Chapter 8: C \ where it stated that '[i]n asystem of tendering, competition is of the essence. If the tenders submitted by those taking part are not the result of individual economic calculation, but of knowledge of the tenders by other participants or of concertation with them, competit10ll is prevented, or at least distorted or restricted'.210 In Building and construction i„ fa Netherlands,1" the Commission condemned the rules and regulations of the umbrella assnq-ation of the federations of Dutch builders and contractors (SPO) which provided, among other things, for exchanges of information prior to tendering and for collusion on price ten ders for building and construction contracts. Moreover, it shared the demand side of the mar ket between members through the prior designation of successful tendering undertakings and the protection of enrided undertakings. The CFI, which rejected the appeal by the undertakings, stated that concertation by contractors regarding the manner in which they intend responding to an invitation for tender is incompatible with article 81 (1) of the Treaty, even if the invitation sets unreasonable conditions. It is for each contractor to determine independently what it regards as reasonable or unreasonable and to conduct himself accordingly'2" In Pre-insuktedpipes, the members of the cartel had set up asystem through which they could allocate individual projects between themselves by manipulating bidding procedures so that they could decide in advance which producer would be awarded the contract.213 In Raw Tobacco Italy, the processors of tobacco coordinated their conduct in respect of the bids placed at public auctions organised for the purchase of tobacco by the Italian monopoly ATI.214 8.43 Sharing sources of supply Cartel participants may also agree to share out their sources of supply. In Raw Tobacco Spain, the four Spanish processors of raw tobacco agreed each year on the quantities of each variety of raw tobacco that each of them would undertake to purchase from the group of producers.z,s In Raw Tobacco Italy, the tobacco processors also allocated to themselves suppliers and quantities to be purchased.216 (d) Co-ordinated Boycotts, Bans on Imports, Concerted Refusal to Deal 8.44 Carteitists may also agree upon concerted action to prevent the entry of new competitors to the market or upon retaliatory measures against undertakings refusing to comply with their restrictive arrangements. 8.45 Keeping competitors away from the cartel's market In several cases, the Commission has condemned coordinated measures designed to keep competitors away from the market In Meldoc, a particularly serious dimension of the cartel was that it was aimed at protecting 2'o [1973]OJL140/17,28. 2" [1992]OJL92/l. ™ CvxT-29192 SPO and others v Commission [1995] ECRII-289, para 119. 2« [1999] OJL24/1. The cartel members had agreed that the other producers would submit higher öfters in the tendering procedure. In return, unsuccessful bidders would be granted the opportunity to participate in the project as subcontractors. There was also another 'compensation system' which corrected departures from the quota if the selected producer railed to win the bid. Likewise, a monitoring system was set up for the cases where a producer undercut the allocated 'favourite', and would be called to account and pressurised to withdraw its bid or to increase its price to allow the favourite win. z<4 Decision of 20 October 2005 (full text of the decision available on DG COMP's web site), paras 126, 150,240. 2" Decision of 20 October 2004 (full text of the decision available on DG COMP's web site), para 67- *gy of Cartel Arrangements and Common Features of Collusion . putch market by blocking imports of cheaper milk from Belgium and Germany, thereby , „jng a clearly adverse effect on consumer interests and obstructing the achievement of one of r he most fundamental objectives of the Treaty, the integration of the economies of the Member Crates.217 A focus on import restrictions was also an important aspect of the cartel agreements in -Welded Steel Mesh. Here, a series of agreements between French producers and producers from Italy! Germany and Belgium who traditionally exported to France included terms setting quo-for import into France. These restrictions on the volume of foreign deliveries to the French market made it possible to enter into a price agreement; the prices charged on the French mar-ÍÍP ket were sec at a level far higher than the average in other Community countries, without this producing an increase in imports as would normally be expected.218 In Luxembourg Brewers, the cartel agreemenrwas intended to keep foreign brewers out of Luxembourg,2'9 In French Beefůie Commission condemned an agreement entered into by farmers' and slaughterers' federations, which had as its object a temporary commitment to suspend all imports of beef.220 Placing certain competitors at a competitive disadvantage Agreements may also be 8.46 reached in order to oblige other parties to adopt a given behaviour, or to place downstream operators at a competitive disadvantage. In Fedetab22^ the Commission condemned the agreement between Belgian and Luxembourg producers of manufactured tobacco not to supply several large distribution firms which did not stock a minimum range of brands. In Electrical and Mechanical Carbon and Graphite Products, cartel participants sold 'rough' carbon blocks in addition to their finished products and found themselves in competition on the downstream market with 'cutters', who bought the rough carbon blocks from them and transformed them into finished products. In order to limit competition from these cutters, the cartel had agreed to keep the cutters in a position of competitive disadvantage by selling the carbon blocks to them at an artificially high price.222 Boycott of reluctant undertakings Action may also be taken to boycott undertakings 8.47 showing reluctance to comply with the collusive arrangements, in Cement, cartel members agreed upon a collective response to what was perceived as the problem posed by the Greek producers, whose conduct was destabilising the cement industry. A 'stick and carrot' approach was devised in order to 'persuade' them to cooperate. The short term punitive actions considered, called 'stick actions', were aimed at defending European domestic markets.223 '" [1986] OJL348/50, para 82. m [1989] OJfL260/I, para 159. 2,9 [2002] OJ L253/21. In this case, a common defensive mechanism was instituted whereby the parties agreed to consult each other first if a foreign brewer attempted to negotiate asupply contract with one of their tied oudets. Priority would then be allocated to one of the cartel participants, in an attempt to keep the out-lpt as a customer. If that party succeeded in negotiating a new contract with the oudet.it was obliged to compensate the party which had lost the outlet by transfetring an equivalent outlet to him. Other clauses allowed for the exclusion from the cartel of any patty which cooperated with a foreign brewer or distributed its beer. 220 £2003]OJL209/12,para38. 221 [1978]OJL224/29. m [2004] OJL125/45 (full text of the decision available on DG COMP s web site), paras 154—156. 173 [1994] OJ L343/1, para 25(4). The 'stick' actions consisted of resorting, inter alia, to; administrative obstacles; quality standards; action by associations; penalising of customers purchasing imported cement; attacks on the export matkets of the producers who were destabilising the market by taking the place of those producers in various countries or by making Greek exports unprofitable; boycotts of shipping lines controlled by the producers who were destabilising the market; adoption of 'guerilla' tactics in the Greek market; and «eking the assistance of international banks to 'convince' the recalcitrant producers to cooperate. 771 Chapter 8: Cartels 8.48 In Pre-insulatedPipes, the Commission found that the cartel participants had devised anii'":$ enforced a sophisticated strategy to eliminate a competitor who had refused to participate^ in their bid-rigging scheme. The award to this undertaking of the largest contract in '^ Germany for ten years sparked off a particularly violent reaction, and a collective boyCOM. 'J\ of this undertaking was instigated. The cartel decided to cease any supply to this undertak ■■ ingand its subcontractors.22'' :J (e) Exchange of Commercially Sensitive Information ,; Under normal competitive conditions, information regarding, for example, capacity, use0f capacity, production levels, customers, prices charged and conditions applied to customers, would not be exchanged between competitors. However, the exchange of such commercially sensitive information usually does take place within cartels, as a means to prepare, implement or monitor the restrictive agreement^) or arrangements. The question is whether such exchanges of information, where they are connected to an identified infringement, are also separately caught by the prohibition of Article 81 EC, and thetefote whether such exchanges are also caught when they take place in complete isolation, ie in the absence of any additional restrictive arrangements. 8.49 A constituent of the 'carteí offence' The exchange of commercially sensitive information is often ancillary to othetper se violations of Article 81 EC, such as price fixing, or market-sharing. It is thus not generally considered separately by the Commission, in that evidence of the exchange of confidential information is used to provide additional proof of the overall cartel arrangements, and the Commission finds a single cartel infringement (implicidy) including the exchange of confidential business information. In such instances, the exchange of information is found to have taken place either by way of preparation and implementation or for the monitoring of the cartel arrangements, and with the same object as was identified for the main (perse) infringement. It is worth noting, however, that the Commission has in many cases singled our exchanges of information as a distinct part of the perse infringement, thereby considering them not merely as a 'facilitating' device but as a separate constitutive element of the 'cartel offence'.225 8.50 A 'cartel offence' in its own right? An important issue, however, is whether the exchange of business sensitive information may constitute an infringement of Article 81 EC on a stand-alone basis. On appeal in Steel Beams, the CFI concluded that, contrary to the Commission's contention during the Court proceedings, the 'information exchange systems' referred to in the decision had been considered by the Commission as separate infringements of Article 65(1) ECSC.226 The CFI subsequently considered that such systems 224 [1999] OJL24/1, paras 98-107. 225 This was the case, for instance, in Cartonboard [1994] OJL243/1, paras 61-64, 105-106 and 134; Seamless SteelTubes [2003] OJL140/1, para 153, third indent; BelgianBeer [2003] OJL200/I, pata 265; Zinc Phosphate [2003] OJ LI53/1, para 215; Methionine [2003] OJ L255/I, para 214; Methylglucamine [2004) OJ L38/18, pata 184; Food Flavour Enhancers [2004] OJ L75/1, para 172; Thread, (para 282) and Industrial Bags (paras 521-523). «6 CaseT-l4l/94 Thyssen Stahl v Commission [1999] ECR11-347, paras 379-392. In Steel Beams, the Commission had described at length systems of exchange of confidential information, but claimed on appeal before the CFI that it had considered that the disputed information systems did not constitute a separate infringement of Art 65(1) ECSC but formed part of wider infringements consisting, in particular, of price-fixing and market-sharing agreements. The Commission argued that the exchange of information infringed Art 65(1) ECSC insofar as the exchange made it easier fot those other infringements to be committed. 772 B. Typology of Cartel Arrangements and Common Features of Collusion fe- for the exchange of (confidential) information could indeed be regarded having the restricts rion of competition as their object.227 This was confirmed on appeal by the ECJ.22B It seems I ■ that the Commission has now fully embraced the idea that information exchanges can be }■■■. consideredjWie infringements. In Plasterboard, the Commission regarded the exchange of ;;'.". confidential information as the essential element of the 'cartel offence'. Its finding of a ;;';■. pgf sg infringement of Article 81 EC was based mostly on the existence of several exchanges 'ľ-., of confidential business information. The Commission concluded that there had existed '■': 'between 1992 and 1998 at least in the four major European plasterboard markets a complex, ■: continuous agreement having as its object the restriction of competition'.229 Interestingly, the r Commission pointed out that the parties had at certain times knowingly exchanged incorrect information, which confirmed that the exchange of information had had a restrictive ■ object as it was actually used as a monitoring mechanism.230 Conclusion In answering the question of whether the concerted practice of information 8.51 exchange can be illegal in itself, the first issue is therefore to see whether the exchange of information can be demonstrated to have as its object the restriction of competition.231 If such an object cannot be demonstrated, then other relevant factors may need to be considered. 227 The CFI stated in particular that 'the information which the undertakings received under the arrangements in question was capable of appreciably influencing their conduct, by reason of the fact that each undertaking knew that it was being kept under close surveillance by its competitors and that it could, if necessary, react to the conduct of its competitors, on the basis of considerably more recent and accurate data than those available by other means' and that 'data, indicating the very recent market shares of participants and not publicly available, are by their very nature confidential data, as confirmed by the fact that interested undertakings could receive rhe data distributed by the secretariat only on a reciprocal basis' (para403). The CFI concluded that 'the information exchange systems in question appreciably reduced the decision-making independence of the patticipating producers by substituting practical cooperation between them for the normal risks of competition' (para 406). "s Case C-194/1999 P Thyssen StahlAGv Commission [2003] ECR 1-10821, paras 59-90. "» [2005] OJ LI 66/8 (full text of the decision available on DG COMP's web site), para 434. The Commission stated in particular at paras 449 and 450 that 'an information exchange constitutes per se an infringement of Article 61(1} EC if the requirement of independence according to which each trader must determine independently his Conducton the market is undermined as a result. This requirement of independence will without a doubt be affected if the exchange takes place in a highly concentrated market and if it reduces the risk of uncertainty for the trader. These two conditions are manifestly met in the present case inasmuch as the market is an oligopolistic one and the uncertainty has disappeared since the patties agreed [...] to put an end to the aggression reigning on the market, this wish being manifested, moreover, on a number of occasions on the relevant markets. The Commission considers therefore that the system constitutes an infringement of Article 81(1) EC. 230 The Commission stated at para 452 that'[tjhis body of evidence permits the Commission to assert that the [...] agreement concerning the exchange of information [...] was intended to enable participants thetein to monitor the conduct of their competitors at least on the relevant markets and constitutes a manifestation of the common wish of the parties to restrict competition on the plasterboard market in the four major European markets. In so doing, the Commission characterises the agreement as restrictive or competition within the meaning of Article 81(1) EC, being a particular manifestation of the complex, continuous agreement having as its object the restriction of competition on the plasterboard market at least in the four major European markets'. 231 In Steel Beams [1994] OJ LI 16/1, the Commission had described at length, in its decision, systems of exchange of confidential information, but claimed on appeal before the CFI that it had considered that the disputed information systems did not constitute a separate infringement of Art 65(1) ECSC but formed part of wider infringements consisting, in particular, in price-fixing and market-sharing agreements. The Commission argued that the exchange of information thus infringed Art 65(1) ECSC insofar as the exchange made it easier for those other infringements to be committed. See C-194/1999 P Thyssen Stahl AG v Commission [2003] ECRI-10821 para384. Chapter 8: Cartels These are, inter alia: the nature of the information exchanged, the level of aggregation and tht age of the data, and the concentration of the industry, The Commission has accepted that depending on an examination of the individual case, exchange of information schemes can be held to be lawful.232 It may indeed be legitimate for companies to pool information about the market in which they operate, as a certain degree of transparency may lead to a more e£H cient functioning of the market. The CFI confirmed the validity of this approach ia John Deere v Commission.133 That said, and as mentioned above, exchanges of information that create an artificial level of transparency and thus a reduction in the uncertainty about com petitors' behaviour in the market are generally considered anti-competitive. For a detailed analysis of the compatibility of exchange of information schemes with EC competition law see Chapter 7 of this book, at paras 7.355 and following. (f) The Problem of Tacit Collusion' 8.52 Can economic evidence of the parallel conduct of certain undertakings in the market, in the absence of any proof of collusion, enable the Commission to determine the existence of a 'cartel' prohibited under Article 81 ?234 8.53 The theory of tacit collusion According to economic theory, it is possible for firms in an oligopolistic market to tend towards a monopoly-type price equilibrium in the absence of any kind of explicit collusion. Owing to the interdependence that characrerises firms in an oligopolistic context, where each market operator takes into account the anticipated reaction of its competitors for the purpose of determining its own market strategy, firms may de facto find that they are coordinating their market behaviour without engaging in any form of consultation. What is thus described by economic literature as 'tacit collusion' consists of each undertaking aligning its commercial behaviour with the conduct of the price leader (or of the first mover) by imposing prices increases as soon as the latter does so. 8-54 Does tacit collusion amount to cartel behaviour? The question of whether tacit collusion amounts to cartel behaviour, ie whether it constitutes a per se infringement of Article 81 EC, raises complex issues that still remain somewhat unresolved today. The notion of concerted 23> Steel Beams [1994] 0] LI 16/1. The Commission has however chosen not to address these within the context of the Guidelines on horizontal cooperation agreements (sec Commission Guidelines on theapplica bility of Arc 81 of the ECTreaty to horizontal cooperation agreements, [2001] OJC3/2, para 10). Interestingly, the Commission stated that che Guidelines are 'only concerned with chose types of cooperation which polen dally generate efficiency gains', implying that this is not the case for exchange of information schemes. J" CaseT-35/92/oAn Deere v Commission [1994] ECR11-957. The CFI found at para 51 chat on a truly competitive market transparency between ccaders is in principle likely to lead to the intensification of competition becween suppliers, since in such a situation, the fe.ee thac a trader takes inco account information made available to him in order to adjust his conduct on the market is not likely, having regard co the atomized nature of che supply, co reduce or remove for che other traders any uncertainty about the foreseeable nature of its competitors' conduct'. 23* This question is of a different nature from the question whether, in the absence of material evidence of an agreement that is restrictive in object or of a concerced practice, evidence of an anticompetitive intention can be deduced from economic evidence of parallel conduce in the market. The laccer question relates to the burden of proof that the Commission must discharge to establish the existence of a common will to restrict competition. As to the former question, it raises the issue whether, in cetcain market conditions, it is possible fot the Commission to conclude that undertakings have engaged in illegal behaviour in respect of cheir ability to jointly restrict competition, by tacitly colluding, ie by aligning their behaviour with their competitors by anticipating and/or following their behaviour. 774 B. Typology of Cartel Arrangements and Com mou Features of Co Huston ractice as defined by case law does indeed seem very close to the notion of'tacit collusion, u that tne íu'mnient of the corresponding test ('conscious substitution of practical cooperation between undertakings for the risks of competition') does not seem to require much evidence of explicit coordination. However, It seems that a finding of concerted practices nevertheless requires an effective breach of the obligation for a firm to determine its market behaviour independently that must go beyond mere tacit collusion. Indeed, the Court in Suiker Unie, having reiterated that each economic operator must 8.55 independently determine the policy which it intends to adopt in the market, stated that 'this requirement of independence does not deprive economic operators of the right to adapt themselves intelligently to the existing and anticipated conduct of their competitors'. The Court went on to confirm that 'it does however strictly preclude any direct or indirect contact between such operators, the object or effect whereof is either to influence the conduct on the market of an actual or potential competitor or to disclose to such a competitor the course of conduct which they themselves have decided to adopt or contemplate adopting in the market'.235 The reference to the term contact' (whether indirect or not) seems to rule out the possibility that the notion of concerted practice includes 'tacit collusion. In its Wood Pulp II judgment, the ECJ gave additional useful indications as to the value of 8.56 economic evidence for the purpose of establishing cartel behaviour. In Wood Pulp,l3B the Commission had found that several producers had engaged in unlawful behaviour which, the Commission submitted, was essentially established by the fact that the firms' quarterly price announcements were near-simultaneous and identical. On appeal, the Court annulled the Commission decision on the grounds that the latter had not established an infringement of Article 81 EC to the required legal standard.237 The Court stated on this occasion that parallel conduct could not be regarded as furnishing proof of concertation unless that collusion constituted the only plausible explanation for such conduct, recalling the right of economic operators to adapt themselves intelligently to the existing and anticipated conduct of their competitors.23a Conclusion In the light of the case law discussed above, it seems that tacit collusion can- 8.57 not, as such, be regarded as cartel behaviour. The Community judicature seems ready to accept, albeit under extremely strict conditions (which, it is submitted, are extremely difficult for the Commission to satisfy), that economic evidence may be resorted to in order to establish that prior concertation tookplace between competitors, in cases where that cannot as Joined Cases 40-48, 50, 54-56, 111 and 113-114/73 Suiker Unie and Others v Commission [1975] ECR 1663, paras 173-174. a* [198530JL85/1. 237 Since che Commission had no documents which directly established the existence of collusion between the producers concerned, the Court stated thac it was 'necessary to ascertain whether the syscem of quarterly price announcements, the simultaneity ot near-simultaneity of the price announcements and che parallelism of price announcements [...] constitute^] a firm, precise and consistent body of evidence of prior concertation' (Joined cases C-89/85, C-104/85, C-114/85, &116/85, C-117/85 and C-125/85 to C-129/85 A. Abistrom Osakeyhtiö and others v Commission [1993] ECR 1-1307, para 70). i3a To discharge the burden of proof of cartel conduct, the Commission was required to establish, 'caking account of the natute of the products, the size and thenumber of che undertakings and the volume of the market in question that the alleged parallel conduct of che undertakings could not be explained otherwise than by concertation'. The Court found that the Commission had failed to do this (paras 71 and 72). 775 Chapter 8: Cartels be established through material evidence of actual contacts. But one should remain carefoj''''' not to interpret the case law as implying that 'tacit collusion' can be legally qualified asa ca"'^ tel behaviour. The Wood Pulp //judgment addresses the question of the standard of pro c-h applicable to the demonstration of classical cartel behaviour, rather than the possibility of'-'? tacit collusion per se being caught under Article 81 EC. If the Commission is not able tn'; establish to the required standard that contacts between competitors have taken place it -seems that parallel conduct in the market will not be deemed unlawful, as uncertainty-' about the future conduct of each undertaking in the market is preserved. This is so, even if ■ economic theory might suggest that the conditions for tacit cootdinatíon do exist. (2) Common Features of Collusion 8.58 Analysis of Commission decisions regarding cartels reveals that collusive schemes have many common operational features. Classic patterns of cartels concern their establishment, organisational aspects and the manner in which collusion is conducted on a day-to-day basis. (a) Factors Conducive to the Establishment of Cartels Cartels will often develop in markets which have a number of characteristics that are favourable to collusion. A specific event affecting the market will generally convince cartel instigators that concerted reaction is needed. In turn they will often convince others to . engage in collusion, thereby acting as a catalyst. Oligopolistic markets Collusion is made easier in oligopolistic markets. In Italian Flat Glass II, the Commission noted that the flat-glass market was dominated by a tight ofigop-oly.239 Similar features can be found in Alloy Surcharge,2*0 Belgian Beer2A} and Zinc Phosphate, where the five cartel members controlled, in spite of their small size, 90 per cent of the EEA market.*42 In French Beer, a non-aggression pact was made between the two main market players who agreed that neither of them should become dominant.243 Cartels have sometimes been formed after a process of intense concentration has taken place, as in Carbonless Paper2** or Plasterboard245 They may nevertheless involve a relatively high number of players. This is workable in homogeneous product markets, in particular when strongly established trade associations are able to ensure adequate coordination, as in Cartonboard 2i6 or Cement26,1 8.61 Collusive business values and established communication channels Sector-specific values may result in operators looking upon the control of competition between them in a 8.59 8.60 ** [1989] O} 133144, para 12. 240 [1998] OJ LlOO/55. The stainless steel market was described as a highly concentrated market. 241 [2003] OJ L140/1. The cartel was set up by the two main actors in the market, who together controlled over 70% of the entire market. i« [2003JOJL153/1. 2« [2005] OJ L184/57 (full text of the decision available on DG COMP s web site). 2U [2004] OJ LI I5/I. The Commission observed that the production of carbonless papers in Europe bad become i ncreasingly dominated by a relatively small number of major producers as smaller suppl iers had withd rawn from the market. At the time of the infringement, the cartel members controlled between 85 and 90% of the EEA market for carbonless paper, with the four biggest players controlling around 60% of the market (paras 14-16). 2AS [2005] OJ L166/8 (full text of the decision available on DG COMP's web site), paras 48-51. 2« [1994]OJL243/I. "> [1994]OJL343/l. ' t B. Typology of Cartel Arrangements and Common Features of Collusion «ftive way- Such values may be diffuse, but have been clearly exposed in certain carrel cases, ich &$ Agreements between manufacturers of glass containers1** or Building and Construction dustry if the Netherlands.249 The Austrian Banks cartel is probably one of the best ill ustra-nris of the influence of specific business values on cartel conduct. In a sector long charac-rised by a very high level of public ownership and considerable oversupply, market players cartel agreements (the 'Lombard club') as a welcome means to combat 'destructive, [t-throat competition, or free competition, as it might simply be termed.350 Established communication channels between competitors may also be conducive to cartel behaviour. This may result from the existence of long established and carefully structured trade associations (Cartonboard,251 Cement)252 from a (legitimate) regulatory framework providing 0pp0rtunities for discussions between competitors (Belgian Beer),2S3 or simply from privi-■;" wed personal contacts between individuals (Fine Art Auction Houses).254 - Exogenous triggering events Cartels may simply arise from a desire to extract supra 8.62 competitive profits but they are often triggered by an exogenous event resulting in con-. certed response from the industry. The Quinine cartel was formed when the suppliers of this substance (used for producing medicines against Malaria) were faced with a situation of considerable oversupply following the end of the Second "World War.255 In European Sugar Industry,256 the cartel was set up as a concerted attempt to neutralise the effects of the creation of a European common market for sugar. In BNIC, the cartel of cognac producers was triggered by the severe imbalance of supply and demand resulting from the breaking out of the oil crisis in 1973, as 80 per cent of the sales of this luxury good were «» [1974] OJ L160/1. The 'International Fair Trade Practice Rules Administration' (IFTRA) had established a considerable number of rules to be applied by European manufacturers of glass containers which qualified and prohibited as 'unfair practices' conduct that was really just competitive behaviour. MS [1992] OJ L92/1. The trade association, SPO, which gathered 28 associations of undertakings representing over 4,000 members of the building sector in the Netherlands, had adopted a 'Code of Honour' and its object was 'to promote and administer orderly competition, to prevent improper conduct in price tendering and to promote the formation of economically-justified prices' (paras 3, 12,47—48). 250 [2004] OJ L56/1. Episodes of more or less unrestricted competition used to be described by the banks as 'hyperactivity' and bank charges were seen in this context, not so much as a factor of competition, but more as 'a joint earnings opportunity', to the detriment of customers. Despite repeated warnings, before the accession of Austria to the EC, that the system would be deemed illegal, banks did not terminate their agreements and the Lombard Club remained in existence, as the banks considered that cartels 'had always been part' of banking and they therefore did not in the least intend to change this now simply because of the applicability of European antitrust law (paras 6,37)-»' [1994JOJL243/1. ™ fl994]OJ 1343/1. "3 Í2003JOJL140/1. ** [2005] OJ L200/92 (full text of the decision available on DG COMP's web site). Such factors explain why recidivism is not rare. Several undertakings have been condemned repeatedly on the basis of the same type offsets. This may also explain the phenomenon of'contamination' from one product market to a neighbouring one. Thus, links can be established between the Graphite Electrodes, Specialty Graphite and Electrical and Mechanical Carbon and Graphite Products cartels, between the Amino Acid and Food Flavour Enhancers cartels, and between the Citric Acid [2002] OJ L239/18 and Sodium Gluconate cartels. KS [1969] OJL192/5.NewpIantationsofcinchoma had been established in Africa and Asia, resulting in a strong rise in the supply of bark and the situation became even more critical when the US government decided to dispose, at auction, of very large stocks accumulated over the previous years- The producers reacted by agreeing on the price of bark, allocating between themselves purchases of the US stocks, prorecrtng their respective domestic markets and sriaringout others. 256 [I973IOJL140/17. Chapter 8: Carrels destined for export."7 In Steel Beams, the cartel resulted partly from a desire to follow uD on the anti-crisis measures initiated and operated by the Commission in the 1980s, which came to an end in 1988.258 In Ferry Operators—-Currency surcharges^ Channel ferry com-panies colluded in response to the devaluation of the pound in September 1992. Similar examples can be found in Alloy Surcharge,250 French Beef 261 and Raw Tobacco Spain.151 The determining role of instigators Particular instigators often play a determining role in the formation of cartels. In Zinc Producer Group, the Commission noted that 'the initiative [. . .] came from the Canadian and Anglo-Australian zinc companies, whilst the Continental European companies joined only after some hesitation 2S3 In PVCII, the cartel originated in a collusive plan formulated at ICI's, and the discussions and consultations which followed.26* In Pre-insulated Pipes, the Commission found that ABB, viewing the price-cutting policies of its competitors as 'irresponsible' in view of the weak state of che market, initiated a series of meetings with competitors in order to find a 'solution'.265 Amino Acidsi6e is also illustrative of typical instigator behaviour. In 1989, ADM decided to start producing lysine when it became aware that two other undertakings were about to set up production facilities in North America. ADM's production facilities for lysine doubled the worlds capacity and it was known that the company had strong financial means and access to cheap raw materials. ADM sent signals to the incumbent producers that, though it intended to be a big player in the lysine market, it would prefer coordination to price war. In order to convince the incumbent producers of the seriousness of its intentions and the penalties of not agreeing, ADM granted its competitors the opportunity to inspect its production plant, and commenced significant sales at low prices. This caused the incumbent producers to drastically lower their prices in an attempt to keep market shares. They finally agreed to cooperate with ADM. 257 [1982] OJ L379/1- The same phenomenon can be observed in Fine Arts Auction Houses, where the cartel was formed at a time when the international art market was undergoing a period of recession, in the context of the economic downturn of the early 1990s (see para 78). »a [1994]OJLll671,para308. iss [199710JL26/23. 160 [1998] OJL100/55. The cartel was triggered by a surge in the price of nickel, an important component of stainless steel, at a time when the price for alloys and stainless had fallen sharply (see para 20). 261 [2003] OJL209/12. The defensive carte! was triggered by a sharp fall in the slaughterhouse entry prices that farmers were receiving for cattle, reaching levels that were even lower than during the second outbreak of the 'mad cow' crisis, despite the Community adjustment measures (see paia 184). 262 Decision of 20 October 2002 (full text of the decision available on DG COMP's web site). The agreement between the tobacco processors on maximum prices for the purchase of tobacco leaves resulted from the opening of this activity to competition. Until 1990, one public company had held a legal monopoly over the processing of raw tobacco in Spain and had negotiated the purchase price. In the mid-90s, three new players entered the market, triggering a rise in the average buying price and placing Spanish tobacco at a competitive disadvantage on export markets. The processors began discussions on the setting of a maximum purchase price'to avoid price escalation' (see para 84). *« [I984]OJL220/27,paraI5. 264 [1994] OJL239/14. Two planning documents amounting to a blueprint for the cartel were found at ICI, the first proposing a new framework of meetings to administer a revised quota system and price fixing scheme, and the second recording the generally favourable reaction of other producers to the ICI proposals. 2« [1999] OJL24/1, para 30. 2« [2001JOJL152/24. 778 B- TyP0--