microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. microtitle.jpg microedition.jpg varianname.jpg 24 Monopoly microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Pure Monopoly uA monopolized market has a single seller. uThe monopolist’s demand curve is the (downward sloping) market demand curve. uSo the monopolist can alter the market price by adjusting its output level. microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Pure Monopoly Output Level, y $/output unit p(y) Higher output y causes a lower market price, p(y). microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Why Monopolies? uWhat causes monopolies? –a legal fiat; e.g. US Postal Service microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Why Monopolies? uWhat causes monopolies? –a legal fiat; e.g. US Postal Service –a patent; e.g. a new drug microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Why Monopolies? uWhat causes monopolies? –a legal fiat; e.g. US Postal Service –a patent; e.g. a new drug –sole ownership of a resource; e.g. a toll highway microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Why Monopolies? uWhat causes monopolies? –a legal fiat; e.g. US Postal Service –a patent; e.g. a new drug –sole ownership of a resource; e.g. a toll highway –formation of a cartel; e.g. OPEC microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Why Monopolies? uWhat causes monopolies? –a legal fiat; e.g. US Postal Service –a patent; e.g. a new drug –sole ownership of a resource; e.g. a toll highway –formation of a cartel; e.g. OPEC –large economies of scale; e.g. local utility companies. microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Pure Monopoly uSuppose that the monopolist seeks to maximize its economic profit, uWhat output level y* maximizes profit? microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Profit-Maximization At the profit-maximizing output level y* so, for y = y*, microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› y $ R(y) = p(y)y Profit-Maximization microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› $ R(y) = p(y)y c(y) Profit-Maximization y microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Profit-Maximization $ R(y) = p(y)y c(y) y P(y) microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Profit-Maximization $ R(y) = p(y)y c(y) y P(y) y* microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Profit-Maximization $ R(y) = p(y)y c(y) y P(y) y* microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Profit-Maximization $ R(y) = p(y)y c(y) y P(y) y* microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Profit-Maximization $ R(y) = p(y)y c(y) y P(y) y* At the profit-maximizing output level the slopes of the revenue and total cost curves are equal; MR(y*) = MC(y*). microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Marginal Revenue Marginal revenue is the rate-of-change of revenue as the output level y increases; microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Marginal Revenue Marginal revenue is the rate-of-change of revenue as the output level y increases; dp(y)/dy is the slope of the market inverse demand function so dp(y)/dy < 0. Therefore for y > 0. microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Marginal Revenue E.g. if p(y) = a - by then R(y) = p(y)y = ay - by2 and so MR(y) = a - 2by < a - by = p(y) for y > 0. microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Marginal Revenue E.g. if p(y) = a - by then R(y) = p(y)y = ay - by2 and so MR(y) = a - 2by < a - by = p(y) for y > 0. p(y) = a - by a y a/b MR(y) = a - 2by a/2b microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Marginal Cost Marginal cost is the rate-of-change of total cost as the output level y increases; E.g. if c(y) = F + ay + by2 then microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Marginal Cost F y y c(y) = F + ay + by2 $ MC(y) = a + 2by $/output unit a microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Profit-Maximization; An Example At the profit-maximizing output level y*, MR(y*) = MC(y*). So if p(y) = a - by and c(y) = F + ay + by2 then microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Profit-Maximization; An Example At the profit-maximizing output level y*, MR(y*) = MC(y*). So if p(y) = a - by and if c(y) = F + ay + by2 then and the profit-maximizing output level is microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Profit-Maximization; An Example At the profit-maximizing output level y*, MR(y*) = MC(y*). So if p(y) = a - by and if c(y) = F + ay + by2 then and the profit-maximizing output level is causing the market price to be microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Profit-Maximization; An Example $/output unit y MC(y) = a + 2by p(y) = a - by MR(y) = a - 2by a a microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Profit-Maximization; An Example $/output unit y MC(y) = a + 2by p(y) = a - by MR(y) = a - 2by a a microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Profit-Maximization; An Example $/output unit y MC(y) = a + 2by p(y) = a - by MR(y) = a - 2by a a microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Monopolistic Pricing & Own-Price Elasticity of Demand uSuppose that market demand becomes less sensitive to changes in price (i.e. the own-price elasticity of demand becomes less negative). Does the monopolist exploit this by causing the market price to rise? microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Monopolistic Pricing & Own-Price Elasticity of Demand microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Monopolistic Pricing & Own-Price Elasticity of Demand Own-price elasticity of demand is microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Monopolistic Pricing & Own-Price Elasticity of Demand Own-price elasticity of demand is so microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Monopolistic Pricing & Own-Price Elasticity of Demand Suppose the monopolist’s marginal cost of production is constant, at $k/output unit. For a profit-maximum which is microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Monopolistic Pricing & Own-Price Elasticity of Demand E.g. if e = -3 then p(y*) = 3k/2, and if e = -2 then p(y*) = 2k. So as e rises towards -1 the monopolist alters its output level to make the market price of its product to rise. microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Monopolistic Pricing & Own-Price Elasticity of Demand Notice that, since microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Monopolistic Pricing & Own-Price Elasticity of Demand Notice that, since microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Monopolistic Pricing & Own-Price Elasticity of Demand Notice that, since That is, microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Monopolistic Pricing & Own-Price Elasticity of Demand Notice that, since That is, microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Monopolistic Pricing & Own-Price Elasticity of Demand Notice that, since That is, So a profit-maximizing monopolist always selects an output level for which market demand is own-price elastic. microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Markup Pricing uMarkup pricing: Output price is the marginal cost of production plus a “markup.” uHow big is a monopolist’s markup and how does it change with the own-price elasticity of demand? microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Markup Pricing is the monopolist’s price. microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Markup Pricing is the monopolist’s price. The markup is microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Markup Pricing is the monopolist’s price. The markup is E.g. if e = -3 then the markup is k/2, and if e = -2 then the markup is k. The markup rises as the own-price elasticity of demand rises towards -1. microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› A Profits Tax Levied on a Monopoly uA profits tax levied at rate t reduces profit from P(y*) to (1-t)P(y*). uQ: How is after-tax profit, (1-t)P(y*), maximized? microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› A Profits Tax Levied on a Monopoly uA profits tax levied at rate t reduces profit from P(y*) to (1-t)P(y*). uQ: How is after-tax profit, (1-t)P(y*), maximized? uA: By maximizing before-tax profit, P(y*). microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› A Profits Tax Levied on a Monopoly uA profits tax levied at rate t reduces profit from P(y*) to (1-t)P(y*). uQ: How is after-tax profit, (1-t)P(y*), maximized? uA: By maximizing before-tax profit, P(y*). uSo a profits tax has no effect on the monopolist’s choices of output level, output price, or demands for inputs. uI.e. the profits tax is a neutral tax. microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Quantity Tax Levied on a Monopolist uA quantity tax of $t/output unit raises the marginal cost of production by $t. uSo the tax reduces the profit-maximizing output level, causes the market price to rise, and input demands to fall. uThe quantity tax is distortionary. microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Quantity Tax Levied on a Monopolist $/output unit y MC(y) p(y) MR(y) y* p(y*) microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Quantity Tax Levied on a Monopolist $/output unit y MC(y) p(y) MR(y) MC(y) + t t y* p(y*) microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Quantity Tax Levied on a Monopolist $/output unit y MC(y) p(y) MR(y) MC(y) + t t y* p(y*) yt p(yt) microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Quantity Tax Levied on a Monopolist $/output unit y MC(y) p(y) MR(y) MC(y) + t t y* p(y*) yt p(yt) The quantity tax causes a drop in the output level, a rise in the output’s price and a decline in demand for inputs. microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Quantity Tax Levied on a Monopolist uCan a monopolist “pass” all of a $t quantity tax to the consumers? uSuppose the marginal cost of production is constant at $k/output unit. uWith no tax, the monopolist’s price is microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Quantity Tax Levied on a Monopolist uThe tax increases marginal cost to $(k+t)/output unit, changing the profit-maximizing price to uThe amount of the tax paid by buyers is microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Quantity Tax Levied on a Monopolist is the amount of the tax passed on to buyers. E.g. if e = -2, the amount of the tax passed on is 2t. Because e < -1, e /(1+e) > 1 and so the monopolist passes on to consumers more than the tax! microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› The Inefficiency of Monopoly uA market is Pareto efficient if it achieves the maximum possible total gains-to-trade. uOtherwise a market is Pareto inefficient. microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› The Inefficiency of Monopoly $/output unit y MC(y) p(y) ye p(ye) The efficient output level ye satisfies p(y) = MC(y). microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› The Inefficiency of Monopoly $/output unit y MC(y) p(y) ye p(ye) The efficient output level ye satisfies p(y) = MC(y). CS microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› The Inefficiency of Monopoly $/output unit y MC(y) p(y) ye p(ye) The efficient output level ye satisfies p(y) = MC(y). CS PS microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› The Inefficiency of Monopoly $/output unit y MC(y) p(y) ye p(ye) The efficient output level ye satisfies p(y) = MC(y). Total gains-to-trade is maximized. CS PS microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› The Inefficiency of Monopoly $/output unit y MC(y) p(y) MR(y) y* p(y*) microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› The Inefficiency of Monopoly $/output unit y MC(y) p(y) MR(y) y* p(y*) CS microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› The Inefficiency of Monopoly $/output unit y MC(y) p(y) MR(y) y* p(y*) CS PS microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› The Inefficiency of Monopoly $/output unit y MC(y) p(y) MR(y) y* p(y*) CS PS microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› The Inefficiency of Monopoly $/output unit y MC(y) p(y) MR(y) y* p(y*) CS PS microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› The Inefficiency of Monopoly $/output unit y MC(y) p(y) MR(y) y* p(y*) CS PS MC(y*+1) < p(y*+1) so both seller and buyer could gain if the (y*+1)th unit of output was produced. Hence the market is Pareto inefficient. microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› The Inefficiency of Monopoly $/output unit y MC(y) p(y) MR(y) y* p(y*) DWL Deadweight loss measures the gains-to-trade not achieved by the market. microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› The Inefficiency of Monopoly $/output unit y MC(y) p(y) MR(y) y* p(y*) ye p(ye) DWL The monopolist produces less than the efficient quantity, making the market price exceed the efficient market price. microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Natural Monopoly uA natural monopoly arises when the firm’s technology has economies-of-scale large enough for it to supply the whole market at a lower average total production cost than is possible with more than one firm in the market. microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Natural Monopoly y $/output unit ATC(y) MC(y) p(y) microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Natural Monopoly y $/output unit ATC(y) MC(y) p(y) y* MR(y) p(y*) microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Entry Deterrence by a Natural Monopoly uA natural monopoly deters entry by threatening predatory pricing against an entrant. uA predatory price is a low price set by the incumbent firm when an entrant appears, causing the entrant’s economic profits to be negative and inducing its exit. microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Entry Deterrence by a Natural Monopoly uE.g. suppose an entrant initially captures one-quarter of the market, leaving the incumbent firm the other three-quarters. microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Entry Deterrence by a Natural Monopoly y $/output unit ATC(y) MC(y) DI DE p(y), total demand = DI + DE microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Entry Deterrence by a Natural Monopoly y $/output unit ATC(y) MC(y) DI DE pE p(y*) An entrant can undercut the incumbent’s price p(y*) but ... p(y), total demand = DI + DE microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Entry Deterrence by a Natural Monopoly y $/output unit ATC(y) MC(y) p(y), total demand = DI + DE DI DE pE pI p(y*) An entrant can undercut the incumbent’s price p(y*) but the incumbent can then lower its price as far as pI, forcing the entrant to exit. microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Inefficiency of a Natural Monopolist uLike any profit-maximizing monopolist, the natural monopolist causes a deadweight loss. microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› y $/output unit ATC(y) p(y) y* MR(y) p(y*) MC(y) Inefficiency of a Natural Monopoly microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› y $/output unit ATC(y) MC(y) p(y) y* MR(y) p(y*) p(ye) ye Profit-max: MR(y) = MC(y) Efficiency: p = MC(y) Inefficiency of a Natural Monopoly microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› y $/output unit ATC(y) MC(y) p(y) y* MR(y) p(y*) p(ye) ye Profit-max: MR(y) = MC(y) Efficiency: p = MC(y) DWL Inefficiency of a Natural Monopoly microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Regulating a Natural Monopoly uWhy not command that a natural monopoly produce the efficient amount of output? uThen the deadweight loss will be zero, won’t it? microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› y $/output unit ATC(y) MC(y) p(y) MR(y) p(ye) ye Regulating a Natural Monopoly At the efficient output level ye, ATC(ye) > p(ye) ATC(ye) microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› y $/output unit ATC(y) MC(y) p(y) MR(y) p(ye) ye Regulating a Natural Monopoly At the efficient output level ye, ATC(ye) > p(ye) so the firm makes an economic loss. ATC(ye) Economic loss microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Regulating a Natural Monopoly uSo a natural monopoly cannot be forced to use marginal cost pricing. Doing so makes the firm exit, destroying both the market and any gains-to-trade. uRegulatory schemes can induce the natural monopolist to produce the efficient output level without exiting.