Efficiency, profitability and welfare gains from the Canadian National Railway privatization☆ Anthony E. Boardman a, ⁎, Claude Laurin b , Mark A. Moore c , Aidan R. Vining c a Sauder School of Business, University of British Columbia, 2053 Main Mall, Vancouver, BC, Canada V6T 1Z2 b HEC Montréal, 3000 Chemin de la Côte-Ste-Catherine, Montréal, Québec, Canada H3T 2A7 c Beedie School of Business, Simon Fraser University, 500 Granville Street, Vancouver, BC, Canada V6C 1W6 a b s t r a c ta r t i c l e i n f o Article history: Received 19 June 2012 Received in revised form 21 November 2012 Accepted 22 November 2012 Available online xxxx Keywords: Privatization Canadian National Railway Operational performance Social welfare This article describes and analyzes the privatization of Canadian National Railway (CN), a large railroad privatization. First, it reviews the theory and evidence concerning railroad privatizations. Second, it presents a brief history of CN and the regulatory environment prior to and after CN's privatization. Third, it uses data from 1990 to 2011 to compare CN's post-privatization operating performance with its pre-privatization performance. Fourth, it uses cost–benefit analysis to estimate the social welfare gains from the privatization and the distribution of those gains. The overall results demonstrate that CN performed substantially better following privatization, both from an operational perspective and from a broader social welfare perspective. We find statistically significant increases over the long term (16 years following privatization) in sales, capital investment, assets, profit, profitability, productivity, dividends and corporate taxes paid. There was little change in the capital structure of CN and a significant decrease in employment. Using Canadian Pacific Railway as a basis for the counterfactual, we estimate that CN's privatization generated social welfare gains of approximately $25 billion in 2011 Canadian dollars. The Canadian government received almost half of these gains, while CN's shareholders (most of whom were non-Canadian) captured the rest. © 2012 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved. 1. Introduction The privatization of Canadian National Railway (CN) in 1995 was by far the largest transportation privatization in Canadian history. Alongside the privatizations of the Japanese National Railways and of the British Rail, the CN privatization represents one of the largest transportation privatizations globally. Both the Japanese and British railroad privatizations have been controversial, especially in the British Rail case (Mathieu, 2003; McCartney & Stittle, 2008; Smith, 2006; Yvrande-Billon & Ménard, 2005). As we discuss later, the evidence on the performance outcomes of the railroad privatizations is mixed, although freight privatization appears to have done better than other privatized railroad businesses, including passenger services. The privatization of CN differs from the Japanese and British railroad privatizations in a number of important ways. First, the CN privatization primarily involved freight transport rather than passenger travel, which is the case in both Japan and Britain. Second, the CN privatization consisted of a one-time share issue sale of an integrated business (including track and rolling stock) and the maintenance of an existing organization, while the British and Japanese privatizations involved either separation of infrastructure and rolling stock (vertical separation) or geographic disintegration (horizontal separation). Third, the topographical footprint and conditions of the CN system are quite different to the other two systems. Fourth, both before and after privatization, CN faced a direct competitor over much of its network, which was not the case in Japan or Britain. Our main purpose is to determine whether the privatization of CN was beneficial. We take two approaches. First, we use data from 1990 to 2011 to compare CN's post-privatization operating performance with its pre-privatization operating performance. We examine changes in output, capital expenditures, assets, employment, profit, productivity, profitability, capital structure, dividends and corporate taxes. The findings are important from a business strategy perspective, a shareholder perspective and a government perspective. Second, we use data from the 1981–2008 period to estimate the change in social welfare from the CN privatization and the distribution of these benefits and costs between the Canadian government and (Canadian and non-Canadian) shareholders of CN. We use cost–benefit analysis (CBA) to conduct this assessment. A key feature of this CBA is that we use cost data from Canadian Pacific Railway (CP), a direct competitor of CN, to compute the counterfactual, that is, what would have happened in the absence of privatization. These findings are most directly relevant for the government of Canada and policy analysts interested in the welfare consequences of privatization in general and, Research in Transportation Business & Management xxx (2012) xxx–xxx ☆ The authors would like to thank Leo Fankhänel and Robert Boardman for research assistance. ⁎ Corresponding author. Tel.: +1 604 822 8484; fax: +1 604 822 8477. E-mail addresses: Anthony.Boardman@sauder.ubc.ca (A.E. Boardman), claude. laurin@hec.ca (C. Laurin), markm@sfu.ca (M.A. Moore), vining@sfu.ca (A.R. Vining). RTBM-00070; No of Pages 12 2210-5395/$ – see front matter © 2012 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.rtbm.2012.11.011 Contents lists available at SciVerse ScienceDirect Research in Transportation Business & Management Please cite this article as: Boardman, A.E., et al., Efficiency, profitability and welfare gains from the Canadian National Railway privatization, Research in Transportation Business & Management (2012), http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.rtbm.2012.11.011 more specifically, of railroad privatization. It also offers lessons to other governments considering railroad privatization or institutional reform. In sum, we find that the privatization of CN was beneficial to shareholders, to the government of Canada and to the overall welfare of Canadians. The most important results can be summarized as follows. In the short run (which we consider to be the 5-year period following privatization), profit (net income), profitability (return on assets and return on sales), and productivity (measured by sales per employee and net income per employee) increased significantly relative to the (5-year) pre-privatization period, employment experienced a statistically significant drop and there was no statistically significant change in sales revenue, capital investment, assets, capital structure, dividends or corporate taxes. In the long run (which we consider to be the 16-year period following privatization), there were statistically significant increases in sales, capital investment, assets, profit, profitability (return on assets and return on sales), and productivity (sales per employee and net income per employee). There were also statistically significant increases in dividends and corporate taxes, demonstrating that the most significant stakeholders in the privatization – government and shareholders – benefited from the privatization. Capital structure (debt-to-assets) did not change substantially. There was, however, a significant reduction in employment, although we argue that employees were not adversely affected. Turning to the welfare results, CN's privatization generated social welfare gains of almost $25 billion in 2011 Canadian dollars (which we use hereafter unless explicitly stated otherwise). The Canadian government received almost half of these gains, while CN shareholders (over half of whom were non-Canadian) captured the rest. The article is organized as follows. Section 2 briefly reviews the theory about privatization and summarizes the academic evidence concerning the outcomes of previous railroad privatizations in Japan, Britain, Australia, New Zealand and Chile. Section 3 presents a brief history of CN and of the regulation of Canadian railroads prior to privatization. It also describes some key events following privatization. Section 4 analyzes both the short-run and the long-run operational performance impacts of privatization. Section 5 presents our estimate of the overall welfare change attributable to the privatization of CN by using cost–benefit analysis, and of the distribution of these changes among different stakeholders. Section 6 summarizes the main results and identifies some of the factors that led to CN's success. It also offers lessons for private sector and government management, and includes some suggestions for future research. 2. Theory and evidence about railroad privatizations The weight of the empirical evidence is that privatization of businesses in reasonably competitive markets increases firm competitiveness, improves productivity and generates positive welfare gains (Boardman, Laurin, & Vining, 2002; Boardman & Vining, 1989; Boubakri & Cosset, 1998; Megginson & Netter, 2001; Shirley & Walsh, 2001). However, the long-haul Canadian railroad industry has been and is effectively duopolistic. While the direct overlap of CN's and CP's networks has been estimated at between 25% and 50%, the effective competitive overlap, given feed-in complementors that have options, is considerably larger (McNish, Jang, & Silcoff, 2012). Unfortunately, the theory and evidence concerning the impact of privatization in highly oligopolistic or duopolistic markets is not resolved (Chirwa, 2004; De Fraja, 1991; Willner & Parker, 2007). Both Canada and the United States have been unusual in enjoying a fairly high degree of direct competition in rail freight. The Secretariat of the OECD has noted: “competition in-the-market between vertically-integrated rail companies …requires the existence of at least two separate rail infrastructures capable of providing substitute rail services …this is the predominant form of competition in rail freight services in North America” (OECD Secretariat, 2006, 71). Furthermore, the Secretariat argues: “experience shows, at least in North America, that this approach has been able to deliver a degree of competition with relatively little regulatory intervention” (OECD Secretariat, 2006, 71). Evidence suggests that the presence of more than one railroad competitor reduces tariffs anywhere between 3% and 25% (Gomez-Ibanez, 2010; Grimm & Winston, 2000; Karikari, Brown, & Nadji, 2006; Winston, Maheshri, & Dennis, 2011). Furthermore, both CN and CP faced increasing inter-modal competition from trucking and shipping. In an important article, Caves and Christensen (1980) refer to Canadian railroads as operating in a competitive environment. Although the Canadian railroad industry was a duopoly on the long haul freight routes, this collective evidence suggests that it was “reasonably competitive” and, consequently, one might expect that the privatization of CN would lead to efficiency improvements and welfare gains. The evidence on previous rail privatizations has been mixed. Only in Japan is the evidence clearly positive: privatization increased efficiency and profitability, especially for freight rail (Mizutani, 1999; Mizutani & Nakamura, 1996, 1997; Thompson, 2003). The privatization also improved safety (Evans, 2010; East Japan Railway Company Management Planning Department, 2008) and travel times (East Japan Railway Company Management Planning Department, 2008). In Britain, the evidence is much less positive. The restructuring and privatization of British Rail (BR) took place during 1993–1996, when John Major's conservative government was in power. Thompson (2003, 347) argues that it “has been the most contentious of all railway system restructuring efforts”. There was significant political and economic opposition to BR's privatization and significant disagreement as to how it should be privatized. Eventually, BR was fully privatized and resulted in over 100 different private firms. Many of these privatizations, including that of the Railtrack, which owned all of the track and the stations, were carried out rapidly (some would argue hastily) towards the end of Major's term. Pollitt and Smith (2002) found evidence of significant operating cost savings in the first few years following privatization. Furthermore, Cowie (2009) found productivity gains in passenger rail on the order of 3–4% per annum over the first 4 years of privatization. In addition, there was substantial growth in passenger and freight traffic. However, there have been many criticisms of this privatization, including accusations of lower quality service (perceived reduced punctuality and overcrowding), a worse price-to-quality ratio and safety concerns (Mathieu, 2003), even though the evidence suggests that safety actually improved (Evans, 2007; Thompson, 2003). Following a huge cost escalation for the upgrade to the West Coast Main Line and the Hatfield derailment in 2000, the government decided to place Railtrack into administration and eventually replaced it with Network Rail, a not-for-profit company, owned by its members (Crompton & Jupe, 2007). Subsequently, annual industry cash costs rose by 47% and unit costs rose by 40%. Smith (2006) argues that this cost increase was largely due to an “excessive” concern with safety. Under the provisions of the Railways Act 1993, BR freight was split into seven companies, each of which was separately offered for private sale. In the end, however, five were sold to a single purchaser, English, Welsh and Scottish Railway (EWS), controlled by Wisconsin Central. Following privatization, freight traffic grew 42% between 1994 and 2000 (Mathieu, 2003; Thompson, 2003). However, operators have only been marginally profitable (Fowkes & Nash, 2004). Furthermore, despite mandating open access to freight companies, which was an important feature of the British restructuring, there has been very little new entry into the rail freight business (Cowie, 2010). In Australia there has also been extensive privatization of parts of the railroad system. Here, the record appears mixed. Williams, Greig, and Wallis (2005) note that the privatization of freight railroads has allowed consolidation across state boundaries and argue that, as a result, the industry is markedly stronger than in the past, although 2 A.E. Boardman et al. / Research in Transportation Business & Management xxx (2012) xxx–xxx Please cite this article as: Boardman, A.E., et al., Efficiency, profitability and welfare gains from the Canadian National Railway privatization, Research in Transportation Business & Management (2012), http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.rtbm.2012.11.011 governments remain the funders of last resort. They also maintain that long-distance passenger privatization appears to have been successful and consider the urban and rural passenger rail concessions a “qualified success”. New Zealand Rail Limited (later re-named Tranz Rail) was privatized as a single integrated entity. In this case, the privatization appears to have been a failure on most dimensions (Clark, 2010; Wilson, 2010). New Zealand Rail was purchased in 1993 by a consortium of financiers and Wisconsin Central who jointly put up about one-third of the money and financed the rest by debt. In 1994, New Zealand Rail sold its stake in Clear Communications and, the next year, it made a capital repayment to the consortium members of $100 million (current Australian dollars), only slightly less than the initial amount of cash they had invested. In 1996, Tranz Rail issued new shares to the public, equivalent to 25% of the company, and it was listed on the New Zealand stock exchange. Despite significant investments in freight operations, the required volumes did not materialize and Tranz Rail lost money. In 2000, a new Board replaced the former management team and sold off many of the non-core assets. However, Tranz Rail continued to perform poorly and the stock price dropped. In 2003, Toll Holdings made a takeover offer for the company and, eventually, Toll became the operator and the government acquired the rail network. The company was renamed Toll NZ and its financial situation continued to worsen. In 2008 it was re-nationalized by the federal government. Although the Tranz Rail privatization was a failure on most dimensions, it was highly profitable for the initial consortium investors. In Chile, railroad reforms resulted in the privatization of the entire Northern Railroad (sold to FERRONOR) and a state-owned Southern Railroad (EFE), which owned and maintained the track and carried passengers, but allowed private freight concessionaires (FEPASA and TRANSAP) to use the track (Soto, 2010). FERRONOR acquired the Northern Railroad in a competitive bid in 1995. It operated as an unregulated monopoly, concentrating on more profitable segments and eliminating others. From 1997 to 2000, freight volumes almost quintupled, revenues tripled, labor productivity tripled and profitability increased (see Soto, 2010, 16). On the Southern Railroad, FEPASA's freight volumes, revenues and productivity did not increase immediately following privatization, but did increase markedly after a decade of private ownership (see Soto, 2010, 18). Volumes rose partially due to the fact that prices were about 40% lower than prior to privatization (Thompson, Budin, & Estache, 2001), but despite this, profitability remained low. At this time, it is hard to reach a definitive conclusion on rail privatization in Chile, although the results appear positive in terms of freight. This review demonstrates that railroad privatization has been conducted quite differently in different countries. Also, the outcomes have been very different, ranging from clearly beneficial to disastrous. In general, it appears that the evidence for freight privatization is considerably better than for the privatization of other railroad businesses, including passenger services. Apart from that result, given the relatively small number of railroad privatizations, and the diversity of situations and outcomes, it is difficult to generalize about the key success factors. However, the following factors appear to affect the efficiency and welfare outcomes of railroad privatizations: (1) how the privatization process was conducted, most importantly whether through a share issue or direct sale; (2) the regulatory framework following privatization; (3) whether the railroad was privatized as an integrated network or whether there was separation of ‘wheel and rail’; (4) the market structure following privatization: the degree of direct competition, as well as the openness of the market and barriers to entry; (5) the price/quality characteristics of substitutes (especially road and sea); (6) the geography of the terrain over which the railroad operates, and economies of scale and density; (7) the degree and nature of technological change; (8) government policy following privatization, especially the extent of any government failures. Moreover, a myriad of relatively random, but politically salient, factors can affect whether or not the privatization is sustained (especially by governments elected subsequent to the privatizing government). For example, a single train crash that kills 10 people has greater political saliency than 10 road crashes that each kills one person. Our primary purposes are to consider whether the privatization of CN has improved operating performance or social welfare. The net effect of the interplay of all the above factors over time in any particular privatization is impossible to predict ex ante. The answer lies in the empirical pudding. 3. Overview of CN and the Canadian freight rail regulatory environment CN was formed as a government-owned corporation through the amalgamation of several financially troubled, privately owned railroads between 1917 and 1923. Since then, CN and CP have dominated railroad freight services in Canada. During much of the period of public ownership, CN was in various forms of financial stress. It is very difficult to determine the size of direct federal assistance to CN. Over the period 1927–1991, direct subsidy payments to the Canadian railroad sector amounted to almost $12 billion (1995 Canadian dollars), although over half of this amount was to subsidize passenger services (Bonsor, 1995). Much of the “subsidy” to CN was by way of recapitalizations: the Canadian government swapped CN's debt for equity or recapitalized it in 1937, 1952 and 1978. With the final recapitalization in 1978, the government imposed a hard budget constraint and mandated that CN should pay a 20% dividend on any profits earned. After 1978, CN appears to have operated more efficiently. Between 1978 and 1989, it was profitable in 9 out of the 11 years and remitted $237 million (current Canadian dollars) to the federal government (Bruce, 1997, 15). In the early 1970s CN was highly diversified. However, over time, it has focused more on railroad freight transportation. Around 1977, Air Canada was spun off as a separate Crown Corporation (state-owned enterprise), CN's passenger services subsidiary became another separate Crown Corporation, later called Via Rail Canada, and CN Marine, which operated ferries in Atlantic Canada, also became a separate Crown Corporation. CN sold CN Route (a trucking business) to private investors in 1986. CNCP Telecommunications and a chain of hotels were sold to CP in 1988, along with telecommunications divisions in the Northwest Territories and Newfoundland. CN also owned oil and gas assets, non-rail real estate, and a subsidiary that manufactured transport equipment. Most of these businesses were divested prior to privatization, and the manufacturing subsidiary was finally sold in 1996 (Canadian National Railway Company, 1995, 1996). The 1967 National Transportation Act significantly reduced the scope of rate regulation over both CN and CP, with the exception of grain transportation. But, Timur and Ponack (2002, 538) note that the 1967 Act still “emphasized cooperation between CN and CP and …the two companies exchanged cost information and set common freight rates.” In 1983, the Western Grain Transportation Act shifted the burden of the so-called Crow Nest Pass rates for grain (essentially price controls) from the railroads to direct government subsidies (Heaver & Waters, 2004). In 1987, the National Transportation Act (NTA) allowed shippers located on only one of the railroads' lines greater access to the other's line, allowed confidential negotiation of rates, encouraged reliance on market forces and arbitration rather than on the regulation of most non-grain rates, and it allowed both railroads somewhat greater freedom to abandon uneconomic branch lines. The 1996 Canada Transport Act extended the 1987 NTA provisions and allowed both railroads to eliminate low-density lines, resulting in the formation of more independent short-line railroads. More importantly, the 1987 National Transportation Act initiated a transition from the era of tacit collusion to one of more direct intra-modal competition (Bonsor, 1995; Timur & Ponack, 2002). 3A.E. Boardman et al. / Research in Transportation Business & Management xxx (2012) xxx–xxx Please cite this article as: Boardman, A.E., et al., Efficiency, profitability and welfare gains from the Canadian National Railway privatization, Research in Transportation Business & Management (2012), http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.rtbm.2012.11.011 And, as mentioned above, both CN and CP faced increasing intermodal competition from trucking and shipping. Paul Tellier was appointed CEO of CN in 1992 with the mandate to make CN more profitable and efficient prior to an ultimate privatization. Tellier began to run CN on a more commercial basis (Canadian National Railway Company, 1995; Bruce, 1997). The Canadian federal government privatized a number of Crown corporations between 1985 and 1997. Boardman and Vining (2012) provide a comprehensive discussion of the aggregate effects of these privatizations. The main reasons for the federal privatizations were the desire for more revenue or to reduce subsidies in the face of large deficits and government debts, and because it was consistent with the conservative government's ideological preferences (Boardman, Laurin, & Vining, 2003). Unlike many railroad privatizations in other countries, CN was privatized in its entirety and the infrastructure was not separated from operations. All of the large Canadian privatizations, including the CN privatization, were carried out through fixed-price share issue privatizations (SIPs). These firms were in at least somewhat competitive industries and were expected to improve their efficiency under private ownership. CN was privatized in November 1995 in one tranche, with proceeds amounting to just over $2 billion in current Canadian dollars. Only the privatization of Petro-Canada in 1991 raised more money for the Canadian government (about $9 billion in aggregate in current Canadian dollars). One issue of interest is whether the government left “money on the table.” Laurin, Boardman, and Vining (2004) found that CN was underpriced by about 25%. Based on a sample of 104 SIPs across 25 countries, they also found that SIP underpricing averaged 15.2% in other developed countries, but only 6.3% in Canada. This comparison suggests that the Canadian government did leave significant money on the table with CN's privatization, unlike its other SIPs. Since its privatization, CN has made a number of important acquisitions that have substantially expanded its North American network. Most significantly, it increased its presence in the U.S. with the acquisition of the Illinois Central Railroad in 1998 for $2.4 billion (current U.S. dollars). After this acquisition, Hunter Harrison of Illinois Central became CEO of CN. CN later acquired Wisconsin Central for $1.2 billion (current U.S. dollars) in 2001, Great Lakes Transportation for $380 million (current U.S. dollars) in 2003 and BC Rail for $1 billion (current Canadian dollars) in 2003. When CN acquired Wisconsin Central it also acquired interests in EWS Railways in the UK, Tranz Rail in New Zealand, and TasRail in Tasmania. CN quickly sold off these holdings. As of 2012, the increased efficiency of CN has had an impact on the management and ownership of CP. In 2012, private equity shareholders of CP (most importantly, Pershing Square) won a proxy battle to have CP hire CN's retired CEO, Hunter Harrison, to run CP (Deveau, 2012; McNish et al., 2012). 4. Operational performance changes at CN This section adopts the methods used by D'Souza and Megginson (1999), Boardman et al. (2002) and others to examine the impacts of the privatization on operational performance. One key difference is that this research uses data for a much longer period of time — from 5 years prior to privatization to 16 years post-privatization. The main results are presented in Table 1. Data are drawn from the annual reports, as reported by Compustat. All financial data are converted to real (inflation adjusted) 2011 Canadian dollars using the Canadian Consumer Price Index — All Items (CPI). Given that Table 1 contains the raw data for each variable, one can clearly see how each performance measure has changed over time. Table 1 also contains the average value of each performance variable during the 5-year period prior to privatization (denoted Pre-Priv), during the short-run (5-year) period after privatization (denoted SR post-priv) and during the long-run (16-year) period after privatization (denoted LR post-priv). It also compares the average value of each variable during the 5-year (SR) post-privatization period and during the 16-year (LR) post-privatization period to the average value in the pre-privatization period (denoted SR post–pre and LR post–pre, respectively). Finally, we present the Mann-Whitney U statistic (also known as the Wilcoxon rank-sum test), which tests whether the post-privatization observations come from the same distribution as the pre-privatization observations. In the following sub-sections we discuss changes in four major operational performance categories: overview (sales, capital investment, assets and employment); profit, profitability and productivity (net income, return on assets, return on sales, sales per employee and net income per employee); capital structure (debt-to-assets ratio); and payments to stakeholders (dividends and corporate taxes paid). In total, these measures provide a comprehensive picture of the effects of privatization on operational performance. 4.1. Overview CN's assets, measured in real 2011 Canadian dollars, were about $10 billion in the years prior to privatization. They fell by more than 10% in the year of privatization, but soon rose rapidly. Assets increased by almost $14 billion from 1997 to 2001, due partly to the Illinois Central (1998) and Wisconsin Central (2001) acquisitions. Since 2001, assets have continued to increase, albeit at a slower rate. By 2011, assets were over 150% higher than during the 5-year pre-privatization period. As shown in Table 1, the increase in assets from the 5 years prior to privatization versus the 16 years after privatization was statistically significant at the 1% level. CN's real sales did not increase as much as real assets during the post-privatization period. Like assets, they were relatively flat prior to privatization. Following privatization they decreased slightly. They picked up in 1998 and then grew slowly through 2008. In 2011, real sales were approximately 50% higher than during the 5-year preprivatization period. Similar to assets, sales were not significantly higher in the 5-year post privatization period than in the 5-year preprivatization period but they were significantly higher in the 16-year post-privatization period than in the pre-privatization period. Employment at CN was declining prior to privatization and continued to decline during the first 3 years following privatization. By 1998, employment had been reduced by 1/3 compared to the average of the 3 years prior to privatization. Thereafter, employment levels remained stable until 2011. The decrease in employment following privatization was statistically significant for both the 5-year and 16-year post-privatization periods. 4.2. Profit, profitability and productivity CN experienced losses (negative net income) in most years immediately prior to privatization. It took a major write-down (of over $1 billion in constant dollars) in 1992, the year Paul Tellier was appointed CEO and lost over $1 billion in 1995, the year of privatization. Following privatization, CN's net income (NI) was always positive and increased consistently, reaching over $2 billion in 2006 and 2007 (in both real and nominal terms). Profits fell slightly in 2008 and 2009 during the recession, but in 2011 profits reverted to their 2007 level. The differences in NI between both the 5-year and 16-year post-privatization periods, relative to the pre-privatization period, were both statistically significant. In the 5-year post-privatization period, CN's return on assets (ROA) averaged 3.6% and its return on sales (ROS) averaged 8.2%, which were substantially better than prior to privatization. Thereafter, ROA increased slightly while ROS continued to increase substantially. This long, consistent increase in profitability is particularly impressive compared to other Canadian SIPs, where profitability gains were usually achieved in the first 3 years and did not increase thereafter (Boardman & Vining, 2012). Both ROA and ROS showed statistically 4 A.E. Boardman et al. / Research in Transportation Business & Management xxx (2012) xxx–xxx Please cite this article as: Boardman, A.E., et al., Efficiency, profitability and welfare gains from the Canadian National Railway privatization, Research in Transportation Business & Management (2012), http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.rtbm.2012.11.011 significant increases following privatization in both the shorter and longer post-privatization periods. Although both sales and employment dropped in the first 5 years following privatization, employment dropped relatively more, which resulted in an increase in labor productivity following privatization, measured in terms of real sales per employee. Thereafter, productivity continued to increase. Prior to privatization, CN's sales per employee were about $180,000 (in real dollars). From 2005 to 2011, they were about $380,000 per employee. The increases in sales per employee were statistically significant in both the 5-year post-privatization period and the 16-year post-privatization period relative to the preprivatization period. Productivity, measured by NI per employee, experienced similar statistically significant increases. These results are consistent with Laurin and Bozec (2001) who found significant improvements in CN's total factor productivity following privatization. 4.3. Capital structure Following privatization, we would expect that debt relative to assets would decrease for two reasons. First, CN now had direct access to capital markets and should have found it easier to raise equity. Second, the removal of government ownership would, in theory, increase the cost of debt. This assumes, however, that CN actually paid interest on its government debt, which it may not have done. In the longer run, the debt-to-assets ratio might increase as profitability increases, risk is reduced and lenders become more willing to lend to CN. In fact, however, the most noticeable change in CN's capital structure occurred prior to privatization when the debt-to-assets ratio increased from about 50% (in 1990) to 66% (in 1993 and 1994). As expected, the debt-to-assets ratio did decrease following privatization, although the change from the 5-year pre-privatization period to the 5-year postprivatization period was not statistically significant. Thereafter the debt-to-assets ratio has changed little, although it has been slightly lower in recent years. 4.4. Dividends and corporate taxes paid For three of the years during the 5-year pre-privatization period, and in the year of privatization, CN paid no dividend. It commenced paying dividends in the first year after privatization and has increased (in nominal dollars) the dividends paid in each subsequent year except 2002 when they dropped very slightly. In 2011, it paid dividends of $585 million. The difference in dividends between the long-run post-privatization period and the pre-privatization period was statistically significant (at the 0.10 level), but not between the short-run post-privatization period and the pre-privatization period. Similarly, in the pre-privatization period, CN paid virtually no taxes. In fact, in some of these years, and the year of privatization, it received a tax rebate. In contrast, in the first 3 years following privatization, CN paid taxes of $151 million per year on average (in real dollars). The taxes paid have trended higher over time, although they have varied considerably from year-to-year. In 2011, for example, CN paid taxes of $889 million, but less than half this amount in 2009. The difference in taxes paid between the long-run post-privatization period and the pre-privatization period was statistically significant (at the 0.01 level), but not between the short-run post-privatization period and the pre-privatization period. 4.5. Conclusion on operational performance changes resulting from privatization Our analysis shows that privatization has resulted in improved performance by CN, using a broad range of operational performance measures. The statistically significant growth in sales, NI, profitability as Table 1 CN's pre-privatization and post-privatization operating performance, 1990–2011. Year Sales (millions) Capital expenditures (millions) Assets (millions) Employment Net income (millions) Return on assets (%) Return on sales (%) Sales per employee (thousands) Net income per employee (thousands) Debt to assets (%) Dividends (millions) Corporate taxes (millions) 1990 6236 500 10,749 37,000 12 0.11 0.19 169 0 49.55 86 −3 1991 5827 346 10,085 35,300 −21 −0.20 −0.35 165 −1 49.30 0 −5 1992 5783 477 10,065 33,500 −1435 −14.26 −24.81 173 −43 64.67 111 −18 1993 5889 614 9953 33,000 −111 −1.11 −1.88 178 −3 66.06 0 18 1994 6476 803 10,925 30,770 343 3.14 5.29 210 11 65.98 0 17 1995 5609 446 8483 26,951 −1485 −17.51 −26.48 208 −55 62.79 0 −25 1996 5609 669 8411 24,060 192 2.28 3.41 233 8 61.83 92 15 1997 5772 765 9384 22,800 535 5.70 9.26 253 23 51.70 103 431 1998 5442 649 14,267 21,510 143 1.00 2.63 253 7 60.50 130 8 1999 6790 812 19,046 23,490 777 4.08 11.44 289 33 62.69 172 476 2000 6845 763 19,099 22,460 970 5.08 14.18 305 43 62.50 201 556 2001 6929 782 23,034 22,670 891 3.87 12.86 306 39 66.14 228 481 2002 7326 685 22,690 23,190 685 3.02 9.35 316 30 64.98 222 321 2003 6863 680 20,003 21,490 856 4.28 12.47 319 40 62.22 223 394 2004 7499 1228 22,069 22,470 1485 6.73 19.81 334 66 61.88 254 723 2005 8113 1322 24,863 21,540 1744 7.01 21.49 377 81 58.32 308 875 2006 8480 1426 26,380 21,810 2294 8.69 27.05 389 105 59.07 374 706 2007 8492 1491 25,227 22,700 2321 9.20 27.33 374 102 56.62 449 589 2008 8913 1496 28,078 22,230 1991 7.09 22.34 401 90 60.48 458 683 2009 7721 1469 26,386 21,500 1943 7.36 25.17 359 90 55.38 497 427 2010 8539 1632 25,942 22,300 2165 8.35 25.36 383 97 55.23 518 795 2011 9028 1625 26,026 23,200 2457 9.44 27.22 389 106 58.96 585 889 Pre-priv 6042 548 10,356 33,914 −242 −2.46 −4.31 179 −7 59.11 39 2 SR post-priv 6092 732 14,041 22,864 523 3.63 8.18 267 23 59.85 140 297 LR post-priv 7398 1093 21,306 22,464 1341 6 17 330 60 59.91 301 523 SR post–pre 49 184 3686 −11,050 766 6.09 12.50 88 30 0.74 100 295 SR Mann–Whitney U 10 4 10 0a 2b 2b 2b 0a 2b 10 5 4 LR post–pre 1355 546 10,951 −11,450 1583 8.29 21.27 151 67 0.80 261 521 LR Mann–Whitney U 15b 7a 10b 0a 2a 3a 2a 0a 2a 36 16c 4a The figures for 1995 are in italics because CN was privatized in this year and these data are not included in the statistical analyses. a Statistically significant at the 0.01 level of significance for a two-sided alternative. b Statistically significant at the 0.05 level of significance for a two-sided alternative. c Statistically significant at the 0.10 level of significance for a two-sided alternative. 5A.E. Boardman et al. / Research in Transportation Business & Management xxx (2012) xxx–xxx Please cite this article as: Boardman, A.E., et al., Efficiency, profitability and welfare gains from the Canadian National Railway privatization, Research in Transportation Business & Management (2012), http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.rtbm.2012.11.011 measured by ROA and ROS, and productivity as measured by the sales per employee ratio and the NI to employee ratio, convincingly demonstrate that CN's operating performance improved in the post-privatization period. Some of these results were affected by CN's acquisitions in the U.S. and Canada. Certainly, assets, sales and employees were affected by the acquisitions. Improvements in profitability and productivity might also be partially due to these acquisitions if there were economies of scale or economies of density. However, we would argue that these improvements should be treated as benefits from privatization because, without privatization, it is very unlikely that the acquisitions would have occurred. Our results also show that CN's privatization has provided significant benefits for the major stakeholders. The increase in profits generated liquidity that CN distributed to shareholders as increases in dividends and to the Canadian government as increases in taxes paid. The next section directly examines the social welfare impacts of CN's privatization. 5. A social welfare (CBA) assessment of the CN privatization This section presents a CBA of CN (Domah & Pollitt, 2001; Florio, 2004; Galal, Jones, Tandon, & Vogelsang, 1994; Jones, Tandon, & Vogelsang, 1990; Pollitt & Smith, 2002). The methodology is similar to that employed in Boardman, Laurin, Moore, and Vining (2009), although some assumptions differ slightly. Also, our data extend five more years to 2008. It is important to note that these data pertain to Canadian freight operations, not to CN (or CP) as a whole. For some years, we applied a smoothing procedure for unusually high restructuring and miscellaneous costs (Boardman et al., 2009, 64). Our financial estimates are converted to present values (PV) as of 1995, the year of privatization, but are expressed in 2011 Canadian dollars. An important advantage of this CBA vis-à-vis most other privatization CBAs is that we use data from CP, a private sector company operating in the same industry and in the same country, to control for contemporaneous industry-wide changes and other external factors. The use of such a closely-related external benchmark is, as far as we can ascertain, unique. It leads to a more accurate counterfactual and considerably strengthens the credibility of the estimated benefits. From a normative perspective, the most appropriate measure of the social “value” of privatization is the net change in social welfare, which can be written as: ΔW ¼ Vp–Vg þ λg Z−Tg   −λp Z þ Tp   ð1Þ where, W is the social welfare, Vp is the value to society of CN after privatization, Vg is the value to society of CN under continued government ownership and Z is the proceeds received by the government. Tg and Tp denote the transaction costs that government and private sector actors incur, respectively, and λg and λp are shadow multipliers (weights) on government revenue and private funds, respectively. Later, we set these multipliers equal to unity. All variables in Eq. (1) are measured in terms of their PVs. Although aggregate social welfare is the most relevant criterion by which we assess privatization, from a public policy perspective it is also informative to consider the distribution of benefits and costs among consumers, shareholders, government, and employees. For this purpose, we use the fact that the change in social welfare can be written (Boardman, Greenberg, Vining, & Weimer, 2011): ΔW ¼ λcΔCS þ λpΔPS þ λgΔGS þ λeΔES ð2Þ where, ΔCS is the change in consumer surplus (CS), ΔPS is the change in producer surplus (PS, economic profits or rents, after tax), ΔGS is the change in the government surplus (GS, government revenues minus expenditures), ΔES is the change in the employee surplus (ES), and λc and λe are shadow multipliers for CS and ES, respectively. Later, these multipliers are set equal to unity. 5.1. Change in consumer surplus Any change in CS is largely determined by the magnitude of changes in prices and quantities following privatization. As mentioned above, the 1987 National Transportation Act marked a transition from an era of tacit collusion or parallelism to one of more direct intra-modal competition (Bonsor, 1995; Timur & Ponack, 2002). At the same time, both CN and CP faced increasing inter-modal competition from trucking and shipping. They responded to these pressures by reducing the track they owned and operated. In 1981, CN owned about twice as much track as CP and, as shown in Fig. 1, it operated about 32% more track than CP. Between 1982 and 1997, both CN and CP reduced the amount of track they operated in Canada by 27–28%. In 1998, CN reduced the amount of track it operated by more than CP, thereby reducing the gap between the two firms; this gap remained fairly constant until 2005. In 2005 and subsequent years, however, CN increased the amount of operational track, while CP continued to reduce track in each of these years, thereby increasing the gap again. These competitive pressures resulted in falling real prices in Canada (measured by dividing real Canadian sales revenue by the number of revenue tonne-kilometres of Canadian freight) from 1986 to 2004, as shown in Fig. 2.1 During this period, real prices at CN and CP fell by almost 50%. The downward trend was slightly faster in the 1986–1991 period, prior to Paul Tellier's appointment, than subsequently. Due in part to these falling prices, both CN and CP were markedly less profitable than their U.S. counterparts (Waters, 1997). Fig. 2 also shows that, with the exception of 1982, CN and CP charged very similar prices in Canada. As real prices fell, output (in revenue tonne-kilometres of Canadian freight) increased at CN and CP, despite the reduction in tracks operated. As shown in Fig. 3, both firms experienced growth in freight volumes from 1981 until 2008 that was in excess of 50%. Fig. 3 also shows that throughout this period, CN's and CP's Canadian freight volumes grew at similar rates and these rates did not change significantly following privatization. Since the amount of track operated fell at both firms, the track usage of both improved considerably. Given that CN and CP charged similar prices, and the output at both companies increased at similar rates, the market shares of both firms (measured in terms of total Canadian freight revenues) have remained very stable, as shown in Fig. 4. As shown in Fig. 2, real prices fell following privatization and, although they were trending upwards during the 2005–2008 period, they were still lower in 2008 than prior to privatization. Also, as shown in Fig. 3, output increased following privatization. Consequently, railroad consumers were better off and enjoyed higher levels of CS following privatization than before privatization. However, we do not attribute this increase in CS to the CN privatization per se. Prices started to fall in 1986 and, in our view, would probably have continued to fall in the absence of privatization. Florio (2004) reaches the same conclusion concerning the long-term trends in prices following UK privatizations. Our evidence on pricing, output and market share suggests that the gains in CS that actually materialized post-privatization would have occurred in the absence of privatization. Although there may have been some improvements in CN's service quality and safety, we cannot measure them and therefore, we do not attribute any change in CS to privatization. 1 A revenue tonne-kilometres means that 1 tonne of revenue-generating freight is transported 1 km. One tonne, also called a metric tonne, equals 1000 kilograms, which is about 2204.5 pounds. On average over the most recent five years, freight generated about 94% of the total Canadian revenues of both firms; passengers generated less than 1%. Other Canadian revenue sources included government subsidies (1.5%), compensation for services rendered to Via Rail (1%) and other miscellaneous revenues (3%) (Statistics Canada, 2003–2008). 6 A.E. Boardman et al. / Research in Transportation Business & Management xxx (2012) xxx–xxx Please cite this article as: Boardman, A.E., et al., Efficiency, profitability and welfare gains from the Canadian National Railway privatization, Research in Transportation Business & Management (2012), http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.rtbm.2012.11.011 5.2. Change in employee surplus Conceptually, any change in ES should include changes in producer surplus (rents) gained (or lost) by either employees or by others, such as consultants and investment bankers. Unions often argue that increased profits following privatization mostly come at the expense of lower employee salaries. If so, such effects would raise PS and lower ES. Furthermore, laid-off employees might not find jobs that pay as well, they may experience periods of unemployment before finding another job or they may incur transaction costs in finding a new job. Each of these factors would lower ES, especially during periods of negative or low economic growth. Fig. 5 shows Canadian employment at both CN and CP over time. In 1982, employment at CN was 66% higher than at CP, while in 2008 it was only 22% higher. This might suggest a loss of ES at CN. However, CN actually reduced employment at a slower rate following privatization (5.4% per annum during the 1995–2002 period) than before it (6.6% per annum during the 1984–1994 period). Furthermore, CP increased the rate at which it reduced employment from 4.2% per annum during the 1984–1994 period to 5.3% per annum during the 1995–2002 period. Consequently, we conclude that the reduction in employment at CN would have occurred even in the absence of privatization. We also examined real wages. In 1982, (real) wages at CN were slightly lower than (real) wages at CP, but the difference increased during the pre-privatization period. By 1995, wages at CN were slightly higher than at CP and they remained so until 2003. Thus, there is no evidence that CN employees experienced pay reductions due to the privatization. Overall, therefore, we conclude that there was no change in ES due to privatization. 5.3. Change in welfare, assuming zero CS and ES Under the assumptions that CS and ES equal zero and λp =λg =1 then, from Eq. (2), the change in welfare equals the sum of the changes in PS and GS. This change in welfare can also be written: ΔW ¼ Πp 96þ −Πg 96þ −Tp−Tg: ð3Þ That is, the change in welfare equals the PV of profits following privatization, denoted Πp 96+ (i.e., we treat 1995 as a transition year and compute the profits for 1996 and subsequent years), minus the profits that would have been earned under continued government ownership for the same years, denoted Πg 96+ , minus private sector and government transaction costs. Note that because of the assumption that λp =λg =1, the amount paid for the company at privatization, Z, is a transfer from shareholders to the government. Now consider the first two terms in Eq. (3). Economic profits equal revenues minus costs. Earlier we argued that prices and output were not affected by privatization and, therefore, sales revenues were not affected either. Thus, the difference in profits can be measured by the difference in costs. More specifically, suppose Cp CN denotes the PV of CN's costs under privatization, that is, from 1996 and onwards: C CN P ¼ ∑ t ATCCN t 1 þ sð Þt Q CN t ð4Þ where, ATCt CN and Qt CN are CN's actual real average total unit costs (ATC) and actual output levels in year t, respectively, and s is the social discount rate. Further suppose Cg CN denotes the PV of what these costs would have been with continued government ownership. Now, the change in welfare due to privatization is given by: ΔW ¼ Cg CN −Cp CN −Tp−Tg: ð5Þ We use CP's actual costs to estimate the counterfactual; specifically, the PV of what CN's costs would have been if it had not been privatized, Cg CN . Fig. 6 shows that CN's and CP's real ATCs fell more or less continuously from 1981 until 2004. From 1981 to 1987, CN's real ATC was higher than CP's ATC, but was falling slightly faster. Thereafter, for the 7 years prior to privatization, 1988–1994 inclusive, CN's ATCs were on average 6.1% higher than CP's ATCs, and this difference remained fairly constant from year to year. Based on this evidence, we conclude that if CN had remained government owned, its real ATCs would have been 6.1% higher than CP's ATCs. Consequently, we construct a series of annual, counterfactual real ATCs for CN by inflating CP's actual real ATCs by 6.1%. We then multiply these ATCs by CN's actual annual outputs to arrive at CN's counterfactual total annual costs. Finally, we discounted these amounts at the social discount rate to obtain our estimate of the PV of CN's Fig. 1. CN and CP Canadian track operated (kilometres). 7A.E. Boardman et al. / Research in Transportation Business & Management xxx (2012) xxx–xxx Please cite this article as: Boardman, A.E., et al., Efficiency, profitability and welfare gains from the Canadian National Railway privatization, Research in Transportation Business & Management (2012), http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.rtbm.2012.11.011 total costs if it had not been privatized, denoted as ^Cg CN : ^Cg CN ¼ ∑ t 1:061ATCCP t 1 þ sð Þt Q CN t : ð6Þ From Eq. (5), our estimate of the PV of the change in welfare due to privatization (ignoring transaction costs) is given by: ^Cg CN − C CN p ¼ ∑ t 1:061ATCCP t − ATCCN t   1 þ sð Þt Q CN t : ð7Þ It is important to note that this estimate of the change in welfare relies on the differences between CN's and CP's actual ATCs. By taking these differences, any industry-wide or economy-wide factor that might affect or bias CN's ATC, in effect, cancels out. Thus, using data from CP to compute our counterfactual provides a superior estimate of the welfare gains from privatization. Our data extend to only 2008. Therefore, we estimate Eq. (7) by using actual annual data for 1996–2008 and then estimate separately the PV of the cost savings attributable to privatization from 2009 onwards. By using a real SDR of 3.5% (Boardman, Moore, & Vining, 2010; Moore, Boardman, Vining, Weimer, & Greenberg, 2004), we estimate that the PV (in 1995) of the cost savings due to privatization for the 1996–2008 period amounted to just under $8 billion (in 2011 dollars). From 2009 onwards, we assume that the real annual cost savings will equal the average of the estimated real annual cost savings for the 2004–2008 period, which were just under $1 billion per year (in 2011 dollars). Dividing this amount by the SDR implies that the value of this perpetuity as of 2008 is about $26.5 billion. Finally, we discount this amount back to 1995, resulting in a PV of just under $17 billion for the savings from 2009 onwards. Adding these two amounts provides an estimate of the cost savings due to privatization of $24.7 billion (in 2011 dollars). To calculate the change in welfare, we must subtract transaction costs. Private sector transaction costs, Tp, were relatively small and can be ignored. It is reasonable to assume that the only non-trivial transaction costs that government incurred, Tg, were the costs of organizing the sale. These costs amounted to about $116 million in 2011 Canadian dollars, which are calculated by multiplying $1.0125 (the per share amount paid to the underwriters for the shares they Fig. 3. CN and CP freight output in Canada (millions of revenue tonne-kilometres). Fig. 2. CN and CP freight prices per revenue tonne-kilometres in Canada (2011$). 8 A.E. Boardman et al. / Research in Transportation Business & Management xxx (2012) xxx–xxx Please cite this article as: Boardman, A.E., et al., Efficiency, profitability and welfare gains from the Canadian National Railway privatization, Research in Transportation Business & Management (2012), http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.rtbm.2012.11.011 sold) by the 83.8 million shares sold (Bruce, 1997, 149) and then converting to 2011 dollars. Including these transaction costs, gives an estimate of the welfare gain from privatization of $24.6 billion (2011 dollars). As discussed above, Paul Tellier started to make efficiency improvements at CN immediately after his appointment. Thus, there is some merit to the notion that the PV of the cost savings during the commercialization period (1993–1995) prior to actual privatization should also be included as a component benefit of privatization. In fact, however, the PV of these cost savings amounts to only $52 million (in 2011 dollars) and can, therefore, be ignored. 5.4. Change in government surplus The change in government surplus, ΔGS, equals the proceeds from privatization, Z, plus personal taxes paid at the personal rate of tax, tp, on the underpricing, U, that is tpU, corporate taxes paid at the corporate rate of tax, tc, on CN's subsequent profits Πp 96+ , that is tcΠp 96+ , less the foregone profits if CN had not been privatized, Πg 96+ , and government transaction costs, Tg: ΔGS ¼ Z þ tpU þ tcΠp 95þ −Πg 95þ −Tg: ð8Þ Z equals the proceeds actually received by government, based on the issue price. While underpricing reduces this amount relative to what it could have been, this reduction is a transfer: it increases PS and reduces GS. For convenience we rewrite Eq. (8) as: ΔGS ¼ Z þ tpU þ tc Πp 96þ −Πg 96þ   – 1−tcð Þ Πg 96þ   −Tg: ð9Þ Here, tc(Πp 96+ −Πg 96+ ) represents the change in corporate taxes due to privatization, assuming that the government would pay corporate taxes at the same rate as the private sector, and (1−tc)(Πg 96+ ) represents the after-tax profits under continued government ownership, Fig. 5. CN and CP rail employment in Canada. Fig. 4. CN and CP market shares in freight in Canada. 9A.E. Boardman et al. / Research in Transportation Business & Management xxx (2012) xxx–xxx Please cite this article as: Boardman, A.E., et al., Efficiency, profitability and welfare gains from the Canadian National Railway privatization, Research in Transportation Business & Management (2012), http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.rtbm.2012.11.011 again assuming that the government would pay corporate taxes at the same rate as the private sector. Using the procedure described in Boardman et al. (2009), we estimate that the sale price, Z, was just over $3 billion (in 2011 dollars) and that the government tax receipts on the underpricing, tpU, amounted to $110 million (in 2011 dollars). To obtain the corporate tax revenues on the incremental profits following privatization, tc(Πp 96+ −Πg 96+ ), we multiply each year's real discounted, estimated cost savings due to privatization by the prevailing, combined federal– provincial corporate tax rate reported by CN and sum them. This yields a PV of $10,077 million (in 2011 dollars). We do not have a direct estimate of the after-tax profit if CN had not been privatized, (1−tc)(Πg 96+ ). However, the before-tax profits under continued government ownership, Πg 96+ , are likely to have ranged between zero and the PV of the expected future profits under private ownership at the time of privatization, denoted Πp e . We further note that the sale price, Z, should equal the PV of the expected after-tax future profits under private ownership, less any underpricing: Z ¼ 1−tcð ÞΠ e p−U: ð10Þ Consequently, under the assumption that Πg 96+ =Πp e , Eq. (10) implies (1−tc)Πg 96+ equals Z+U, the actual sale price of $3038 million plus the underpricing, $459 million, which amounts to $3497 million (in 2011 dollars). The average of this extreme amount and $0 yields an estimate of the after-tax profit under continued government ownership of $1748 million. Consequently, the estimated change in GS is about $11.4 billion (in 2011dollars) as shown in Table 2. The receipt from the sale is not the largest component of ΔGS; by far the largest benefit to government comes about as a result of increased tax receipts on increased profits. 5.5. Change in producer surplus Assuming, as we have argued above, that privatization had no effect on the surplus of shippers (consumers) or employees (ΔCS= ΔES=0) and assuming, as we have above, that λp =λg, then the gains to shareholders, ΔPS, can be derived from Eq. (2) by subtracting the gain in government surplus from the total welfare gain. Given our estimate of ΔW equal to $24,580 million and our estimate of ΔGS equal to $11,361 million, we estimate ΔPS equals $13,219 million (in 2011 dollars). The change in producer surplus, ΔPS, is the PV of the net benefits to shareholders discounted at the SDR. It equals the PV of the after-tax profits following privatization, denoted (1−tc)Πp 96+ , less the amount paid for the shares, private-sector transaction costs, and capital gains taxes paid at the personal rate of tax tp on the underpricing, U: ΔPS ¼ 1−tcð ÞΠp 96þ −Z−Tp−tpU: ð11Þ If we subtract the sale price of $3038 million and the personal taxes on underpricing of $110 million from our estimate of the gain in producer surplus, we obtain an estimate of the increase in after-tax profits of $16,367 million, as shown in Table 2. As we discussed above, the expected after-tax increase in profits equals $3497 million. Consequently, we estimate that the unexpected increase in after-tax profits was $12,870 million, which is also shown in Table 2. Clearly, it paid shareholders to buy and hold their shares until after these increases were capitalized into the share price. 5.6. Distribution of the welfare effects Table 2 shows how the benefits were distributed among Canadians and non-Canadians. Canadians, of course, received all of the ΔGS. The Table 2 Summary of the welfare gains from the privatization of CN and their distributiona . Total Canadians Rest of the world Government surplus Proceeds from sale 3038 3038 Taxes on underpricing 110 110 Increased corporate taxes 10,077 10,077 Total revenues 13,225 13,225 Less Foregone govt profits after tax 1748 1748 Transaction costs 116 116 Net government surplus 11,361 11,361 Producer surplus Expected after-tax profits 3497 2098 1399 Unexpected after-tax profits 12,870 5792 7079 Total after-tax profits 16,367 7890 8477 Less Taxes on underpricing 110 83 28 Sale price 3038 1823 1215 Transaction costs 0 0 0 Net producer surplus 13,219 5984 7235 Total increase in welfare 24,580 17,345 7235 a All figures are in millions of 2011 real Canadian dollars. Fig. 6. CN and CP average total costs per revenue tonne-kilometre (2011$). 10 A.E. Boardman et al. / Research in Transportation Business & Management xxx (2012) xxx–xxx Please cite this article as: Boardman, A.E., et al., Efficiency, profitability and welfare gains from the Canadian National Railway privatization, Research in Transportation Business & Management (2012), http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.rtbm.2012.11.011 distribution of ΔPS is based on the assumption that Canadians held about 60% of the shares when they were first listed (Bruce, 1997). Therefore, Canadians received 60% of the expected after-tax profits, amounting to just over $2098 million, but paid tax of $83 million on that gain and, of course, paid for their initial shares at the offering which was $1823 million. This amounted to $192 million. Soon after the stock was listed some Canadians sold their shares. About a decade after privatization, Canadians owned about 55% of CN (Boardman et al., 2009). Those who held on received their share of the unexpected after-tax profits, which amounted to $5792 million, resulting in a total benefit to Canadian shareholders of $5984 million. 5.7. Concluding comments on the welfare effects One can never be certain that a state-owned operator would not have achieved the same cost reductions as the privatized CN. Nonetheless, we think this is unlikely. Our analysis makes conservative assumptions concerning the counterfactual. First, while CN had closed the cost gap with CP prior to privatization, the difference had not been eliminated and had remained stable (at about 6%) over the 7 years immediately prior to privatization (for an even more conservative counterfactual, see Boardman et al., 2009). Second, by using data from CP we are able to control for Canadian industry-wide effects. As we mention above, the use of a very close competitor for such purposes is unique. Most importantly, if there were economies of scale effects, as Pollitt and Smith (2002) argued in the UK, they would likely affect both CN and CP similarly. Because we take differences, these effects would cancel out. We know of no other factor apart from privatization that would explain why CN's unit costs decreased relative to CP's unit costs after privatization. The effect of the U.S. acquisitions (such as Illinois Central) would be minor because our welfare analysis is restricted to Canadian freight operations, both before and after the takeover. Furthermore, even if these acquisitions did have a beneficial effect, it would be appropriate to include this effect because these acquisitions were unlikely to have occurred without privatization. There are many other reasons to presume that our estimates of the welfare benefits are conservative. Most importantly, we assumed that price decreases and quantity increases were not attributable to privatization. Thus, we do not include any CS benefit to shippers or other customers. Furthermore, ΔPS should also include any changes in the profits of CN's competitors and suppliers as well as the change in CN's profits in its other (non-Canadian freight) businesses. We very conservatively assume these additional effects are zero even though CP achieved some efficiency gains following CN's privatization and there may well have been spillover benefits to other parts of CN. Similarly, we have not included any longer-term, dynamic benefits of the privatization. Since privatization, CN has initiated or participated in numerous railroad supply chain initiatives (Miller, 2010) that have transformed the North American transportation network and have benefitted shippers as reduced time-costs (Boyd, 2011; Rodrigue, 2008; Starling, 2011). These benefits are probably substantial, but they are very difficult to measure and cannot be attributed entirely to CN's privatization. It is particularly important to point out that we have assumed that λg =1. Boardman et al. (2011) and other cost–benefit analysts suggest that λg =1 plus the marginal excess tax burden (METB). Based on a survey of relevant research, Boardman et al. (2011) suggest that the METB is about 0.23, that is, it costs society about $1.23 to raise $1 in taxes. Multiplying our estimated increase in GS by 1.23 implies that ΔGS equals $16,259 million and our estimate of the increase in social welfare would increase concomitantly to $27,620 million. 6. Conclusion: the aggregate impact of privatization Our main findings are that the privatization of CN improved sales, efficiency, profitability and social welfare. The total social welfare gains amounted to approximately $24.5 billion 2011 Canadian dollars. The increase in government surplus was about $11 billion, and the increase in producer surplus was about $13 billion with just under half of this amount going to Canadian citizens. The considerable size of these estimates demonstrates the potential value of a well-conducted privatization. Factors that contributed to the success in CN's case include the following. First, CN was well prepared for privatization and the privatization was not rushed. Non-core businesses were divested over a number of years prior to privatization. A few years before privatization, a new CEO was appointed with a mandate to improve efficiency and profitability in preparation for an eventual sale. Second, CN focused almost exclusively on freight, and provided no passenger services (although VIA Rail Canada and the Rocky Mountaineer provide some passenger services over parts of the network). Third, it was privatized as a vertically integrated company without separation of ‘wheels and rail’, thereby reducing transaction costs. Fourth, it was privatized through a share-issue privatization, rather than as a direct sale privatization. This ensured that CN was listed on the stock exchange and that ownership was not concentrated in a few hands. (In theory, this aspect could have been either advantageous or disadvantageous.) Fifth, there was a direct competitor. Sixth, there was some inter-modal competition from trucking and shipping, although these alternative modes were not as close substitutes as in many other countries, given the long-haul distances in Canada. This privatization offers some lessons for private sector and government management. This case study shows that company management can matter a great deal. While CN's average total costs were about 6% higher than CP's ATC prior to privatization, they were about 13% lower than CP's 5 years after privatization and thereafter. Tellier and Harrison took CN from underperforming relative to CP to outperforming it. According to Thompson (2003, 331) CN “is currently considered perhaps the best managed railroad in North America.” Management focused clearly on the core business and eliminated non-core assets, such as Wisconsin Central's holdings in a number of smaller railroads. Government managers carefully prepared CN for privatization, as we discussed above. Most importantly, they did not rush the privatization process. Tellier had 3 years to prepare CN for privatization. Another important lesson is that vertical disintegration (unbundling) may not be necessary for successful privatization when there is at least one other vertically integrated competitor. Indeed, Pittman (2005) argues vertically separated freight railroads tend towards bilateral monopoly, which has significant costs and only limited benefits. The Canadian experience suggests that having a vertically integrated duopoly is often a superior arrangement. Of course, these lessons pertain to freight privatization and may not apply to passenger privatization. A single, detailed study such as this one, in conjunction with other research findings, should provide some guidance to government policy makers in helping improve railroad privatization outcomes. There are some areas where additional research would provide further guidance. First, the performance and welfare effects of existing privatizations should be tracked over longer time periods (a large percentage of our estimated welfare gains are due to the assumed perpetual benefits that arise beyond the end of our data period). Second, it would be helpful if the welfare impacts of rail privatization could be further disaggregated by markets. This kind of analysis would shed light on the extent to which any measured gains from privatization flow from the presence of inter-modal or intra-modal competition. It may be that those routes on which CN faced no effective competition did not produce the same cost savings as on those where it had to compete directly against CP or where trucking or shipping were close substitutes. Third, more systematic evidence is needed to determine the conditions under which share issue privatization is superior to direct private sale. Along the same lines, more research is needed to substantiate our tentative conclusion 11A.E. Boardman et al. / Research in Transportation Business & Management xxx (2012) xxx–xxx Please cite this article as: Boardman, A.E., et al., Efficiency, profitability and welfare gains from the Canadian National Railway privatization, Research in Transportation Business & Management (2012), http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.rtbm.2012.11.011 that freight rail privatizations have been more successful than passenger rail privatizations. Finally, in order to control as much as possible for confounding effects, performance and welfare analyses of privatizations should compare actual post-privatization results to those that would have occurred in an explicit counterfactual situation of continued government ownership. Simple before-and-after comparisons cannot truly confirm that a privatization produced better results than state ownership. It is now widely accepted that privatization improves performance in competitive markets in developed countries. But there have been a number of reservations and caveats around this broadly positive conclusion. Do these improvements persist over time? Can these improvements occur in more oligopolistic markets? Although based on a single case study, this analysis suggests a positive answer to both questions. References Boardman, A. E., Greenberg, G. H., Vining, A. R., & Weimer, D. L. (Eds.). (2011). Cost– benefit analysis: Concepts and practice (4th edition). Upper Saddle River, NJ: Prentice Hall. Boardman, A. E., Laurin, C., Moore, M. A., & Vining, A. R. (2009). A cost–benefit analysis of the privatization of Canadian National Railway. Canadian Public Policy, 35(1), 59–83. Boardman, A. E., Laurin, C., & Vining, A. R. (2002). Privatization in Canada: Operating and stock market performance with international comparisons. Canadian Journal of Administrative Sciences, 19(2), 137–154. Boardman, A. E., Laurin, C., & Vining, A. R. (2003). Privatization in North America. In D. Parker, & D. Saal (Eds.), International handbook on privatization (pp. 129–160). Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar (Chapter 7). Boardman, A. E., Moore, M. A., & Vining, A. R. (2010). The social discount rate for Canada based on future consumption. Canadian Public Policy, 36(3), 325–343. Boardman, A. E., & Vining, A. R. (1989). Ownership and performance in competitive environments: A comparison of the performance of private, mixed, and state-owned enterprises. Journal of Law and Economics, 32(1), 1–33. Boardman, A. E., & Vining, A. R. (2012). A review and assessment of privatization in Canada. School of Public Policy. University of Calgary: SPP Research Papers, 5,(4). (pp. 1–28). Bonsor, N. (1995). Competition, regulation and efficiency in the Canadian railway and highway industries. In F. Paldi (Ed.), Essays in Canadian surface transportation. Vancouver: Fraser Institute. Boubakri, N., & Cosset, J. -C. (1998). The financial and operating performance of newly privatized firms: Evidence from developing countries. Journal of Finance, 53(3), 1081–1110. Boyd, J. D. (June 20). BNSF under Buffett. The Journal of Commerce, 10–13. Bruce, H. (1997). The pig that flew: The battle to privatize Canadian National. Vancouver: Douglas and McIntyre. Canadian National Railway Company (1990–2011). Annual reports. Caves, D., & Christensen, L. (1980). The relative efficiency of public and private firms in a competitive environment: The case of Canadian railroads. Journal of Political Economy, 88(50), 958–976. Chirwa, E. W. (2004). Industry and firm effects of privatization in Malawian oligopolistic manufacturing. Journal of Industrial Economics, 52(2), 277–290. Clark, R. (2010). Full circle: Rail industry privatisation in New Zealand, and a new theory of its fundamental conceptual weakness. ETC. Conference Proceedings. Cowie, J. (2009). The British passenger rail privatization. Journal of Transport Economics and Policy, 43(1), 85–104. Cowie, J. (2010). Productivity and performance in the British rail freight industry since privatisation. 12th WCTR, Lisbon, Portugal. Crompton, G., & Jupe, R. (2007). Network rail — Forward or backward? Not-for-profit in British transport. Business History, 49(6), 908–928. D'Souza, J., & Megginson, W. L. (1999). The financial and operating performance of privatized firms during the 1990s. Journal of Finance, 54(4), 1397–1438. De Fraja, G. (1991). Efficiency and privatisation in imperfectly competitive industries. Journal of Industrial Economics, 39(3), 311–321. Deveau, S. 2012. Corporate culture shift underway in Canada after CP Rail proxy fight. Financial Post, May 11. Domah, P., & Pollitt, M. G. (2001). The restructuring and privatisation of electricity distribution and supply business in England and Wales: A social cost–benefit analysis. Fiscal Studies, 22(1), 107–146. Evans, A. (2007). Rail safety and rail privatisation in Britain. Accident Analysis and Prevention, 39(3), 510–523. Evans, A. W. (2010). Rail safety and rail privatisation in Japan. Accident Analysis and Prevention, 42(4), 1296–1301. Florio, M. (2004). The great divestiture: Evaluating the welfare impact of the British privatizations, 1979–1997. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. Fowkes, A., & Nash, C. (2004). Rail privatisation in Britain — Lessons for the rail freight industry. ECMT Round Table 125, European integration of rail freight. Galal, A., Jones, L., Tandon, P., & Vogelsang, I. (1994). Welfare consequences of selling public enterprises: An empirical analysis. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Gomez-Ibanez, J. (2010). The simple analytics of open access with illustrations from railroads. Annual meeting of the Australian Competition and Consumer Commission, Surfer's Paradise, Queensland, July 29. Grimm, C., & Winston, C. (2000). Competition in the deregulated railroad industry: Sources, effects and policy issues. In S. Peltzman, & C. Winston (Eds.), Deregulation of network industries: What's next?. Washington, DC: Brookings. Heaver, T., & Waters, W. (2004). Canadian transport policy. In K. Button, & D. Hensher (Eds.), Transport strategy, policy and institutions. Oxford: Pergammon Press. Jones, L., Tandon, P., & Vogelsang, I. (1990). Selling public enterprises: A cost–benefit methodology. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. East Japan Railway Company Management Planning Department (2008). 20 years of JR East — Making a fresh start to shape the future. Japan Railway and Transport Review, 49, 18–24. Karikari, J., Brown, J., & Nadji, M. (2006). The Union Pacific/Southern Pacific Railroads merger: Effect of trackage rights on rates. Journal of Regulatory Economics, 22(3), 271–285. Laurin, C., Boardman, A. E., & Vining, A. R. (2004). Government underpricing of shareissue privatizations. Annals of Public and Cooperative Economics, 75(3), 399–429. Laurin, C., & Bozec, Y. (2001). Privatization and productivity improvements: The case of Canadian National (CN). Transportation Research (Part E), 37(5), 355–374. Mathieu, G. (2003). The reform of UK railways — Privatization and its results. Japan Railway and Transport Review, 34, 16–31. McCartney, S., & Stittle, J. (2008). ‘Taken for a ride’: The privatization of the UK rolling stock industry. Public Money and Management, 28(2), 93–100. McNish, J., Jang, B., & Silcoff, S. (2012). Collision course. Report on business, globe and mail, Saturday, January 14, B1. (pp. B6–B7). Megginson, W. L., & Netter, J. M. (2001). From state to market: A survey of empirical studies on privatization. Journal of Economic Literature, 39(2), 403–452. Miller, L. (2010). CN's productivity pipeline. Railway Age, 211(11), 12–16. Mizutani, F. (1999). An assessment of the Japan railway companies since privatization: Performance, local rail service and debts. Transport Reviews, 19(2), 117–139. Mizutani, F., & Nakamura, K. (1996). Effects of Japan National Railways' privatization on labour productivity. Papers in Regional Science, 75(2), 177–199. Mizutani, F., & Nakamura, K. (1997). Privatization of the Japan National Railway: Overview of performance changes. International Journal of Transport Economics, 24(1), 75–99. Moore, M. A., Boardman, A. E., Vining, A. R., Weimer, D. L., & Greenberg, D. H. (2004). ‘Just give me a number!’ Practical values for the social discount rate. Journal of Policy Analysis and Management, 23(4), 789–812. Pittman, R. (2005). Structural separation to create competition? The case of freight railways. Review of Network Economics, 4(3), 181–196. Pollitt, M. G., & Smith, A. S. G. (2002). The restructuring and privatisation of British Rail: Was it really that bad? Fiscal Studies, 23(4), 463–502. Rodrigue, J. -P. (2008). The thruport concept and transmodal rail freight distribution in North America. Journal of Transport Geography, 16(4), 233–246. Secretariat, O. E. C. D. (2006). Structural reform in the rail industry. OECD Journal of Competition Law and Policy, 8(2), 69–79. Shirley, M. M., & Walsh, P. M. (2001). Public vs. private ownership: The current state of the debate. Washington, DC: The World Bank policy research working paper, No. 2420. Smith, A. (2006). Are British railways costing too much: Perspectives based on TFP comparisons with British Rail 1963–2002. Journal of Transport Economics and Policy, 40(1), 1–44. Soto, R. (2010). End of the line: Railroads in Chile. Working paper 391. Instituto de Economia, Pontificia Universidad Catolica de Chile available at http://www.economia. puc.cl/docs/dt_391.pdf, accessed 16 Oct 2012 Starling, D. L. (2011). Intermodal's explosive growth. Railway Age, 212(9), 57–58. Statistics Canada (1983–2010). Rail in Canada, 1981–2008. Catalogue # 52-216-X. Ottawa: Minister of Industry. Thompson, L. (2003). Changing railway structure and ownership: Is anything working? Transport Reviews, 23(3), 311–355. Thompson, L., Budin, K., & Estache, A. (2001). Private investment in railways: Experience from South and North America, Africa and New Zealand. PTRC Conference, Cambridge. Timur, A. T., & Ponack, A. (2002). Labor relations and technological change at Canadian Pacific Railway. Journal of Labor Research, 23(4), 535–557. Waters, W. (1997). Changes in structure and performance in the North American rail industry. In J. Jones, & A. Stewart (Eds.), The new environment in freight rail. Kingston, ON: Queen's University School of Policy Studies. Williams, R., Greig, D., & Wallis, I. (2005). Results of railway privatization in Australia and New Zealand. Washington, D.C.: The World Bank. Willner, J., & Parker, D. (2007). The performance of public and private enterprise under conditions of active and passive ownership and competition and monopoly. Journal of Economics, 90(3), 221–253. Wilson, J. (2010). Short history of post-privatization in New Zealand. New Zealand Treasury 1982752v1. Available at: http://www.comu.govt.nz/resources/pdfs/mixed-ownershipmodel/mom-shppnz-wilson-dec10.pdf (accessed 15 October 2011) Winston, C., Maheshri, V., & Dennis, S. (2011). Long-run effects of mergers: The case of U.S. western railroads. Journal of Law and Economics, 54(2), 275–304. Yvrande-Billon, A., & Ménard, C. (2005). Institutional constraints and organizational changes: The case of the British rail reform. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 56(4), 675–699. 12 A.E. Boardman et al. / Research in Transportation Business & Management xxx (2012) xxx–xxx Please cite this article as: Boardman, A.E., et al., Efficiency, profitability and welfare gains from the Canadian National Railway privatization, Research in Transportation Business & Management (2012), http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.rtbm.2012.11.011