Applied Research in Public Policy Making Fall 2024 Martin GUZI martin.guzi@econ.muni.cz Benefits and costs of migration Week 2 Outline 1.Theory of migration 2.Push and pull factors of migration 3.Benefits and costs of migration 4.Remittances • THEORY OF MIGRATION • •Adam Smith (1776) was the first economist to write on migration: •... the wages of labour vary more from place to place than the price of provisions. The prices of bread and butcher's meat are generally the same or very nearly the same through the greater part of the United Kingdom. These and most other things which are sold by retail, the way in which the labouring poor buy all things, are generally fully as cheap or cheaper in great towns than in the remoter parts of the country ... But the wages of labour in a great town and its neighbourhood are frequently a fourth or a fifth part higher than at a few miles distance. Eighteen pence a day may be reckoned the common price of labour in London and its neighbourhood. At a few miles distance it falls to eight pence, the usual price of common labour through the greater part of the low country of Scotland, where it varies a good deal less than in England. Such a difference of prices, which it seems is not always sufficient to transport a man from one parish to another, would necessarily occasion so great a transportation of the most bulky commodities, not only from one parish to another, but from one end of the kingdom to the other. After all that has been said of the levity and inconstancy of human nature, it appears evidently from experience that a man is of all sorts of luggage the most difficult to be transported. •An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations, 1776 •Adam Smith (1776) was the first economist to write on migration: •... the wages of labour vary more from place to place than the price of provisions. The prices of bread and butcher's meat are generally the same or very nearly the same through the greater part of the United Kingdom. These and most other things which are sold by retail, the way in which the labouring poor buy all things, are generally fully as cheap or cheaper in great towns than in the remoter parts of the country ... But the wages of labour in a great town and its neighbourhood are frequently a fourth or a fifth part higher than at a few miles distance. Eighteen pence a day may be reckoned the common price of labour in London and its neighbourhood. At a few miles distance it falls to eight pence, the usual price of common labour through the greater part of the low country of Scotland, where it varies a good deal less than in England. Such a difference of prices, which it seems is not always sufficient to transport a man from one parish to another, would necessarily occasion so great a transportation of the most bulky commodities, not only from one parish to another, but from one end of the kingdom to the other. After all that has been said of the levity and inconstancy of human nature, it appears evidently from experience that a man is of all sorts of luggage the most difficult to be transported. •An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations, 1776 •Smith found trade to be more intense than migration. The reason is that migration is hampered by certain barriers that trade is not. •Regional differences in commodity or factor prices provide opportunities for arbitrage. •Intercity movements of goods (trade) arbitrages away commodity price differentials, whereas intercity movements of people (migration) arbitrages away wage differentials. •Smith suggested that migration is a response to spatial differences in the returns to labor supply. Thus the movement of goods and finance between countries is easier, and greater in magnitude, than the movement of people. Sending your money or your goods to some distant economy is much easier than sending yourself. Theory of migration: migration as human capital investment •Becker (1964) argues that migration is an investment because it involves the incurring of direct and indirect costs up-front in order to realize an (uncertain) payoff in the future. •The migrant’s goal is to maximize utility by choosing the location that offers the highest net return to human capital. •People can migrate for reasons other than income maximization (e.g. family reunification, political asylum). 1. • Non-monetary gains enjoyed from moving (e.g., amenities such as better climate and recreational opportunities, a desirable social, political or religious environment, or more desirable quantities of public goods available at the destination) are not counted among migration returns in the migration model.This does not mean that the influences of amenities and consumption goods are irrelevant. Spatial differences in such influences on migration will already be accounted for by geographic differences in living costs (his model includes spatial differences in real pecuniary returns to migration). For example, a more pleasant climate in California versus Minnesota should already be reflected in higher prices for California real estate. Empirical observations by Becker (1964) •Imperfect transferability of human capital, especially in high-skill areas, across borders limits migration •Younger persons are more likely to migrate than older persons •Temporary migrants have less incentives to invest in skills than permanent residents •More able people tend to migrate more •Migration is relatively low despite huge real international earnings differences Becker (1964), Human Capital: A Theoretical and Empirical Analysis with Special Reference to Education DETERMINANTS OF MIGRATION • Why people do migrate (relocate)? • •For work •For study •Marriage •Retirement •Housing amenities (e.g. air quality, culture, university) • http://media.economist.com/images/20090321/1209US1.jpg n 2013, 232 million people – 3.2 per cent of the world's population – lived outside their country of origin. - See more at: http://www.unfpa.org/migration#sthash.cQdrQRj1.dpuf •One out of five permanent migrants in 2016 was a humanitarian migrant (900,000 people). •United States (17%) and Germany (50%) were main destinations. • Source: INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION OUTLOOK 2017 Permanent migration flows to OECD countries by category of entry Source: INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION OUTLOOK 2019 •The family migration accounts for more than a half of all migration excluding free movement. PUSH AND PULL FACTORS • Push factors Pull factors Economic Economic High unemployment Demand for labor Poverty High wages High taxes Strong economic growth Poor health care Opportunity for advancement Overpopulation Schooling Technology Political and social Generous welfare benefits Discrimination Low cost of living War or oppression Corruption Political and social Crime Family and friends Compulsory military service Rights and freedoms Law and order Other Safety Natural disaster Famine Other Climate change Amenities Immigration push and pull factors The Economics of Immigration, by Bansak, Simpson & Zavodny ©2015 Push factors Pull factors Economic Economic High unemployment Demand for labor Poverty High wages High taxes Strong economic growth Poor health care Opportunity for advancement Overpopulation Schooling Technology Political and social Generous welfare benefits Discrimination Low cost of living War or oppression Corruption Political and social Crime Family and friends Compulsory military service Rights and freedoms Law and order Other Safety Natural disaster Famine Other Climate change Amenities Immigration push and pull factors The Economics of Immigration, by Bansak, Simpson & Zavodny ©2015 • •Source: http://download.gsb.bund.de/BIB/global_flow/ • Roy-Borjas Model – Selection of immigrants •Roy (OEP 1951); Borjas (AER 1987) •Consider two countries, A and B –Identical mean earnings –Different income distributions: returns to human capital higher in A •Individual returns to migration depend on one’s skills •In which country can skilled workers earn more? –Migration patterns: –Skilled migration to A and unskilled migration to B Skilled workers fare better in A If immigrants have above-average skills, the immigrant flow is positively selected. If immigrants have below-average skills, the immigrant flow is negatively selected. Frequency Skills Positively selected Immigrant Flow Negatively selected Immigrant Flow Skills The Self-Selection of the immigrant The Roy model of migration illustrates the self-selection of migrants on skill. How can you describe the migration motives of the low-skilled workers? 1.Low-skilled workers prefer to migrate to a country with higher income inequality. 2.Low-skilled workers prefer to migrate to a country with the more compressed income distribution (and lower income inequality). 3.Low-skilled workers prefer to migrate to a neighbouring country to minimize travelling costs. 4.There are no economic incentives to migration for low-skilled workers. •Puerto Ricans can move freely to the US without the legal restrictions. About 10% of the population born outside PR during 1970-2000. • Migration between Puerto Rico and the US •Return to skills is much higher in PR than in the US. The patterns of migration can be understood with Roy model – relative payoffs for skills across countries determine the skill composition of the immigrant flow. The international migrant population globally has increased in size but remained relatively stable as a proportion of the world’s population Source: World Migration Report 2020 The number of people living in a country other than where they were born Migrants in 2019: 1 in every 30 people 48 % are females 14 % are children 74% are of working age 20-64 60 % are migrant workers 2 % are students 10 % are refugees 15% are displaced (BD, MM) In last 5 years, more than 30,900 have died before trying to reach other country. Migration flows Top 20 world destinations (left) and origins (right) of international migrants in 2019 (millions) Source: World Migration Report 2020 Legal barriers to mobility •In medieval Europe (feudalism) serfs were prohibited to move without lord's consent •Barriers to internal migration in Czarist Russia and the USSR •China’s internal passport system (“Hukou”) •State specific occupational licensing laws act as barriers to internal migration in the US •Visa Occupation licensing is a legal requirement in order to practice a profession •In the US in 1970s, about 10 percent of workers had to have licenses, but by 2008, almost 30 percent of the work force needed them. •Louisiana, requires licenses for florists, math teachers need to be relicensed every time they move from one state to another. •Workers with licenses must pay upfront costs and face limited geographic mobility. • • • https://www.nytimes.com/2014/05/29/opinion/why-license-a-florist.html https://www.nytimes.com/2014/05/29/opinion/why-license-a-florist.html MINNEAPOLIS — IN Minnesota, more classroom time is required to become a cosmetologist than to become a lawyer. Becoming a manicurist takes double the number of hours of instruction as a paramedic. In Louisiana, the only state in the country that requires licenses for florists, monks were until recently forbidden to sell coffins because they were not licensed funeral directors. These regulations are not just unusual cases of state laws run amok but deliberate policies from one of the fastest growing labor market institutions in the United States: government licensing of jobs. This form of regulation — largely established by state governments and implemented through their licensing boards — is often referred to as “the right to practice.” Under these laws, working in a licensed occupation is illegal without first meeting government standards. In the 1970s, about 10 percent of individuals who worked had to have licenses, but by 2008, almost 30 percent of the work force needed them. With this explosion of licensing laws has come a national patchwork of stealth regulation that has, among other things, restricted labor markets, innovation and worker mobility. There is a role for government in protecting the public from incompetent or unscrupulous service providers, but there is little reason for math teachers to be relicensed every time they move from one state to another. These requirements put additional burdens on teachers that reduce the ability of good teachers to find work and schools to find good teachers. Having more flexible reciprocity between states for occupations like teachers would allow these professionals to move to jobs more easily. But even better would be to stop requiring licenses for jobs whose potential harm to the public is minimal, like tour guides, and instead allow for certification. This lesser form of regulation provides a distinction in the eyes of a consumer but does not forbid others from offering the service. There is good reason for workers in licensed fields to push for the laws. Jobs in a service-oriented economy are more likely to be licensed, which raises wages by about 15 percent, as I found in research with the Princeton economist Alan B. Krueger, the former head of President Obama’s Council of Economic Advisers. This is largely because of the ability of regulated professions working through state legislators and regulatory boards to limit the supply of practitioners and to drive up costs to consumers. Yet the growth of occupational regulation has prompted rare bipartisan opposition. On the left, there are concerns about inflated prices for essential services like plumbers and the availability of those services for people in or near poverty. Many of the jobs that require licenses are relatively low-skilled, like barbers and nurse’s aides, and licensing creates a barrier that might keep low-income people out of those positions. Occupational licensing, moreover, does nothing to close the inequality gap in the United States. For consumers, there is likely to be a redistribution effect in the “wrong” direction, as higher income consumers have more choice among higher quality purveyors of a service and lower income individuals are left with fewer affordable service options. On the right, the issue is one of economic liberty. From that perspective, government-issued licenses largely protect occupations from competition. Conservatives often see members of the regulated occupation supporting licensing laws under claims of “public health and safety.” However, these laws do much more to stop competition and less to enhance the quality of the service. Also, all consumers do not demand the same level of quality. If licensure “improves quality” by restricting entry into the profession, then some consumers will be forced to pay for more “quality” than they want or need. Not everyone wants a board-licensed hairdresser. If both the left and right oppose more occupational regulation, why is it growing? From the time of medieval guilds, service providers have had strong incentives to create barriers to entry for their professions in order to raise wages. The Dartmouth economist Charles Wheelan’s research showed in the late 1990s that respiratory therapists who organized themselves and raised their profession’s dues in order to lobby for licensing laws tended to be more successful in getting these statutes passed. In contrast, consumers who will be affected by the higher fees of, say, a licensed manicurist are unorganized and arguably underrepresented in the political process. Given these arguments from both the left and the right, can the growth of occupational regulation be reversed or slowed down? Last week, Representative Eric Cantor, Republican of Virginia, said he would ask governors around the country to take a closer look at licensing practices. And during the 2012-13 legislative sessions, Gov. Terry E. Branstad of Iowa, a Republican, vetoed the licensing of addictive disorder counselors and related occupations. In Indiana, Gov. Mike Pence, a Republican, vetoed the licensing of diabetes counselors and anesthesiologist assistants and dietitians. Both Mr. Branstad and Mr. Pence mentioned that this type of regulation would result in economic losses to consumers, higher prices and less employment. Occupational licensure has a large and growing impact on labor markets and consumers, but has yet to draw significant public attention or scrutiny. The left and right seem to be in agreement that policy makers need to revisit the process for creating licensure regulations and consider amending or rolling back existing laws in favor of lesser forms of regulations such as certification. Ultimately, we all would benefit from wiser, not more, occupational licensing. In the craft and related occupations, the proportion of licensed workers is 38% in Germany and 7% in Spain, while the average proportion of licensed workers at the state level is 33 and 17% •The prevalence of licensing varies significantly across member states: ranging between 14% in Denmark and 33% in Germany • •Occupational licensing is least common in managerial occupations (e.g., managers, executives) and elementary occupations (e.g., food preparation, cleaners) and most common among plant and machine operators, technicians (e.g., electricians), and professionals (e.g., lawyers). • Fig. 1 Pagliero, 2019 (https://link.springer.com/article/10.1007/s11151-019-09711-8) Changes in immigration regimes in 22 Western liberal states Source: Hass et al. 2016 •Over the past 70 years, immigration regimes (in Western countries) have been heavily concentrated on border control and more recently on exit and return measures (e.g. deportation). Policies have become more targeted on specific migrant groups providing multiple entry channels for low and high-skilled workers, permanent and temporary migrants, family members, students, entrepreneurs, and asylum seekers. Governments have liberalised entry for ‘wanted’ migrants, while policies have become more restrictive to prevent the entry and (irregular) stay of ‘unwanted’ migrants. Figure 27.2 reveals that over the past 70 years, policy changes in major (mostly Western) destination countries have been heavily concentrated on border control and more recently on exit and return measures, while admission regulations and post-entry integration policies have become overall less restrictive over the past few decades. However, policies have become more fine-grained and targeted on specific migrant groups which are reflected in the creation of multiple entry channels for low and high-skilled workers, permanent and temporary migrants, family members, students, entrepreneurs, and asylum seekers. Obviously, for each of these migrant categories, entry and post-entry regula- tions have not changed uniformly for the different legal categories but have become stricter for some migrant groups while turning more liberal for other groups. These trends and patterns reflect the extent to which governments have liberalised regular entry channels and stay perspectives for ‘wanted’ migrants, while border control and enforcement policies, as well as return and deportation measures, have become more restrictive in an apparent attempt to prevent the entry and (irregular) stay of ‘unwanted’ migrants. • https://www.passportindex.org/ Passport fees around the world (Passport fee for 10 years in USD) https://www.passport-collector.com/passport-fees-around-world-2018-2/ COSTS AND BENEFITS OF MIGRATION • Receiving economies (mostly developed countries) Short-run Long-run + lower wages, advantage for employers + lower labour costs + growing demand for social capital from the migrants (flats - accommodation, education, health and social insurance, energies, waste collection etc.) + increased demand for social capital from the migrants + inflow of highly-qualified labour force + inflow of highly-qualified labor force – decrease in the real wages + increased state budget revenues – increase in the unemployment rate of the domestic population (mostly with low qualification) + increase in the economical effectiveness + increase of the competitiveness of the domestic companies – problems of migrants to adapt in the new environment – growth of criminality + lower labour costs + lower wages, advantage for employers + increased state budget revenues + increase in the economical effectiveness + growing demand for social capital from the migrants (flats - accommodation, education, health and social insurance, energies, waste collection etc.) + inflow of highly-qualified labour force + increased demand for social capital from the migrants – decrease in the real wages + inflow of highly-qualified labor force + increase of the competitiveness of the domestic companies – growth of criminality – increase in the unemployment rate of the domestic population (mostly with low qualification) > Receiving economies (mostly developed countries) Short-run Long-run + lower wages, advantage for employers + lower labour costs + growing demand for social capital from the migrants (flats - accommodation, education, health and social insurance, energies, waste collection etc.) + increased demand for social capital from the migrants + inflow of highly-qualified labour force + inflow of highly-qualified labor force – decrease in the real wages + increased state budget revenues – increase in the unemployment rate of the domestic population (mostly with low qualification) + increase in the economical effectiveness + increase of the competitiveness of the domestic companies – problems of migrants to adapt in the new environment – growth of criminality Sending economies (mostly developing countries) Short-run Long-run + decrease in the unemployment rate + decrease in the unemployment rate + increase in the level of remittances (thanks to the growing revenues of the migrant workers) – losses in the form of cost for migration (travelling, accommodation in the receiving economy etc..) + potential re-emigration – return of the migrants with new experiences and knowledge, as well as accumulated capital – brain drain – lost investment due to brain drain to those workers (economical loss) – decrease of the level of the labor productivity influenced by the loss of qualified labor force – decrease in the pensions and incomes + decrease in the unemployment rate – losses in the form of cost for migration (travelling, accommodation in the receiving economy etc..) + increase in the level of remittances (thanks to the growing revenues of the migrant workers) + potential re-emigration – return of the migrants with new experiences and knowledge, as well as accumulated capital – brain drain – lost investment due to brain drain to those workers (economical loss) + decrease in the unemployment rate – decrease of the level of the labor productivity influenced by the loss of qualified labor force – decrease in the pensions and incomes > Sending economies (mostly developing countries) Short-run Long-run + decrease in the unemployment rate + decrease in the unemployment rate + increase in the level of remittances (thanks to the growing revenues of the migrant workers) – losses in the form of cost for migration (travelling, accommodation in the receiving economy etc..) + potential re-emigration – return of the migrants with new experiences and knowledge, as well as accumulated capital – brain drain – lost investment due to brain drain to those workers (economical loss) – decrease of the level of the labor productivity influenced by the loss of qualified labor force – decrease in the pensions and incomes REMITTANCES • REMITTANCES •Financial or in-kind transfers made by migrants directly to families or communities in their countries of origin. •Official estimates (by World Bank) on the scale of remittances are likely underestimated. •Globally, remittances are now more than three times the amount of official development assistance. •The biggest beneficents are middle income countries. • • • – 706 billions USD Estimated volume of remittances sent by migrants in 2019 (up from 126 billion in 2000). Officially recorded remittances to developing countries amounted to a record $550 billion in 2019. Remittance Flows dropped during the pandemic Remittances to Low- and Middle-Income Countries (LMIC) are expected to grow by 1.4 percent to reach $656 billion in 2023, following a very strong 8 percent growth in 2022 and 10.6 percent in 2021. Remittances •Moneys sent back home by immigrants (why?) •Large inflows, esp. for developing countries •Macroeconomic effects of remittances: –economic growth –employment –prices –exchange rate •High remittances may create dependency, increase local prices, appreciate exchange rate – • • Microeconomic effects of remittances •Remittances go directly to households in emigrants’ home countries •Reduce poverty and increase consumption •Allow higher spending on education and health care, hence better life for children and people •Help starting a small business (investment) •Facilitate the return of migrants • • • • https://remittanceprices.worldbank.org/ World bank monitors the cost of international remittance services since 2008 when the cost to send money was 10%. G20 set a target to reduce costs to 5%. Sustainable Development Goal (SDG) 10.c.1 aims to reduce this cost to 3% on average by 2030. Faster adoption of digital financial services, which make remittances cheaper and more convenient, should be a priority. Výsledok vyhľadávania obrázkov pre dopyt day of family remittances Social remittances •In addition to money, migration leads to the circulation of ideas, practices, skills, identities, and social capital. •Research shows how emigrants influence social protests, elections, and calls for greater transparency or reform. •Migration may affect traditional gender norms Which one is the push-factor of migration? A. A.Average income B.Ethnic conflict C.Democracy D.Unemployment benefits Why do people migrate most? A.For work, family reasons and better living B.For political reasons C.For education D.All of above E. Reading •Chapter 2 - Why People Become Immigrants •Chapter 3 - Where Immigrants go