9 MATE SELECTION ?k 246 Pan III / Gender Roles, Courtship, and Marriage and the Family Chapter Outline Mate Selection: Free Choice or Arranged? MaiTiage Regulations Why Marriages Are Arranged: Love and Marriage Arranged Marriages and Dowry in India Mate Selection in Feudal and Contemporary Japan Institutional Matchmakers: A Comparison of Contemporary Japan and America Conclusion In earlier chapters, I discussed an important structural change occurring in family systems—the movement toward the conjugal family. The conjugal family emphasizes the importance of the marital relationship and the ties of parents with children. In contrast, the consanguineal family stresses the extended-kinship relationship based on i common ancestry. In this family form, the emphasis is on the reciprocal ties and obligations of individuals with their extended kin. The importance of the conjugal (marital relationship is deemphasized, whereas the individual's involvement with the consanguineal (blood) family is emphasized. A most dramatic piece of evidence of the movement toward the conjugal family system is in the areas of premarital sex, conceptions of love, and mate selection. In many societies, men and women were not expected to choose the person they would marry; marriages were arranged by their parents and kinsmen. The freedom to choose one's spouse is an emerging phenomenon. In this chapter, I investigate the whys and wherefores of arranged marriages and nonarranged marriages. I examine the factor? that accounted for the prevalence of arranged marriages and the various forms these marital arrangements took. Of considerable interest is the relationship of modernization processes with marital-arrangement patterns and the contemporary modification of these patterns. Changing conceptualizations regarding premarital sex and love and the relationship of these to marital-selection arrangements attract attention. The consequences of the changes in attitudes and behavior regarding sex, love, and marriage for the individual, the family, and the society7 are investigated and analyzed. I conclude by looking at singlehood as an alternative to marriage. MATE SELECTION: FREE CHOICE OR ARRANGED? Who do people mam'? One way this question can be answered is to look at how spouses arc chosen. When persons have freedom to choose their spouses, individual motives account for marital decisions (Stephens, 1963). These can include romantic love, sexual desire, loneliness, desire for children, and the feeling of the attainment o: adulthood. In some societies, individual motives are allowed to be the determinants in selection of spouses. However, the majority of the world's societies chose to have family elders arrange the marriage of the potential couple. Frequendy, this occurred with- Chapter 9 / Mate Selection 247 out the consent of the prospective marital couple, and in some societies, like Hindu India, China, and Japan, the couple did not meet until the marriage day. In these societies, individual motives, like romantic love, were not supposed to be factors in mate selection. For example, in classical China or in feudal Tokugawa japan, love was viewed as a tragedy and at best as irrelevant to the family. The criteria for the selection of a spouse revolved around such matters as the size of the bride-price or dowry, the reputation of the respective kin groups, and traditional, customary, and obligatory marital arrangements. In his now classic cross-cultural survey on family customs in other societies, William N. Stephens (1963) found that those societies that had extended-family systems or unilineal kin groups tended to give the heads of these families, who were usually men, a great amount of authority and power. They either had the entire responsibility for arranging the marriage of their children or did not allow children to choose for themselves without reserving the right to veto that choice. Further, those societies that were characterized by a nuclear conjugal-family system and bilineal kin groups were the only ones that allowed free choice of mate with parental approval not being necessary. Stephens concludes that "the form of mate choice is in part a function of extended kinship: when large kin groups are strong and important, then marriage tends to be a kin-group affair—it is taken out of the hands of the potential bride and groom" (Stephens, 1963:198). This strong relationship between types of family organization, extended or nuclear, and the form of mate choice is consistent with earlier discussions of conjugal and consanguineal systems. The conjugal-family system, which takes the nuclear form, emphasizes strong husband-wife and parent-child ties. As William J. Goode (1963) has observed, the ideolog)' of the conjugal family emphasizes the independence of the marital couple from extensive obligatory ties with extended consanguineal kin. It stresses individual choice in mate selection that is guided by romantic love and sexual attraction. On marriage, the couple set up their own independent household (neolocal residence), which symbolically and actually demonstrates their commitment to the development of strong conjugal ties and the desire to sever potentially dominating ties with either kin groups. The consanguineal family, on the other hand, is a quite different form of family organization. Here, the stress is on the maintenance of extended blood relationships. On marriage, a couple may move into or near the household of either the husband's or wife's family (patrilocal or niatrilocal residence). Children are socialized into the larger extended kinship group. The consequent strong blood ties of unilineal members of the consanguineal-family system thus account for the greater need and desire to control the mate choice of their members. Marriage Regulations There is a striking increase in the number of societies that now allow individuals to marry through free choice in contrast to their former predominant practice by which family elders arranged the marriage. The choice of eligible mates for their children was governed by two conflicting types of marital regulations. The first, endogamy, refers to the requirement that an individual marry someone within a particular group. 248 Part. III / Gender Roles, Courtship, and yiamiage and the Family This group could be a kinship group, a clan, a religious organization, or any other social category. The second, exogamy, refers to the requirement that an individual marry someone outside a particular group. Exogamous rules usually coincide with incest taboos—the prohibition of sexual intercourse between certain blood relations, for example, between father and daughter, mother and son, or brother and sister. Exogamous rules are primarily kinship based and generally prohibit sexual activities and marriage among people who are closely related. Frequently, exogamous rules are extended to apply to larger social units. In classical China, a man was not permitted to marry a woman who had the same surname, even though they were not kinship-related. Certain societies prohibit the marriage of members of the same village or the same tribe. Yonina Talmon (1964) reports that children raised in the same peer group on a collective settlement (kibbutz) in Israel are informally pressured against intra-kibbutz marriage. She suggests that the excessive familiarity1 of young people socialized together prevents them from falling in love. There are numerous theories of incest and exogamy. This is a much discussed topic in die social sciences with many explanations proposed through the years. The explanations seem to fall into two main categories: First, diere are theories that revolve around biological, genetic, and psychological factors to explain individual motivations: second, there are theories that deal with mate-selection patterns in terms of their effec: on intragroup or intergroup solidarity with macrolevel analysis of the society. Falling into the first category are such theories as (1) a horror instinct agains: incest, (2) Freudian psychoanalytical theory, and (3) genetic influences on the inces: taboo. The first theory, horror instinct against incest, postulates that individuals have an instinctive horror of having sexual relations with close kin. To avoid such an occurrence, incest taboos were created to provide further social pressure against the commitment of such a "horror." This theory is somewhat contradictory in that if there was an instinctual dread of incest, there would he no need for the creation of incest taboo? socializing individuals against it. This theory has been generally discarded. The Freudian psychological theory in regard to the incest taboo was developec out of Sophocles' tragedy, Oedipus Rex. Oedipus, the son, unknowingly slays his father and marries his mother. On becoming aware of his actions, he blinds himself. Freud stressed tire universal tendency of children to have a strong sexual attraction to the parent of the opposite sex. Incest taboos arise as a reaction to incestuous wishes an c are a rejection of the forbidden and frightening sexual attraction of the opposite-sex parent. The Freudian theory is weak in that it does not explain the extension of inces: taboos beyond the immediate family. The genetic theory postulates that incest taboos were developed to prevent the potentially harmful effects of inbreeding, that is, madness, hemophilia, and so on. The theory emphasizes the real and imagined deleterious effects of inbreeding and ignores the positive ones; for example, the inbreeding of cattle to develop a superior strain of usable beef. Further, although there is some genetic evidence of die negative consequences o: inbreeding, die dieory assumes a level of biologic sophistication and knowledge that goes beyond that exhibited by most persons in most societies. An extreme example is the Arunta of Australia who were unaware of the role of die father in procreation. There are several theories that focus on societal factors in regard to the inces: taboo. George Mnrdock (1949) used psychological behavior theory, Freudian psycho- ■ ^wgffltejjjjj. Chapter 9 /Mate Selection 249 analytic theory, and previously developed theories in anthropology and sociolog}7 to construct his theory of the incest taboo. His ideas were enhanced by his use of his own cross-cultural data from 250 societies. He argues that the origins of the incest taboo arise out of the unwillingness of parents and siblings to satisfy personally the child's sexual desire. Further, the family, which provides important societal needs (economic cooperation, reproduction, education, and socialization), wishes to avoid anything that weakens it. It is thought that weakening the family would, in turn, weaken the larger social system. Conflict within the family resulting from sexual competition and jealousy would be highly disruptive. Thus, "the reduction of sexual rivalry between parents and children and between siblings consolidates the family as a cooperative social group, promotes the efficiency of its societal sendees, and thus strengthens the society as a whole" (Murdoch, 1949:295). Murdock then argued that the extension of the incest taboo to more distant and remote relatives beyond the nuclear family can be explained by the behavioristic psychology concept of stimulus generalization. According to diis principle, any response evoked by one stimulus will tend to be elicited by other stimuli in direct proportion to their similarity to the original stimuli. Murdock sees that secondary or remote relatives who resemble a sexually tabooed member of the nuclear family will have the avoidance behavior extended to them. His illustration is that of a mother's sister (ego's aunt), who may possess similar features and other physical traits of the mother. This relative will be perceived as similar to the mother and thus will be sexually avoided. He states that there is a prevalence of applying the same kinship term to the two women in many societies (both referred to by the term, mother) and ego exhibits similar patterned behavior towards both. Murdock does not answer the question on why the marital restrictions and taboos are extended further in many societies. The theory of reciprocity by Claude Levi-Strauss seeks to answer this question. Levi-Strauss (1957) believes that the prohibition of incest is one of the rules related to reciprocity. The marriage between individuals belonging to different nuclear families may be viewed as an exchange between two families, one providing the husband, the other providing the wife. The newly formed nuclear family is conceived of as a social organization that links several families in a chain of reciprocal exchanges. The cultural development of a society is seen to be dependent on the development of a more complex culture than can be developed by any given family. Cultural development is enhanced by the linking of families into wider social organizations through reciprocal social bonds. To illustrate this, Levi-Strauss utilizes the following model. The prohibition of incest is a rule of reciprocity when it means that a family must give up a daughter or sister if its neighboring family will also do so. Marriage is viewed as an exchange between families in which, at one point in time, a given family gives up a daughter and at another point accepts one. Thus, there is a perpetual mutual obligation to supply women in marriage. If one looks at a hypothetical situation in which one family has a monopoly on desirable women, whereas the other family in the group has none available, a potential climate of hostility and tension can arise. Reciprocity thus serves to assure a more balanced state. This illustrative model assumes that women are treated as property and that there is a scarcity of women for marriage. It is based on an assumption of male polygyny and on the greater attractiveness and desirability of cer- 250 Part III / Gender Roles, Courtship, and Marriage and the Family tain women. More important, the principle of reciprocity in regard to marriage is seen by Levi-Strauss as assuring the occurrence of social exchange and the establishment c: alliances between families. The incest taboo serves as the basis for the development o: groups larger than the nuclear family and is a key organizing factor in society. The family, then, is vital to society as it establishes broader social relationships through the patterned exchange of sexual relationships. Rules of endogamy run counter to the rules of exogamy, or totem prohibition. T: repeat, endogamous rules require a person to marry someone within a given social grouping. These social groups can range from the extended-kinship system, the tribe, community, social class, race, or nationality. Linton C. Freeman (1974), following the analysis of George Murdock, sees the basis for endogamous rules stemming from ett~ nocentris?n, or group conceit, which is common to all social groups. Freeman observe: that, almost universally, outsiders are suspect; people tend to distrust or to dislike people who are different from themselves. People discriminate on the basis of race, creed, and cultural backgrounds. Conversely, they accept members of their own family an: community more readily, since they share a common background and heritage. In sex relations and mate selection, ethnocentrism is expressed by prohibiting marriage with. outsiders through specified rules of endogamy. In the United States, endogamoui rules are exhibited through pressures for individuals to marry someone of the same race, social class, ethnic group, religion, and age. The term homogamy has been used t; refer to this governing principle of marital choice. Homogamy is the tendency t: marry someone who is like ourselves in the important social attributes of race, class, education, age, religious and ethnic backgrounds. Endogamy (marriage within a group) and exogamy (marriage outside a group) can be seen to delineate a "field of eligible mates" (Freeman, 1974:355). This field of eligible or approved marital partners can be large or small, depending on the relative strengths of the two complementary tendencies of endogamy and exogamy. Together, they are seen to make up the rules for preferential mating. In addition to preferential mating, a second principle is seen to underlie the process of mate selection: marriage arrangement. Marriage arrangement is defined by Freeman as referring to the degree to which persons other than the prospective bride and groom participate in the process of selection; for example, whether parents are involved in the mate-selecticc process. Here, again, a wide range of societal patterns exist, ranging from families having little involvement in the selection of a spouse to societies where families select the individual's spouse with little or no involvement by that individual in the decisionmaking process. The question now arises, why should and how do people other than the man an: woman immediately involved arrange marriages? WHY MARRIAGES ARE ARRANGED: LOVE AND MARRIAGE A more systematic analysis of the factors that have accounted for the widespre:: prevalence of arranged marriages is now undertaken. Of particular interest is the role of love in the arrangement of marriages. Chapter 9 /''Maie Selection 251 Ainlee, a 5-year-old bride, unties string knots of her husband, Ashok, 15, during their marriage ritual in the Indian desert village of Srirampur of the nortliwestern state of Rajasthan on May 14, 1994. Hundreds of children across the state were married on the Hindu auspicious day "Akha Teej" despite the government proclamation against such marriages. Two different theoretical models have been put forth on why marriages are arranged. One theory, developed by Bernard Färber (1964), stresses the importance of rules regarding mate selection in terms of preserving family culture. The other, developed by William J. Goode (1959), stresses the restrictions placed on mate selection to maintain the social-stratification system through the emphasis on lineage and kinship obligations and involvements. According to Färber (1964), family culture is seen to have as its constituent elements the norms and values that people hold regarding courtship, marriage, divorce, 252 Pan III / Gender Roles, Courtship, and Marriage and the Family kinship identity and obligations, socialization of children, residence, and househcT:; maintenance. Exogamous rules may lead to individuals marrying outside of their family group; potentially the possibility does exist that one will marry someone with efferent norms and values and open the family system to external influences that can V damaging to the continuity of the culture of the particular family group. The choice : : marriage partner, then, is controlled by the family of orientation to assure transmission of the family culture to future generations. Thus, at the point of marriage of the child both parental families are in danger of having their culture interrupted in transmission by the introduction of possibly contradictory values from the other family. Restrictions in the society on mate selection would delimit the direction of change in family cultures from one generation to the next. If certain families will permit marriage only with other families very similar to themselves in norms and values, then a genera! continuity of the cultures of both families can be expected. (Färber, 1964:63-64 In his essay "The Theoretical Importance of Love." William J. Goode '.-'■■ delineates the reasons on why marriages are arranged and the way love is conti: „r_. Goode argues that allowing individuals the freedom to marry on the basis of inim:-ual motives, particularly love, can be potentially disruptive to lineage pattern: _::.: weaken kinship systems. When marriage involves the linking of two kinship grľ'ji* and when kinship serves as the basis of societal organization, mate choice has i~-> r-tant consequences for the social structure. Thus, when marriage affects the own=r;..:x of property and the exercise of influence, the issue of mate selection and hvč šir'-t been considered "too important to be left to the children" (Goode, 1959:4-3). Goode states that, "Kinfolk or immediate family can disregard the question c.: who marries whom, only if a marriage is not seen as a link between kin lines, only if nc property, power, lineage honor, totemic relationships, and the like are believed to flow from the kin lines through the spouses to their offspring" (1959:42). Societies tha: emphasize kinship find it necessary to control marriages. Goode, then, distinguishes among several methods for controlling the selection of marital partners. First, it is controlled by child marriage, where, as in India, the young bride moves to the household of her husband and the marriage is not consummated until a much later date. This practice precludes the possibility of the child falling in love and also limits the resources for the opposition to the marriage. While much less common today and against the law, such child marriages still occur in Indii [Associated Press (1989)'cited in Benokraitis (1993)]. In 1981 [Associated Press (1981 cited in Eshleman, (1994)], an estimated 40,000 to 50,000 children were married over a single weekend in violation of a law banning such marriages. In this rura^ section of India these marriages occurred in keeping with centuries-old Hindu traditions. Children as young as a 2-year-old girl and an 8-year-old boy were ceremoniously married in a ritual that usually is kept secret from outsiders. It was presumably publicized as a reaction to a law banning child marriages that was trying to be implemented. Second, mate selection is controlled by kinship rules, which define a relativelv Chapter 9 /Mate Selection 253 small number of eligible spouses. For example, the Yaruros of Venezuela, a nomadic tribe of fisherman and hunters, is a society that restricts marriage to cross-cousins: That is, a man must marry the daughter of his mother's brother or the daughter of his father's sister. Incest taboos and ethnocentrism are employed to restrict the field of eligibles. Freeman (1974) observes that this practice fosters interfamilial solidarity by forcing marriage to people who live nearbv but in different communities. The Hottentots of southwest Africa are a group of seminomadic herders. They too, require cross-cousin marriage. But, unlike the Yaruro, the Hottentots are free to choose for themselves which cross-cousin to marry (Freeman, 1974). A third practice of mate selection is controlled by socially and physically isolating young people from potential mates. This makes it easier for parents to arrange the marriage of their children in that there is little likelihood that these children would have developed love attachments to conflict with their parents' wishes. In feudal Japan, the social contacts between members of the opposite sex were limited and were highly ritualized. They were permitted only in the presence of elders. This had the effect of minimizing informal and intimate social interaction. I shall return to a more in-depth analysis of this practice in feudal Japan a little later in this chapter. Fourth, love relationships are controlled by strict chaperonage by duennas or close relatives. Here again, young people are not permitted to be alone together or in intimate interaction. This practice has existed in Spain, Portugal, Italy, and in Latin America. It has also prevailed among recently arrived FTispanic immigrants to the United States. The play—later made into a movie—-West Side Stoiy, is a tragic love story that updates Romeo and Juliet to the sidewalks of New York City. It depicts the influence of family and friends on a Puerto-Rican-born young woman and her forbidden love for a young white-ethnic man. The clash of youth gangs, battles over turf, and the questioning of traditional family cultures are used vividly depict the power of romantic love. The fifth and final way in which love is controlled is typical in American culture. Although formally allowing individuals to choose their own marriage partners, parents control the field of eligibles through the influence of the informal contacts of young people. This is done through living in selected neighborhoods, asserting control over the schools that children attend, restricting guest lists to parties and informal gatherings, and making the children aware of their parents' ethnocentric biases relating to race, religion, ethnicity, social class, and so on. In the United States, individual motives play an important role in deciding the question of whom one should marry. The common assumption is that two people marry7 on the basis of love. However, the determination of eligible lovemates is influenced by the principle of preferential mating. Incest taboos preclude the eligibility of immediate kin. Frequently, the incest taboos extend to the first-cousin relationship, but there are no clan or other kinship structure restrictions. Rules of endogamy are expressed in ethnocentric beliefs that define "suitable" marriage partners to people of the same social class, religion, ethnic group, and race. The field of "suitable" partners is further limited to people of the same age group and to people who live nearby in the same neighborhood or community. Until recently, ethnocentric biases were supported by legal statutes in the most dramatic case—racial 254 Part III / Gender Roles, Courtship, and Marriage and the Family intermarriage. As late as 1967, almost twenty states still had antimiscegenaticz statutes, with penalties up to ten years imprisonment and fines up to S 1,000. In th:: year, the Supreme Court declared that such laws were unconstitutional. Although there has been some trend away from ethnocentric restrictions, the general pattern continues to be the marriage of people who share similar backgrounds, values, attitudes, and interests. Informal ethnocentric pressures, which stll characterize American mate-selection processes, help account for the fact that marriages outside these norms tend to have greater difficulty and more frequently end iz. divorce. The result is that although the field of eligibles can be the entire umvei opposite-sex population, it is in fact significantly narrower because of these endoea-mous practices. The choosing of one's spouse is ideally depicted as being solely within the province of the individual. Parents, friends, and others are normally not supposed t: interfere in the mate-selection process. In addition, it is felt that such interference is not effective and can even backfire. For example, The Fantastkks, a long-running contemporary play, uses this normative guideline as the central theme: Two father-scheme to keep their respective children apart in the hope that such interference wiľ have the opposite effect and bring them together. In many cases, parents are not informed or consulted by children about their prospective spouse either prior to or after the wedding. Although their formal input in the marital decision-making process is diminished, the parents have a strong indirect influence in the mate-selection process. By residing in selected areas and sending their children to selected schools, parents restrict the options of young people in forming friendships. Further, through parties and selective invitation lists and verbalizing their own ethnocentric biases, parents influence their children. By influencing the informal social contacts of their children, the parents indirectly control the mate-selection process. As William J. Goode states, "Since youngsters fall in love with whom they associate, control over informal relationships also controls substantially the focus of affection" (Goode, 1959:46). The following passage from Peter L. Berger's Invitation to Sociology: A Humanistic Perspective nicely conveys American mate-selection processes: In Western countries, and especially in America, it is assumed that men and women marry because they are in love. There is a broadly based popular mythology about the character of love as a violent, irresistible emotion that strikes where it will, a mystery that is the goal of most young people and often of the not-so-young as well. As soon as one investigates, however, which people actually many each other, one finds that the lightning-shaft of Cupid seems to be guided rather strongly within very definite channels of class, income, education, racial and religious background. . . . The suspicion begins to dawn on one that, most of the time, it is not so much the emotion of love that creates a certain kind of relationship, but that carefully predefined and often planned relationships eventually generate the desired emotion. In other words, when certain conditions are met or have been constructed, one allows oneself "to fall in love." (Berger, 1963:35) Chapter 9 /Mate Selection 255 In summary, where societies emphasize the importance of kinship lineage and its preservation—-and support this by establishing strong ties between family interests and economic and social interests—marriages are arranged by the couple's respective consanguineal families. On the other hand, where societies emphasize the importance of the conjugal relationship between husband and wife and deemphasize their obligations and responsibilities to the extended-family system, the choice of marriage partners is more or less left up to the individuals involved. ARRANGED MARRIAGES AND DOWRY IN INDIA Contemporary matchmaking patterns in India has fascinated Americans. However, juxtaposed with these often humorous—to Western sensibilities—accounts of the attempt to use modern matrimonial want ads in newspapers with traditional concerns for matching astrological signs and caste groups has been a concurrent darker and horrific story of mate selection processes. These are the too prevalent and tragic incidents of wife abuse and bride-burnings that have become known as dowry deaths. In this section I will discuss these contemporary phenomena. India has become an increasingly mobile, urban society. For the more highly educated, the centuries-old practice of arranging marriages has been transformed by modern technology. In New Delhi, on a typical Sunday, more than 1,500 "matrimonial" advertisements appear in the three largest newspapers. These ads are now appearing throughout India's urban centers and are placed primarily by affluent Hindi middle-class parents and grandparents and are designed to marry off their children. The typical ads detail the qualifications of the prospective groom's or bride's caste, education, income, and demands. The following ad is illustrative: "Beautiful, fair, slim, educated girl wanted for slim, 27 year old, 173cms respectable Punjabi Khatri project engineer. 2,500 [rupees] per month salary-plus perks." The salary would be about $215 U.S. dollars. (Fineman, 1985) The ads are not confined to Indians living in India but include those who have migrated elsewhere. The periodical India Abroad has classified ads appearing on a regular basis that seeks to matchmake globally (see Figure 9-1). For both men and women the appearance of matrimonial advertisements promoting their marital qualifications are justified in that they believe that the ads give them a wider choice of potential spouses. The matrimonial ads reflect the changing circumstances of modern times. As families migrate outside of the familiar social circles of the ancestral village to urban centers and to other countries, these ads have replaced the traditional matchmaker, socially connected relatives, and parental networks. While there has been an upsurge in Westernized love matches, the prevalent pattern are arranged marriages. They, however, have been tempered by the final veto power of the children, and prior to the marriage, children are allowed to date their future spouses between the engagement and the marriage (Moore, 1994). 256 Part III / Gender Roles, Courtship, anďMairiage ani the Family INDIA ABROAD CI MATRIMONIAL Matrimonial — Female New York baaed physician sister invites correspondence from professionals for vary attractive, vegetarian Rafput Doctor sister 23, merit scholar Intern Lady Hard Inge Delhi, family of physicians. No bars. Reply biodata, photograph. Gujarat! Charotar Palel parents invito correspondence trom professionals (or daughter, UÄ educated, citizen, protoaalorv aliy employed. 24,5'I". Please correspond with returnable photograph and biodata to: Proposal Invited from compatible, handsome professional for beautiful, talented, Bengali Hindu girl, 25, US raised, BS, professional, employed. No bars. Match for convent educated, pretty, smart, Gujarat i girl, 27 yrs., 5', BA, L.L.B.. from Bombay, currently visiting USA. Punjab) Brahmin parent» Imrtle cor-mtpandinca fot ttwrir highly cultured «ltd axtiwrwly beautiful, US ctlt-Eon daughter, 5'ľ, 32 y*w*. physician. Innocent dtwsce«. Boy must be Punjabi, broadmlnded and highly educated trom respectable (»mlly CLASSIFIED Malrinwoid—FcTuk fChu-i Weil placed Indian parents Invito corresponds nee for their attractive 25 year old daughter, U.S. citizen, complfltino graduate school, has infant daughter. No bars. JJ F*"1- I5T(^.- drwofWl mW*«» puBafeb*. Mi.., A.D. pri [rxfea« far Nubtc *»**, BrtAa MTVfta Oifrr^aKif^t from. OwjuH HtMkU p™*CH*caa-i IDT ■CUkCUVc lBÉ(fL pihtr. JS. kAHd fr*d*n vd pKw nut. ■ ii*nHJiinn fpiTufl m**il ifmnüp« *«- Pnrtarr iimm tie< aarirappudrfc frvqwrll mod. frtricH^, GMftrpq r»dcn-fl, «Ml for m» D.Aitb.. *■!■»■■ U.SiA «»- Send rati Broth* tBťii oonOfpcwaCwe hon hon-Hahdi lytr aw* *» um JO. nU. *wr 39, °* cí- ■ŕdkof. luaJj- b*ck(nmd, cooipktWI mníencj. PimnitiJKfllcJaiGiJfiiii Pime K*d úr*uji w*fl ItflirotWť pJKUOtnph______________N ťotTRponVacr invHed b? dn^neJ ptofrran»! oí Irrfun boCtpOiod, M. if. 1+4K inoj*, mxry DdcreMi EditoU GUAnq racmOr iľuliI. *I yem ůtd. **ü «nkd Ei^a«*f. S"9L". » children nwUfi CLÜCU^ajah-HJ fcí BUDnurAül lííítJOMhV- (UHnafrk pbo«D muH he______________* Forty ^£H old n-Jc iuv|i 6m. 17J ■»., Gfwa drf, «Ü eMfcl-*^-Ulf ■Ml-1. Call: _________1 Gejuwi Jü ^--—~—"r*-. Kí« . Ü.B., M B.A., JI. ST" ifProO ťocrqpffcTT frpffl G.j—en.*.-—! phi. pho-x -rar«. C*a. ___„____. __, P«e BKUTHi. ~^i pi»t«l bBkily No o>otoppi, Ffcotifric*. IwdAK Hir4i«4ik. íiif- M ■-A - MakimJriiua llMHaiinn. Cr«b Cud feUf: iafedUr«. .w^i^w*■ t*p» —J lot^j^ fafŕiiiinl I laU. tvr. M.D. or ácHtl *kV i^í* A« c*- PTflcanhfOUT Ln.fcjJIJll ■■ U J «t Judit. niSK wr« wict bH ptÄwl« »ad mu- n*irfcůlc phq*atr»pti B 4 aay-^pfr______________ D MalriiiHHÚfll—Malt • ■toVto biodjaf»_______________________ Hirne** brodw i««« Dcnripoivict« Írom bcbrfifiá profuuoW« lor huM*o«c, IT". 33 )hi old bujfVr^ MS EläTTKid tnpnsfiA|. USA. CMJTChdf dOH( r*t> compwif«. »barUnr „M. vrtU -onucctfaj Pua^rin Unhnun tvut^ CjJI: v «CBd ECOMOKIUI. «i. Fre*ř***o—Í ^ Ďto«. Hľb MftJctf.nd.aa;. faint, mi nrimB.mil. tkán. Soma indao Udr <"Q> H.45.í*.S™iphiÄ rMptma WH» GrcV* Cwd i*| US Ufp^l aaUm-W ittaCW. Eafff. MBA. CPA. rtC ] fof KöJ-* K*J*trti»r*w¥*Prf 30. J6'". 140 Km. feA fiSBA. MBA •*-< MAC fcirott trofa USbwu^. C*H; i rn—l. ■vaWtTMi. ■■afcfe. [hAitaljHAn 1 ■ďWď «-ä fed M ■CCCBVJtBhcd, -0**ÜOUa. triKto«« M« C*™<— »v, 34. VIO" E^rtor.MBA-aabA, RfoW «i* přMtv Ke«obb both W 31 rl.. Cx^iu Jl™' i"4 . )30tU..tiiÉMiLlCMiiPil..A-.OMai m5. Garg;uij ]99?. drey have other daughters for fear that they will Morgan, 1984a; O'Kelly and Carney, 1986; Sharma, not be able to marry them off. 1980 MATE SELECTION IN FEUDAL AND CONTEMPORARY JAPAN Japan is a society that historically has permitted a wide range of marital eligibles. But the actual choice, especially in the past, was determined by the family, not the marrying person. In this section I will provide an overview of the historical changes that have occurred in Japan. Linton Freeman (1974) in his study of feudal Japan (Tbku-gawa Japan) in the eighteenth century, observed that it was divided into local small duchies, each ruled by a lord and supported by an army of knights {samurai). Governing the society was a hereditary military leader, with the emperor having little importance. As in most feudal societies, there was a clearly delineated social-class system, with each class restricted to designated dwellings, styles of clothing, food, and so on. The family in feudal Japan was at the heart of an individual's activities. The family was ruled by a patriarch with the assistance of a family council, which included most of the mature males and the old women in the family. The extended family included the patriarch's wife, all his sons and their wives and children, his unmarried daughters, younger brothers and their wives and children, and finally the servants. As head of the family, the patriarch's approval was required for marriages and divorces, for adoptions, and for the expulsion of recalcitrant members. He was responsible for the family's fulfillment of its obligations to the state. Professor Kawishima, a Japanese social scientist, observes the following: As a means of emphasizing through external impressions the mental attitude of filial obedience, the head of a family (generally the father) enjoys markedly privileged treatment in everyday life. The family head does not do with his own hands even trifling things—or rather is prohibited from doing such