x1 x2 Slopes = -w1/w2. microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› The y’-Output Unit Isoquant x1 x2 All input bundles yielding y’ units of output. Which is the cheapest? f(x1,x2) º y’ microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› The Cost-Minimization Problem x1 x2 All input bundles yielding y’ units of output. Which is the cheapest? f(x1,x2) º y’ microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› The Cost-Minimization Problem x1 x2 All input bundles yielding y’ units of output. Which is the cheapest? f(x1,x2) º y’ microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› The Cost-Minimization Problem x1 x2 All input bundles yielding y’ units of output. Which is the cheapest? f(x1,x2) º y’ microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› The Cost-Minimization Problem x1 x2 All input bundles yielding y’ units of output. Which is the cheapest? f(x1,x2) º y’ x1* x2* microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› The Cost-Minimization Problem x1 x2 f(x1,x2) º y’ x1* x2* At an interior cost-min input bundle: (a) microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› The Cost-Minimization Problem x1 x2 f(x1,x2) º y’ x1* x2* At an interior cost-min input bundle: (a) and (b) slope of isocost = slope of isoquant microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› The Cost-Minimization Problem x1 x2 f(x1,x2) º y’ x1* x2* At an interior cost-min input bundle: (a) and (b) slope of isocost = slope of isoquant; i.e. microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› A Cobb-Douglas Example of Cost Minimization uA firm’s Cobb-Douglas production function is uInput prices are w1 and w2. uWhat are the firm’s conditional input demand functions? microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› A Cobb-Douglas Example of Cost Minimization At the input bundle (x1*,x2*) which minimizes the cost of producing y output units: (a) (b) and microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› A Cobb-Douglas Example of Cost Minimization (a) (b) microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› A Cobb-Douglas Example of Cost Minimization (a) (b) From (b), microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› A Cobb-Douglas Example of Cost Minimization (a) (b) From (b), Now substitute into (a) to get microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› A Cobb-Douglas Example of Cost Minimization (a) (b) From (b), Now substitute into (a) to get microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› A Cobb-Douglas Example of Cost Minimization (a) (b) From (b), Now substitute into (a) to get So is the firm’s conditional demand for input 1. microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› A Cobb-Douglas Example of Cost Minimization is the firm’s conditional demand for input 2. Since and microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› A Cobb-Douglas Example of Cost Minimization So the cheapest input bundle yielding y output units is microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› 20-29.png Fixed w1 and w2. Conditional Input Demand Curves microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Fixed w1 and w2. Conditional Input Demand Curves 20-29.png microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Fixed w1 and w2. Conditional Input Demand Curves 20-29.png microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Fixed w1 and w2. Conditional Input Demand Curves 20-29.png microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Fixed w1 and w2. Conditional Input Demand Curves output expansion path 20-29.png microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Fixed w1 and w2. Conditional Input Demand Curves output expansion path Cond. demand for input 2 Cond. demand for input 1 20-29.png microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› A Cobb-Douglas Example of Cost Minimization For the production function the cheapest input bundle yielding y output units is microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› A Cobb-Douglas Example of Cost Minimization So the firm’s total cost function is microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› A Cobb-Douglas Example of Cost Minimization So the firm’s total cost function is microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› A Cobb-Douglas Example of Cost Minimization So the firm’s total cost function is microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› A Cobb-Douglas Example of Cost Minimization So the firm’s total cost function is microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› A Perfect Complements Example of Cost Minimization uThe firm’s production function is uInput prices w1 and w2 are given. uWhat are the firm’s conditional demands for inputs 1 and 2? uWhat is the firm’s total cost function? microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› A Perfect Complements Example of Cost Minimization x1 x2 min{4x1,x2} º y’ 4x1 = x2 microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› A Perfect Complements Example of Cost Minimization x1 x2 4x1 = x2 min{4x1,x2} º y’ microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› A Perfect Complements Example of Cost Minimization x1 x2 4x1 = x2 min{4x1,x2} º y’ Where is the least costly input bundle yielding y’ output units? microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› A Perfect Complements Example of Cost Minimization x1 x2 x1* = y/4 x2* = y 4x1 = x2 min{4x1,x2} º y’ Where is the least costly input bundle yielding y’ output units? microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› A Perfect Complements Example of Cost Minimization The firm’s production function is and the conditional input demands are and microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› A Perfect Complements Example of Cost Minimization The firm’s production function is and the conditional input demands are and So the firm’s total cost function is microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› A Perfect Complements Example of Cost Minimization The firm’s production function is and the conditional input demands are and So the firm’s total cost function is microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Average Total Production Costs uFor positive output levels y, a firm’s average total cost of producing y units is microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Returns-to-Scale and Av. Total Costs uThe returns-to-scale properties of a firm’s technology determine how average production costs change with output level. uOur firm is presently producing y’ output units. uHow does the firm’s average production cost change if it instead produces 2y’ units of output? microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Constant Returns-to-Scale and Average Total Costs uIf a firm’s technology exhibits constant returns-to-scale then doubling its output level from y’ to 2y’ requires doubling all input levels. microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Constant Returns-to-Scale and Average Total Costs uIf a firm’s technology exhibits constant returns-to-scale then doubling its output level from y’ to 2y’ requires doubling all input levels. uTotal production cost doubles. microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Constant Returns-to-Scale and Average Total Costs uIf a firm’s technology exhibits constant returns-to-scale then doubling its output level from y’ to 2y’ requires doubling all input levels. uTotal production cost doubles. uAverage production cost does not change. microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Decreasing Returns-to-Scale and Average Total Costs uIf a firm’s technology exhibits decreasing returns-to-scale then doubling its output level from y’ to 2y’ requires more than doubling all input levels. microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Decreasing Returns-to-Scale and Average Total Costs uIf a firm’s technology exhibits decreasing returns-to-scale then doubling its output level from y’ to 2y’ requires more than doubling all input levels. uTotal production cost more than doubles. microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Decreasing Returns-to-Scale and Average Total Costs uIf a firm’s technology exhibits decreasing returns-to-scale then doubling its output level from y’ to 2y’ requires more than doubling all input levels. uTotal production cost more than doubles. uAverage production cost increases. microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Increasing Returns-to-Scale and Average Total Costs uIf a firm’s technology exhibits increasing returns-to-scale then doubling its output level from y’ to 2y’ requires less than doubling all input levels. microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Increasing Returns-to-Scale and Average Total Costs uIf a firm’s technology exhibits increasing returns-to-scale then doubling its output level from y’ to 2y’ requires less than doubling all input levels. uTotal production cost less than doubles. microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Increasing Returns-to-Scale and Average Total Costs uIf a firm’s technology exhibits increasing returns-to-scale then doubling its output level from y’ to 2y’ requires less than doubling all input levels. uTotal production cost less than doubles. uAverage production cost decreases. microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Returns-to-Scale and Av. Total Costs y $/output unit constant r.t.s. decreasing r.t.s. increasing r.t.s. AC(y) microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Returns-to-Scale and Total Costs uWhat does this imply for the shapes of total cost functions? microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Returns-to-Scale and Total Costs y $ y’ 2y’ c(y’) c(2y’) Slope = c(2y’)/2y’ = AC(2y’). Slope = c(y’)/y’ = AC(y’). Av. cost increases with y if the firm’s technology exhibits decreasing r.t.s. microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Returns-to-Scale and Total Costs y $ c(y) y’ 2y’ c(y’) c(2y’) Slope = c(2y’)/2y’ = AC(2y’). Slope = c(y’)/y’ = AC(y’). Av. cost increases with y if the firm’s technology exhibits decreasing r.t.s. microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Returns-to-Scale and Total Costs y $ y’ 2y’ c(y’) c(2y’) Slope = c(2y’)/2y’ = AC(2y’). Slope = c(y’)/y’ = AC(y’). Av. cost decreases with y if the firm’s technology exhibits increasing r.t.s. microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Returns-to-Scale and Total Costs y $ c(y) y’ 2y’ c(y’) c(2y’) Slope = c(2y’)/2y’ = AC(2y’). Slope = c(y’)/y’ = AC(y’). Av. cost decreases with y if the firm’s technology exhibits increasing r.t.s. microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Returns-to-Scale and Total Costs y $ c(y) y’ 2y’ c(y’) c(2y’) =2c(y’) Slope = c(2y’)/2y’ = 2c(y’)/2y’ = c(y’)/y’ so AC(y’) = AC(2y’). Av. cost is constant when the firm’s technology exhibits constant r.t.s. microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Short-Run & Long-Run Total Costs uIn the long-run a firm can vary all of its input levels. uConsider a firm that cannot change its input 2 level from x2’ units. uHow does the short-run total cost of producing y output units compare to the long-run total cost of producing y units of output? microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Short-Run & Long-Run Total Costs uThe long-run cost-minimization problem is uThe short-run cost-minimization problem is subject to subject to microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Short-Run & Long-Run Total Costs uThe short-run cost-min. problem is the long-run problem subject to the extra constraint that x2 = x2’. uIf the long-run choice for x2 was x2’ then the extra constraint x2 = x2’ is not really a constraint at all and so the long-run and short-run total costs of producing y output units are the same. microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Short-Run & Long-Run Total Costs uThe short-run cost-min. problem is therefore the long-run problem subject to the extra constraint that x2 = x2”. uBut, if the long-run choice for x2 ¹ x2” then the extra constraint x2 = x2” prevents the firm in this short-run from achieving its long-run production cost, causing the short-run total cost to exceed the long-run total cost of producing y output units. microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Short-Run & Long-Run Total Costs x1 x2 Consider three output levels. microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Short-Run & Long-Run Total Costs x1 x2 In the long-run when the firm is free to choose both x1 and x2, the least-costly input bundles are ... microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Short-Run & Long-Run Total Costs x1 x2 Long-run output expansion path microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Short-Run & Long-Run Total Costs x1 x2 Long-run output expansion path Long-run costs are: microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Short-Run & Long-Run Total Costs uNow suppose the firm becomes subject to the short-run constraint that x2 = x2”. microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Short-Run & Long-Run Total Costs x1 x2 Short-run output expansion path Long-run costs are: microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Short-Run & Long-Run Total Costs x1 x2 Short-run output expansion path Long-run costs are: microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Short-Run & Long-Run Total Costs x1 x2 Short-run output expansion path Long-run costs are: Short-run costs are: microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Short-Run & Long-Run Total Costs x1 x2 Short-run output expansion path Long-run costs are: Short-run costs are: microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Short-Run & Long-Run Total Costs x1 x2 Short-run output expansion path Long-run costs are: Short-run costs are: microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Short-Run & Long-Run Total Costs Short-run costs are: x1 x2 Short-run output expansion path Long-run costs are: microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Short-Run & Long-Run Total Costs uShort-run total cost exceeds long-run total cost except for the output level where the short-run input level restriction is the long-run input level choice. uThis says that the long-run total cost curve always has one point in common with any particular short-run total cost curve. microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Short-Run & Long-Run Total Costs y $ c(y) cs(y) A short-run total cost curve always has one point in common with the long-run total cost curve, and is elsewhere higher than the long-run total cost curve.