eJOURNAL USA 9 Economists know the fatal flaw in our international monetary system — but they can’t agree on how to fix it. John B. Judis is a senior editor at the New Republic and a visiting fellow at the Carnegie Endowment for International Peace. T he past few months have been a crash course in the abstract and obscure instruments and arrangements that have derailed the world’s economy. From mortgage-backed securities to credit default swaps, the international monetary system is in big trouble. For decades, the United States has relied on a tortuous financial arrangement that knits together its economy with those of China and Japan. This informal system has allowed Asian countries to run huge export surpluses with the United States, while permitting the United States to run huge budget deficits without having to raise interest rates or taxes, and to run huge trade deficits without abruptly depreciating its currency. Quite a few bankers, international economists, and high officials such as U.S. Federal Reserve Chairman Ben Bernanke think this informal system contributed to today’s financial crisis. Worse, they fear that its breakdown could turn the looming downturn into something resembling the global depression of the 1930s. The original Bretton Woods system dates from a conference at a New Hampshire resort hotel in July 1944. Leading British and American economists blamed the Debt Man Walking John B. Judis In 1944, the United Nations Monetary and Financial Conference at Bretton Woods, New Hampshire, decided that the dollar would replace the British pound as the accepted global currency. ©APImages eJOURNAL USA 10 Great Depression and, to some extent, World War II on the breakup of the international monetary system in the early 1930s, and they were determined to create a more stable arrangement in which the dollar would replace the British pound as the accepted global currency. The dollar became the accepted medium of international exchange and a universal reserve currency. If countries accumulated more dollars than they could possibly use, they could always exchange them with the United States for gold. But with the United States consistently running a large trade surplus — meaning that countries always needed to have dollars on hand to buy American goods — there was initially little danger of a run on the U.S. gold depository. Bretton Woods began to totter during the Vietnam War, when the United States was sending billions of dollars abroad to finance the war and running a trade deficit, while deficit spending at home sparked inflation in an overheated economy. Countries began trying to swap overvalued dollars for deutschmarks, and France and Britain prepared to cash in their excess dollars at Fort Knox (the United States’ gold depository). In response, President Richard Nixon first closed the gold window and then demanded that Western Europe and Japan agree to new exchange rates whereby the dollar would be worth less gold, and the yen and the deutschmark would be worth more, relative to the dollar. That would make U.S. exports cheaper and Japanese and West German imports more expensive, easing the trade imbalance and stabilizing the dollar. By imposing a temporary tariff, Nixon succeeded in forcing these countries to revalue, but not in creating a new system of stable exchange rates. Instead, the values of the currencies began to fluctuate. And as inflation soared in the late 1970s, the system, which still relied on the dollar as the universal currency, seemed ready to explode into feuding currencies. BRETTON WOODS II That’s when a new monetary arrangement began to emerge. Economists often refer to it as “Bretton Woods II,” but it was not the result of a conference or concerted agreement among the world’s major economic powers. Instead, it evolved out of a set of individual decisions — first by the United States, Japan, and Saudi Arabia, and later by the United States and other Asian countries, notably China. Bretton Woods II took shape during President Ronald Reagan’s first term. To combat inflation, Paul Volcker, then the chairman of the Federal Reserve, jacked interest rates above 20 percent. That precipitated a steep recession — unemployment exceeded 10 percent in the fall of 1982 — and large budget deficits as government expenditures grew faster than tax revenues. The value of the dollar also rose as other countries took advantage of high U.S. interest rates. That jeopardized U.S. exports, and the U.S. trade deficit grew even larger as Americans began importing underpriced goods from abroad while foreigners shied away from newly expensive U.S. products. The Reagan administration faced a no-win situation: Try reducing the trade deficit by reducing the budget deficit, and you’d stifle growth; but try stimulating the economy by increasing the deficit, and you’d have to keep interest rates high in order to sell an adequate amount of Treasury debt, which would also stifle growth. At that point, Japan, along with Saudi Arabia and other OPEC (Organization of Petroleum Exporting Countries) nations, came to the rescue. At the end of World War II, Japan had adopted a strategy of economic growth that sacrificed domestic consumption in order to accumulate surpluses that it could invest in export industries — initially laborintensive industries such as textiles, but later capitalintensive industries such as automobiles and steel. This export-led approach was helped in the 1960s by an undervalued yen, but, after the collapse of Bretton Woods, Japan was threatened by a cheaper dollar. To keep exports high, Japan intentionally held down the yen’s value by carefully controlling the disposition of the dollars it reaped from its trade surplus with the United States. Instead of using these to purchase goods or to invest in the Japanese economy or to exchange for yen, it began to recycle them back to the United States by purchasing companies, real estate, and, above all, Treasury debt. That investment in Treasury bills, bonds, and notes — coupled with similar purchases by the Saudis and other oil producers, who needed to park their petrodollars somewhere — freed the United States from its economic quandary. With Japan’s purchases, the United States would not have to keep interest rates high in order to attract buyers to Treasury securities, and it wouldn’t have to raise taxes in order to reduce the deficit. As far as historians know, Japanese and American leaders never explicitly agreed that Tokyo would finance the U.S. deficit or that Washington would allow Japan to maintain an eJOURNAL USA 11 undervalued yen and a large trade surplus. But the informal bargain — described brilliantly in R. Taggart Murphy’s The Weight of the Yen — became the cornerstone of a new international economic arrangement. Over the last 20 years, the basic structure of Bretton Woods II has endured, but new players have entered the game. As Financial Times columnist Martin Wolf recounts in his book Fixing Global Finance, Asian countries, led by China, adopted a version of Japan’s strategy for export-led growth in the mid-1990s after the financial crises that wracked the continent. They maintained trade surpluses with the United States. And instead of exchanging their dollars for their own currencies or investing them internally, they, like the Japanese, recycled them into Treasury bills and other dollar-denominated assets. This kept the value of their currencies low in relation to the dollar and perpetuated the trade surplus by which they acquired the dollars in the first place. By June 2008, China held more than $500 billion in U.S. Treasury debt, second only to Japan. East Asia’s central banks had become the post-Bretton Woods equivalent of Fort Knox. UPSIDES AND DOWNSIDES Until recently, there have been clear upsides to this bargain for the United States: the avoidance of tax increases, growing wealth at the top of the income ladder, and preservation of the dollar as the international currency. Without Bretton Woods II, it is difficult to imagine the United States being able to wage wars in Iraq and Afghanistan while simultaneously cutting taxes. For their part, China and other Asian countries enjoyed almost a decade free of financial crises. And the world economy benefited from low transaction costs and relative price stability from having a single currency that countries could use to buy and sell goods. But there have been downsides to Bretton Woods II. A nation could conceivably blackmail the United States by threatening to cash in its dollars. Of course, if a nation such as China actually began to unload its dollars, it would jeopardize its own financial standing as much as it would jeopardize America’s. But economists Brad Setser and Nouriel Roubini argue that even the implicit threat of dumping dollars — or of ceasing to purchase them — could limit U.S. maneuverability abroad. “The ability to send a ‘sell’ order that roils markets may not give China a veto over U.S. foreign policy, but it surely does increase the cost of any U.S. policy that China opposes,” they write. In Japan, China, and other Asian countries, there has also been a downside to the grand bargain. The surplus dollars gained from trade with the United States have not been used to raise the standard of living, but rather have been squirreled away in Treasury securities. Writes Martin Wolf: “China has about 800 million poor people, yet the country now consumes less than half of GDP [gross domestic product] and exports capital to the rest of the world.” Of more immediate concern, Bretton Woods II contributed to the current financial crisis by facilitating the low interest rates that fueled the housing bubble. Here’s how it happened: In 2001, the United States suffered a mild recession largely as a result of overcapacity in the telecom and computer industries. The recession would have been much more severe, but, because foreigners were willing to buy Treasury debt, the Bush administration was able to cut taxes and increase spending even as the Federal Reserve lowered interest rates to 1 percent. The economy barely recovered over the next four years. Businesses, still worried about overcapacity, remained reluctant to invest. Instead, they paid down debt, purchased their own stock, and held cash. Banks and other financial institutions, wary of the stock market since At a U.S. Senate hearing in 1945, foreign currency is displayed. ©ThomasD.McAvoy/TimeLifePictures/GettyImages eJOURNAL USA 12 the dot-com bubble burst, invested in mortgage-backed securities and other derivatives. The anemic economic recovery was driven by growth in consumer spending. Real wages actually fell, but consumers increasingly went into debt, spending more than they earned. Encouraged by low interest rates — along with the new subprime deals — consumers bought houses, driving up their prices. The “wealth effect” created by these housing purchases further sustained consumer demand and led to a housing bubble. When housing prices began to fall, the bubble burst, and consumer demand and corporate investment ground to a halt. The financial panic quickly spread not only from mortgagebacked securities to other kinds of derivatives, but also from the United States to other countries, chiefly in Europe, that had purchased these American financial products. And that’s not all. As American demand for Chinese exports has stopped growing, China’s economy has begun to suffer. China would experience the equivalent of a recession, with repercussions throughout Asia. More importantly for the United States, China would no longer have the surplus dollars to prop up the market for U.S. Treasury bills. NEEDED ADJUSTMENTS The consequences could be even more dire. In the past, countries in recession could count on countries with growing economies to provide outlets for their exports and investments. The hope this time is that economic growth in Asia, and particularly in China, can backstop a U.S. and European recession. China depends on exports to the United States, and the United States depends on capital from China. If that special economic relationship breaks down, as it seems to be doing, it could lead to a global recession that could morph into the first depression since the 1930s. Policy makers have to recognize that while Bretton Woods II is not the product of an international agreement, it is not a “free-market” system that relies on floating currencies, either. Rather, it is sustained by specific national policies. The United States has acquiesced in large trade deficits — and their effect on the U.S. workforce — in exchange for foreign funding of our budget deficits. And Asia has accepted a lower standard of living in exchange for export-led growth and a lower risk of currency crises. China, Japan, and other Asian countries — either on their own or with prodding from the Obama administration — will also have to play a part. Indeed, China may have already begun to do so by announcing last fall a $586 billion stimulus plan of public investment in housing, transportation, and infrastructure. If China plows its trade surplus back into its domestic economy, it will increase demand for imports and put upward pressure on the yuan, reducing China’s trade surplus with the West. This kind of adjustment — in which the United States commits itself to reducing its trade deficit, and China, Japan, and other Asian countries move away from their strategy of export-led growth — is what many American policy makers favor. But there is also growing sentiment, particularly in Europe, that beyond these measures, the world’s leading economies have to agree on a new international monetary system — or at least dramatically reform the existing one. British Prime Minister Gordon Brown has explicitly called for a “new Bretton Woods — building a new international financial architecture for the years ahead.” Brown would strengthen the International Monetary Fund so it functions as “an early warning system and a crisis prevention mechanism for the whole world.” He would also have it or a new organization monitor cross-border financial transactions. But adjustments to the dollar’s role are certainly needed. The era of the dollar may not be over, but the special conditions under which it reigned during the last decades are being dashed on the rocks of the current recession and financial crisis. The original Bretton Woods was the product of deliberate agreement and laid the basis for stable growth. A new Bretton Woods agreement will depend a good deal on the choices of the international community. This article is excerpted from an article of the same title that appeared in The New Republic, December 3, 2008. Copyright © 2008 The New Republic, LLC. The opinions expressed in this article do not necessarily reflect the views or policies of the U.S. government.