NOTICE: This material may be protected by Copyright «W.>«• Law^Title 17' us Code) O UM trr U another concept that needs definition; Daily andEhrlich<1992:761-771)explicjuc it in the most effective way—their ecologist's definition (p. 761) of carrying capacity is: "the maximal population size of a given species thai an area can support without reducing its ability to support the same species in the future.'' But for humans, CC must be disaggregated into Biophysical CC and Social CC, parallel to the distinction between ES and SS Our definition thus hinges on distinguishing between growth and development. According to Bourros-Qhali (1994:1) development is a "fundamental human tight" that requires inter alia democracy and good governance. "Economic growth is the engine of development.... sustai ned economic growth." This definition does not distinguish between the different concepts of growth and development While development can and should go on indefinitely for all nations, throughput growth cannot. Sustainability will be achieved only when development supplants growth. Acknowledging the finite nature of our planet, ''sustainable growth" is a bad oxymoron (Daly 1991). Recent emphases on such topics as social development, economic development, development with equity, and development and basic needs suggests that "development" could become so vague as to require a sanctifying adjective. These topics should be carefully distinguished and defined anew by others; that is a challenge for development specialists, not for environmentalists. The priorities of development are usually said to be the reduction of poverty, illiteracy, hunger, and disease. While these goals are fundamentally important, they ace quite different from the goals of environmental sustainability, namely maintaining environmental sink and source capacities unimpaired. But "environmental sustai nablluy" as a topic is legitimized by the Boutros-Ghali (1994) pronouncement on economic development, and is the focus of this paper. The tacit goal of economic development is to narrow the equity gap between the rich and the poor. Almost always this is taken to mean raising the bottom (i.e.. enriching the poor), rather than lowering the top, or undertaking redistribution (Haavelmo and Hansen 1992}. Only very recently is it becoming admitted that bringing the low-income countries up to the affluent levels found in OECD (Organisation for Economic Cooperation and Development) countries, in 40 or even IO0 years, is & totally unrealistic goal. We.do not want to be accused of attacking a straw roan—who ever claimed that global equality at current OECD levels LOO* ROBERT QOODLAND AND HERMAN DALY EcolefiuJ Af plicitioni Vol 6, No. 4 «1! possible? Howe vet, most politicians and most citizens have not yet accepted (he unrealistic nature of this goal. Most people would accept that it is desirable for low-income countries to be. as rich as the North— and then leap to the false conclusion that it must therefore be passible'. They are encouraged in this non sc-quitur by the realization that if greater equality cannot be attained toy growth alone, then sharing and population stability will be necessary. Politicians find it easier to revert to wishful thinking than to face those two issues. Once we wake up to reality, however, there is no further reason for dwelling on the impossible, and every reason to focus on what is possible. One can make a persuasive case (see Serageldin 19936:141-143) that achieving per capita income levels in low-income countries of U.S.51500 to $2000 (.rather than $21000) is quite possible. Moreover, (hat level of income may provide 80% of the basic welfare provided by a $20000 income—as measured by life expectancy, nutrition, education, and a Cher measures of social welfare. This tremendously encouraging case remains largely unknown, even in development circles It needs to be widely debated and accepted as die main goal of development. Its acceptance would greatly facilitate the transition to ES. But to accomplish the possible parts of the imperative of development, we must stop idolizing the impossible. We leave the discussion of development at this point and repeat the challenge to development specialises to deepen this important argument. The paramount importance of sustainability arose partly because, as mentioned, the world is starting to recognize that current patterns of economic development are not generalizable. Present patterns of OECD per capita resource consumption and pollution cannot possibly be generalized to all currently living people, much less to future generations, without liquidating the natural capital on which future economic activity depends. Sustainability thus arose from the recognition that the profligate and inequitable nature of current patterns of development, when projected into (he not-too-distant future, lead to biophysical impossibilities. The transition to sustainability is urgent because the deterioration of global life-support systems—the environment—imposes a time limit. We do not have time to dream of creating more living space or more environment, such as colonizing the moon or building cities beneath the sea; we must save the remnants of the only environment we have, and allow lime for, and invest in the regeneration of, what we have already damaged. Growth Compared with Development Consider the dictionary distinction between growth and development: (1) To grow means to "increase in size (amount, degree) by assimilation"; (2) To develop means to "expand, bring out potentialities, capabilities; to advance from a lower to a higher state" (Funk A WagmuTs Standard Desk Dictionary, 1980, T. Y. Crow- ell, New York, New York, USA). These definitions are useful in conceptualizing sustainability in that development is sustainable, and throughput growth is not. This is unrelated to the unhelpful "development vs. environment" perception of a policy trade-off. True, "growth" refers to added value, but sustainability demands tha( we disaggregate what part of the value-added increase is due to quantity change (throughput) and what pan to qualitative improvement It is neither ethical nor helpful to the environment to expect poor countries to cut or arrest their development, which tends to be highly associated with throughput growth. Poor, small, developing economies need both growth and development. Therefore, (he rich countries, which are responsible for most of today's global environmental damage (e.g., CO, accumulation, ozone-shield damage), and whose material well being can sustain halting or even reversing throughput growth, must take trie lead in this respect. Most local environmental damage (eg., soil erosion, water pollution) occurs in developing countries. Poverty reduction will require considerable growth, as well as development, in developing countries. Bur global environmental constraints are real, and more growth for the South must be balanced by negative throughput growth for (he Norm if environmental sustainability is to be achieved. Future Northern growth should be sought from productivity increases in terms of throughput (eg , reducing the energy intensity of production). Development by the North must be used to free resources (source and sink functions of the environment) for growth and development so urgently needed by the poorer nations. Large-scale transfers to the poorer countries also will be required, especially as the impact of economic stability in the North countries may depress terms of trade and lower economic activity in developing countries Higher prices for the exports of poorer countries, as well as debt relief, will therefore be required. Most importantly, population stability is essential to reduce the need for growth everywhere, especially where population growth has the greatest impact (i.e., in Northern high consuming nations; there the population has a doubling time of 162 yr) as well as where population growth is highest (L.e., in the poor, low-consuming countries, with a population doubling time of only 30 yr, exclusive of China). Natural. Camtaj. and Sustainability Inurgenertmonat and intrageneratioiud sustautabiUty Sustainability in economic terms can be described as the "maintenance of capital," sometimes phrased as "non-declining capital." Historically, at least as early as the Middle Ages the merchant traders used the word "capital" to refer to human-made capital. The merchants wanted to know how much of their trading ships' cargo sales receipts could be consumed by their fam- November 1996 ENVIRONMENTAL SERVICES ARE NOW LIMITING ilies without depleting their capital. Economics No-belist Sir John Hicts encapsulated the sustainabiufy concept in 19-46 when he defined income as the amount (whether natural or financial capital} one could consume during a period and still be as welt off at the end of the period. Solow (1991) is vaguer; to him attainability it an obligation or injunction "... to conduct ourselves so that we leave to the future tfae option or foe capacity to be « well off as we are .. not to satisfy ourselves by impoverishing our successors-..." Today's OECD societies have already impoverished much of the world. Most people in the world today are already impoverished or barely above subsistence and can by no stretch of the imagination ever be as well off is the OECD average. Our successors or future generations seem more likely to be more numerous and poorer than today's generation. Sustainability indeed has an element of not banning the future (uuergener-ariotial equity), but only addressing die future element diverts attention from today's lack of sustainibility (in-trageneratiooal equity). If the world cannot move towards intragenerational sustainability for this generation it will be greatly more difficult to achieve inter-generationsl susuinability in the future. This is partly because the world is hurtling away from environmental sustainability (ES) today. Environmental source and sink capacities are being impaired. This means the capacity of these environmental services in the future will be lower than today. The second reason for tackling intragenerational sustainability first U that world population soars by 100 x 10* new souls each year, same of them OECD over-consumers, many of them poverty stricken. This means achieving intergenerational equity is more difficult each year that has a bigger generation. Of the various forms of capital mentioned above, ■'environmental sustainability" refers to natural capital. So defining environmental sustainability includes at least two further terms, namely "natural capital" and "maintenance" or at least "non-declining.1' Natural capital is basically our natural environment, and is defined as the stock of environmentally provided assets (such as soil and its microbes and fauna (Pi-mentel « al. 1992), atmosphere, fareas, water, wetlands) that provides a flow of useful goods or services. The flow of useful goods and services from natural capital can be renewable or non-renewable, and marketed or non-marketed. Sustainability means maintaining environmental assets, or at least not depleting mem. "Income" is sustainable by the generally accepted definition of Hicks (194fi): "the maximum value a person can consume during a week, and still expect to be as well off at die end of the week as at the beginning." Any consumption that is based on the depletion of natural capital should not be counted as income. Prevailing models of economic analysis tend to treat consumption of natural capital as income, and therefore tend to promote patterns of economic activity that are unsustain- able. Consumption of natural capital is liquidation, the opposite of capital accumulation. Natural capital is distinguished from manufactured and human or social capital. Manufactured capital includes bouses, roads, factories, and ships. Human or social capital includes people, their capacity levels institutions, cultural cohesion, education, information and knowledge. Human capital formation, fay convention, is left out of the national accounts (the United Nations System of National Accounts, SNA) for various reasons, one of which is that, if it is truly productive, it will eventually be reflected, through enhanced productivity, in a higher gross domestic product (GDP). Realization of the values of education and administration, for example, are lagged, and are conventionally assumed to be equal to their costs. The loss of natural capital, if not recorded— as is largely me case today—may take same time before it will reflect itself in income and productivity measurements. From the mercantilists until very recently "capital" referred to the form of capital in the shortest supply, namely manufactured capital. Investments were made in the limiting factor such as sawmills and fishing boats, because their natural capital complements—forests and fish—were abundant. That idyllic era has ended Now that the environment is so heavily used, the limiting factor for much economic development has become natural capital as much as man-made capital In some cases, like marine fishing, it has become the limiting factor—fish have become limiting, rather than fishing boats. Timber is limited by remaining forests, not by saw mills; petroleum is limited by geological deposits and atmospheric capacity to absorb CO* not by refining capacity. As natural forests and fish populations become limiting we begin to inveit in plantation forests and fish ponds. This introduces a hybrid category that combines natural and human-made capital—a category we may call "cultivated natural capital." Thus, the subcategory of marketed natural capital, intermediate between human capital and natural capital, is atbi\aud natural capital such as agriculture products, pond-bred fish, cattle herds, and plantation forests This category is vital to human well being, accounting for most of the food we cat, and a good deal of ate wood and fibers we use. The fact that humanity has the capacity to "cultivate" natural capital dramatically expands the capacity of natural capital to deliver services. But cultivated natural capital (agriculture) is decomposable into human made capital (e.g., tractors, dtesel irrigation pumps, chemical fertilizers) and natural capital (eg., topsoil, sunlight, water). Eventually the natural capital proves limiting. Natural capital is now scarce la. an era in which natural capital was considered infinite relative to the scale of human use. it was ret- 1006 ROBERT GOODLAND AND HERMAN DALY Entafical ApplicatHiu Vot. 6, No * soaiblc not to deduct natural-capital consumption from gross receipts in calculating income. That era is now past. The goal of environmental sustainabiliiy is thus the conservative effort to maintain the traditional meaning and measure of income in an eta in which natural capital is no longer a free good, but is more and more the limiting factor in development. The difficulties in applying the concept arise mainly from operational problems of measurement and valuation of natural capital, as emphasized elsewhere in this paper, and by Ahmad m al (1989). Lutz (1993), and El Senfy (1991, 1993). Four degrees of environmental sustainability Sustaiaability can be divided into four degrees— weak, intermediate, strong, and absurdly strong—depending on bow much substitution one thinks there is among types of capital (Daly and Cobb 1994). We recognize that there are at least four kinds of capital: Hu-ouuv-aiade (die one usually considered in financial and economic accounts), natural capital (as defined previously, and leaving for the moment the case of cultivated natural capital), human capital (investments in education, health and nutrition of individuals), and social capital (the institutional and cultural basis for a society to function). Weak sustainability.—This means maintaining total capital intact without regard to its composition from among the four different kinds of capital (natural, human-made, social, or human). This would imply that the different kinds of capital are perfect substitutes, at least within the boundaries of current levels of economic activity and resource endowment. Given current gross inefficiencies in resource use, weak sustainability would be a vast improvement as a welcome first step— but would by no means constitute-—BS (environmental sustainability). Weak sustainability means we could convert all or most of me world's natural capital into human-made capital or artifacts and still be as well off. (Human and social capital is largely lost at death so has to be renewed each generation). We disagree; society would be worse off (fewer choices) because natural and human-made capital are not perfect substitutes. On the contrary, they are complements to a great extent. InUrmeduitt suttaiitability.—This would require that in addition to maintaining the total Level of capital intact, attention should be given to the composition of that capital from among natural, manufactured, and human. Thus oil may be depleted as Long as the receipts ate invested in other capital elsewhere (e.g., in human capital development, or in renewable energy resources), but, in addition, efforts should be made to define critical levels of each type of capital, beyond which concerns about substiturability could arise and these should be monitored to ensure that the patterns of development do not promote a total decimation of one kind of capital no matter what is being accumulated in the other forms of capital. This assumes that while manufactured and natural capital are substitutable over a sometimes significant but limited margin, they are complementary beyond that limited margin. The full functioning of the system requires at least a mix of the different kinds of capital. Since we do not know exactly where the boundaries of these critical limits for each rype of capital lie, it behooves the sensible person to err on the side of caution in depleting resources (especially natural capital) at too fast a rate. Intermediate sustainability is a big improvement over weak sustainability and seems "sensible." Its great weakness is that it is difficult if not impossible to define critical levels of each type of capital, or rather each type of natural capital that is the limiting factor. We suspect that if (he levels of the different types of natural capital become reliably defined, intermediate sustainability would approximate strong sustainability. Strong sustainability.—This requires maintaining different kinds of capital intact separately. Thus, for natural capital, receipts from depleting oil should l>c invested in ensuring that energy will be available to future generations at least as plentifully as enjoyed by the beneficiaries of today's oil consumption. This assumes that natural and human-made capital are not really substitutes but complements in most production functions. A sawmill (human-made capital) is worthless without the complementary natural capital of a forest. The same logic would argue that if there ate :o be redactions in one kind of educational investments they should be offset by other kinds of education, not by investments in roads. Of the four degrees of sustainability, we prefer strong suttainabiliry Absurdly strong sustainability.—This would never deplete anything. Non-renewable resources—absurdly—could not be used at alt; far renewablea, only net annua] growth rates could be harvested, in the form of the overmature portion of the nock. The choice between intermediate and strong sustainability highlights the trade-offs between human-made capital and natural capital. Economic logic requires us to invest in the limiting factor, which now Is often natural rather than manufactured capital, which was itself limiting yesteryear, investing in natural caj>-ital (non-marketed) is essentially an infrastructure investment on a grand scale, that is the biophysical infrastructure of the entire human niche, investment in such "infTa-infrastructttre" maintains the productiviL-y of all previous economic investments in human-made capital, public or private, by rebuilding the natural capital stocks that nave come to be limiting. Operationally, this translates into three concrete actions as follows 1) Regeneration—Encouraging the growth of natural capital by reducing our level of current exploitation of it; 2) Relief of Pressure—Investing in projects to relieve pressure on natural capital stacks by expanding Novembä 1996 ENVIRONMENTAL SERVICES ARE NOW LIMITING 1007 Fio. I. The thret goals (objectives) of economic development, and how they compare to social and ecological objectives. (Modified from Seragetdin 1993a. b.) eOOHOMC OBjeCTIVES ' GROWTH • EQUITY - EFHOENCV SOOAL OBJECTIVES mnciwnoH •OCMLHOnuiV g^yyif COMMON OUUOML. Willi I MMmunONM. OMMMT eCOLOQlOL OBJSCTtves DCAUNG WITH 6LOBAI ISSUES cultivated natural capital, such as tree plantations to relieve pressure an natural, forests; and 3) increase of Efficiency—Increasing the efficiency of (a) products (such as unproved cookstoves, solar cookers, wind pumps, solar pumps, manure rather than chemical fertilizer), (b) infrastructure services (such as mulching toilets rather than conventional sewage treatment), and (c) lifestyle (such as less carnivorous diets). Criteria for environmental sustainabiiity Prom the maintenance*of-natural-capital approach to environmental sustainabiiity (ES), we can draw practical rules of thumb to guide the design of sustainable economic development. As a first approximation, the design of investment strategies should be compared with the Input and output rules of ES in order Co assess the extent to which a project is sustainable. At the next level of detail, specific indicators of environmental sustainabiiity can be used, such as (hose die World Bank is preparing. The implications of implementing environmental sustainabiiity are immense. We must team how to manage the renewable resources for the long term; we have to reduce waste and pollution; we must learn how to use energy and materials with scrupulous efficiency; we must leant how to use solar energy economically (Pimentel et al. 1994); and we must invest in repairing the damage, as much as possible, done to Earth in the past few decades by unthinking industrialization in many parts of the globe. Environmental sustainabiiity needs enabling conditions that are not themselves integral parts of environmental sustainabiiity; ES needs not only economic and social sustainabiiity (Table 1, Fig. 1) but also democracy, human resource development, empowerment of women, and much more investment in human capital than is common today (i.e., increased literacy, especially ecoliteracy, Orr 1992). As can be seen by the World Bank's recent extraordinary expansion of its traditional investments in human capital, its concerns with governance and promotion of the civil society (forms of investment in social capital), and its growing concern with natural capital and its maintenance, the Bank is increasingly tackling an agenda that tends towards promoting environmental sustainabiiity (see A dynamic formulation .... below). The World Bank considers environmental sustainabiiity to be an urgent priority. The sooner we start to approach environmental sustainabiiity the easier it will become. For example, the demographic transition took a century in Europe, but only a decade in Taiwan: technology and education make big differences. But the longer we delay, the worse will be the eventual quality of life (e.g., fewer choices, fewer species, more risk), especially for the poor who do not have the means to insulate themselves from the negative effects of environmental degradation. Immigration to the New World was a major choice lot Europe, accelerating its demographic transition. Immigration has now all but halted worldwide as a demographic safety valve. Many writers have expressed concern that the world is hurtling away from environmental sustainabiiity at present (Stmonis 1990, Meadows et al. 1992, Hardin 1993, Brown et al. 1994), although consensus has not yet been reached. But what is not contestable is that the current modes of production prevailing in most parts of the global economy are causing the exhaustion and dispersion of a one-time inheritance of natural capital, such as topsoil, groundwater, tropical forests, fisheries, and biodiversity. The rapid depletion of these essential resources, coupled with the degradation of land and atmospheric quality, show that the human economy, as currently configured, is already inflicting serious damage on global supporting ecosystems and is probably reducing future potential biophysical carrying capacities by depleting essential natural-capita! stocks (Daily and Ehrlich 1992) Yet, what is galling is that in spice of spending capital inheritance rather man just income, most of the world consumes at barely subsistence levels. Can humanity attain a more equitable standard of living that does not exceed the carrying capacity of the planet? The transition to environmental sustainabiiity will inevitably occur. However, whether nations will have the wisdom and foresight to plan for an orderly and equitable tran- ROBERT OOODLAND AND HERMAN DALY Fcolflgicil Applrcitums Vol 4, N«4 sirien to environmental sustainability, rather than allowing biophysical limits to dictate the timing and course of this transition, remains in doubt. Ii is obvious that if pollution and environmental degradation were to grow at the same rate as economic activity, or even population growth, the damage to ecological and human health would be appalling, and (he growth itself would be undermined and- even self-defeating. Fortunately, this is not necessary. A transition to sustainability is possible, although it will require changes in policies and the way humans value things. The key to the improvement of the well being of millions of people lies in the increase of die added value of output after properly netting om alt the environmental costs and benefits and after differentiating between the stock and now aspects of the use of natural resources. In our view, this is the key to sustainable development. Without this needed adjustment in thinking and measurement, the pursuit of economic growth that does aot account for natural capital and counts depletion of natural capital as an income stream will not lead to a sustainable development path. The global ecosystem, which is the source of all the resources needed for the economic subsystem, is Suite and has now reached a stage where its regenerative and assimilative capacities have become very strained. It looks inevitable that the next century will witness double the number of people in the human economy, depleting sources and filling sinks with their increasing wastes. If we emphasize the latter, it is because human experience seems to indicate that we have tended to overestimate the environment's capacity to cope with our wastes, even more man we overestimated the "limitless" bounty of such resources as the fish in die sea. The Basic Conditions for Environmental Sustain ability The fundamental definition of environmental sus-tainabitity is contained in the input-output rule as follows: Output RuU Waste emissions from a project should be within the assimilative capacity of the local environment to absorb without unacceptable degradation of its future waste-absorptive capacity or other important services. Input RuU: (a) RtntwaUtir harvest rates of renewable-resource inputs should be within the regenerative capacity of the natural system that generates them, (b) Non-rentwabUs: depletion rates of oou-renewable-re-aource inputs should be equal to the rate at which renewable substitutes ace developed by human invention and investment. Part of the proceeds from liquidating non-renewables should be allocated to research in pursuit of sustainable substitutes. (For a theoretical development of mis idea, see El Serafy (1991.1993] and Das gup u and Heal [1979].) Building on the economic definition of susiainabiliiy as "non-declining wealth per capita," and since wealth is so difficult to measure, environmental sustainability is now defined by the two fundamental environmental services—the source and sink functions—that must be maintained unimpaired during the period over which tusiainabilky is required. While this general definition is robust—and irrespective of country, sector, or epoch—it can is turn be disaggregated. The emphasis on maintenance is to be expected, first for imergeneratiooal equity. Our descendants should have as much choice as we have. Second, as scale increases or matures, production is no longer for growth but for maintenance "Production" is the maintenance cost of the stock and should be minimized (Daly 1994). Sustainability demands that production and consumption be equal so that we maintain capital stocks. Efficiency demands that the maintenance cost (production equal to consumption) be minimized, given the capital stock. The bask conditions for environmental sustainability can be summarized as follows: A) Environmental sustainability requires four related conditions of economic sustainability: 1) Maintenance of per capita manufactured capital (e.g.. artifacts, infrastructure), per capita. 2) Maintenance of renewable natural capital (e.g., healthy air and soils, natural forests, oceanic fish stocks), pet capita. 3) Maintenance of per capita non-renewable substi-tutable natural capital, with capital values based on (he value of the services of the present stock of natural capital. For example, mis means that if the cost of supplying energy substitutes rises, sufficient capital must be accumulated to maintain these services. 4) Maintenance of non-substituuble, non-renewable natural resources o—Education and training, and employment creation, particularly for girls equivalent to that foe boys; meeting unmet family-planning demand. 2) Technological transfer—For the South and East to leapfrog the North's environmentally damaging stage of economic evolution. For the developing countries, this requires creating an incentive framework conducive to efficient investment. For industrial countries, this requires an open trade regime aod adequate investment in new, cleaner technologies. 3) Direct poverty alleviation—Including social safety nets, and targeted aid (inter alia see World Bank 1990, GoodUnd and Daly 19934 A). In energy, for example, the introduction of mechanical and electrical devices in power generation over the past four decades has reduced particulate emissions per unit of energy generated by up to 99% and newer technologies, such as Sue-gas deiulfurization and fiuidized-bed combustion are dramatically reducing enussions of sulfur and nitrogen oxides. But it will be the transition to non-fossil-based sources that will make the permanent difference. Here, technological progress has been remarkable—with costs of solar generation of electricity falling by 95% in the past two decades— but not yet enough. Renewable energy continues to receive much too small a share of public research funds. Technological innovation and application has also done much to make agriculture more productive. New technologies (many developed throughout the Consultative Group for International Agricultural Research [CGIAR] system) and increased fossil fuel inputs have enabled a doubling of food production in the world in just 25 years, with >90% of this growth deriving from yield increases and < 10% from area expansion. Dissemination of integrated pest management (IPM), and internalizing the environmental costs of biocidc use, would enable bincide application to be cut dramatical! y with no loss of productivity (Pimentel a at. 1993). Despite such remarkable progress, it is a mistake to base too much optimism on technological change. New technology is often adopted in order to improve labor productivity, which in turn can raise material standards of living, but without adequate attention to the environmental impacts of the manner in which the im provements are reached. Ttie impact of a particular technology depends on (he nature of the technology, the size of the population deploying it, and the population's level of affluence Toe World Bank, along with others, is increasing investments in more sustainable technologies, such as wind and solar energy, which have limited or benign impacts on the relations of humanity to the ecosystem that supports us all. Bui the level of affluence currently enjoyed by the citizens of the OECD countries cannot be generalized to the rest of the world's current population, much less the massively larger population of the developing countries -40 years from now, no matter what the improvements in technology are likely to be. The contribution to approaching global environmental susiainability differs markedly in three geographic regions- OECD's main contribution Co environmental sustainability should surely be to cease its long history of environmental damage from ovcrconsumptioa and pollution (corollaries to affluence under today's technology), such as greenhouse warming and ozone-shield damage. The contribution of low-income countries lies in stabilizing the human population. The farmer centrally planned economies' contribution seems to be more in accelerating die modernization of its technology in order to reduce acid rain (by removing subsidies on dirty coal), to stop poisoning the land, to reduce waldesterben forest death, and to decrease nuclear risks. It is in OECD's self-interest to accelerate technology transfer to the former centrally planned economies and to the low-income countries But it is possible that with current types of technology and production systems the global economy has already exceeded the sustainable limits of the global ecosystem, and that manifold expansion of anything remotely resembling the present global economy would simply speed us from today's long-run unsustainability to imminent collapse We believe that in conflicts between political feasibility and biophysical realities, the former must eventually give November 19% ENVIRONMENTAL SERVICES ARE NOW LIMITING 1013 way to the Utter, although we cannot specify exactly how long "eventually" will be. A Dynamic Formulation: From Sustain ability to Sustainable Development The foregoing discussion of population, affluence, and technology, based on the Ehrlich and Hotdren (1974) generalization can be nuanced. The inter-relationships among the three factors, and their links with shifts in the structure of the economy should be further disaggregated Three trends need to be accelerated as we struggle towards sustainability. Pint, given the political unreality of a voluntary decline in the overall affluence of industrial countries, how is the "pattern" of this affluence shifting'? Specifically, is the economic structure of toe economy shifting away from environmentally damaging activities (e.g.. heavy and toxic industries) and towards less "natural capital-depleting" sectors (e.g., services)? This trend is to be encouraged, although some services deplete much natural capital (e.g., hospitals, hotels). Furthermore, while affluent Northern nations may be becoming less capital depleting by evolving into the service sector, ar the same time much industry and other natural-capital-depicting activities are being transferred to developing countries. This is not a net gain for the sole global ecosystem, and may be a loss if developing countries' environmental standards are weaker than those whence the industries originated. Japan's huge success in using less input per unit of economic output, such as by de-Unking energy and production, is based partly on the fact that most of Japan's aluminum, for example, is smelted overseas. Similarly, Japan's forest natural capital is almost entirely intact; practically all timber is imported. Recent research shows that structural shifts can have powerful impacts on natural-resource consumption. Second, the clear trend in the consumption of natural resources per unit of output is improving in OECD and in places in developing countries. Two mechanisms need to be monitored here; improvements in economic efficiency (inputs per unit of output), and the degree of substitution away from environmentally critical inputs Policy instruments, including taxes and user charges, can help promote such transitions, especially when the environmental costs are not captured in the marketplace. Third, the pollution impact per unit of economic activity is declining in places; less so in others. Here it is important to distinguish berween the innovation of new technologies, and their dissemination and application. Many of the most profound forms of environmental damage in today's world (soil erosion, lack of clean water, municipal waste, etc) do not require new technologies, but simply the application of existing ones. This in turn requires (a) that decision makers are persuaded tbat the benefits of using such technologies exceed the costs, and (b) that resources are available for putting them in place. Public policies can be targeted towards meeting both conditions. The availability of resources to implement more-sus-tatnablc strategies was a central argument in the findings of the Brundcland Commission's "Our Common Future" (World Commission on Environment and Development 1987). the United Nations Rio Earth Summit's "Agenda 21" (United Nations 1992), and the World Bank's World Development Report 1992. These documents and Coodiand and Daly (1993) argue strongly that the reduction of poverty (i.e., empowering the poor with human and financial resources) is a sine qua non of sustainability The point here is a crucial one: The clear goal of environmental sustainability needs the fuzzy process of environmentally sustainable development. The challenge is to distinguish between environmentally sustainable and unsustainable development. Interactions among the driving factors—scale, structure, efficiency, technology, and investment in environmental protection—together with the key feedback: loops between economic activity and human behavior, such as the powerful impact of income on fertility, explain why in some situations economic growth and technological progress will sometimes cause increased environmental damage and sometimes less. For effective policymaking, it is essential that these various paths be disentangled so that policies may be targeted in a manner that induces changed behavior away from environmentally damaging and inequitable growth and towards accelerated sustainable poverty reduction. World Bank Prookess Towards Sustainable Development The World Bank's latest position on sustainable development has been published (Seragetdin 1993a) so it will not be repeated in this conceptual paper. To summarize: an entire Vice Presidency for Environmentally Sustainable Development (ESD) was created in January 1993, and substantia] numbers of staff (•ZOO persons) are now focusing on sustainable development. ESD has surfed to integrate the viewpoints of the three relevant disciplines: economics, ecology, and sociology against which any technical/engineering proposal: should be evaluated. ESD focuses on improved valuation of environmental concerns, building lustainabjliry into national accounts, and how to value the future. But beyond these conceptual concerns, the World Bank is actively pursuing a four-pronged agenda to promote ESD worldwide, through all its activities. This agenda comprises: (I) Assisting borrowing countries in promoting environmental stewardship; (2) Assessing and mitigating whatever adverse impacts are associated with Bank-financed projects; (3) Building on (he positive synergies between development and the environ- 1014 Table 2. ROBERT GOOD LAND AND HERMAN DALY Worid Bank tending for environmental management. (After World Bank 1993a) Bcoiopat Afplimiau VoL 6. No * Lou/credji amoant Country__Project (10* U.S.J) New commitments, approved in focal 1993 Brazil Water quality and poUaaon control—Sao Paalo/Paxiiu 245.0 Brazil Mimi Cerais water quality and pollution control 145.0 Chin* Southern Jiangtu environmental protection 250.0 India Reaewabie resources development 190.0 Korea, Rep. of Kwangju and Seoul sewerage 1 to.0 Mexico Transport sir quality nuoagemeat 220 0 Tackey Bursa water and sanitation 139.5 Total 1289.J Projects uoder unplemeiuatiaa, approved in fiscal 1989-1992 Angola Lobito-BeoxuHt artun environment*] retubUiuuion (1992) 46.0 Bruil National industrial pollution control 50.0 Chile Sccoad Valparaiso wstei sapply and sewerage (1991) 50.0 China Ship waste disposal (1992) 15.0 China Beijing environmental (1992) 125.0 China Tunjin urban dcveiopraect »nd environment (1992) 100.0 Coie d' Ivo ire Abidjan lagoon eaviroanieat protection <1990) 21.9 Czech and Slovak Federal Republics Power and environmental improvement (1992) 246.0 [adia Industrial pollatioa control (1991) 155.6 Korea, Republic of Pusan and Taejon sewerage (1992) 40.0 Poland Energy resouttes development (1990) 250.0 Poland Hot joppty restructuring «id conservation (!99l) 340.0 Total 1439.5 Portfolio total 2729.0 merit (often called "win-win" strategies); and (4) Addressing the global environmental challenges. Promoting environmental stewardship When it comes to assisting countries in environmental stewardship, the Bank is helping in the definition of strategies and is providing funds for environmental management as well as for projects. In 1994 the Bank committed U.S.S173 X 10* in support of environmental management, bringing the portfolio of environmental management projects and project components financed so far up to ~TJ.S S5O0 million. This compares with a total portfolio of environmental loans amounting to -U.S.S5 x 10* of which about $2 x 10* were committed last year alone; details are provided in Table X In addition, die Bank is trying to help in the expansion and dissemination of knowledge by promoting die sharing of experiences among decision makers in the various countries. But sound environmental stewardship is rooted in sound development and environmental strategies, which must be based on properly identifying the right priorities, and these are country-specific. The key point is that environmental priorities will vary from country to country, and the Bank should stand ready to assist each country with the design and implementation of its own environmentally sustainable development strategy. Each will have to address particular problems. Air pollution may be the prevalent issue in Mexico City (where the Bank is helping with a $280 x 10* loan), but there are other forms of pollution that could be a major priority in some other cities of the developing world. Toxic wastes are the most urgent problem in parts of the former Soviet Union. In Niger, it could very well be the problem of overgrazing. But whatever it is, the formulation of these national strategies, we believe, should be die result of a consultative participatory process in the countries themselves. That is how we expect thai the National Environmental Action Plans (NEAPs), which arc now being promoted in many countries, will be done. Assessing and mitigating adverse impacts The second part of the four-point agenda is assessing and mitigating unavoidable adverse impacts of projects that the Bank agrees to finance. This requires subjecting every proposal to a rigorous environmental assessment, as well as the traditional technical and economic assessments. Furthermore, the Bank is now trying to introduce social assessment as well. The Bank has published much on environmental assessment procedures (e.g.. World Bank 1992a), so we will not go into detail here. Building on "win-win" strategies The third pan of the four-pronged agenda is building synergies between development and the environment The key bere is that by adopting the conceptual framework of environmental sustainability, proper development helps environmental protection and vice versa. That is the so called "win-win" strategy, and it has two parts: investing in people and promoting the efficient use of resources. Investing in people is particularly important. It is the N30 countries have prepared national environmental action plans with assistance from the Bank. The Bank is convinced mat environmental sustainabiliry is essential, and costs less than unsustainable development A major obstacle io promoting policies that foster sustainabiliry to date has been the incomplete measurement of income and investment, particularly the failure to reflect the use or deterioration of natural capital (Steer and Lutt 1993). To correct mis failure, the Bank is promoting improvements in the United Nations System of National Accounts (SNA) (Ahmad et al. 1989. Et Serafy 1993, Lou 1993). Environmentally adjusted SNA has massive policy implications for most developing countries. Economics Nobel Laureate Rob-en Solow has recently modified his 1973 position mat natural capital is unimportant: "The world can, in effect, get along well without natural resources" (Solow 1974:11). In 1992 be concluded that the U.S. gross domestic product (GDP) may change only 1-2% if environmentally adjusted (Solow 1992). Perhaps (his seems a small concession, taut during the discussion period of his 1992 Resources for the Future lecture he recognized mat developing countries rely to a vastly greater extent on natural capital than does the U.S. Without environmentally adjusted SNA, we cannot judge if an economy is genuinely growing or merely living unsustainabty on asset liquidation beyond its true income, whether the balance of payments is in surplus or deficit on current account, or whether the exchange rate needs to be changed. Conclusion This paper represents our current views on the concept of environmental sustainability This is ongoing work, part of which is being done in (he World Bank, and much of it being done by concerned scholars around the world. Our aim bas been to make a modest contribution to the debate on the essence of sustainability. We fully expect the concept to be refined in the coming months and years. By its actions, it is clear mat the World Bank is taking environmental sustainability seriously indeed. But this conceptualization is far from an academic exercise The monumental challenge of ensuring that possibly 10 x lo> people are decently fed and housed within less than two human generations—without damaging the environment on which we all depend—means that the goal of environmental sustainability rrntst be reached as soon as humanly possible. LrraiATinui Cms Ahmad, Y, S. EI Serafy, aad E. Uhz. editors 1989. Envi roomeau( aecouaiiog. The world Bank, Wuhingtoa, DC., USA. Boutros-Ghali, B. 1994. Aa agenda for development. NGO Unison Service Volume 46. United Nauens, New York, New York, USA. Brown, U B., A. Darning, C. Fernen, N. Leasson, M- Lowe, A. Misch, S. Pente 1, M. Renner, L. Starke, P. Weber, and I. Yoang. 1994. Stale of the world: 1994. Worldwaicn tnttiuue, Washington, DC, USA. Cernca, M 1993. The sociologist's approach t0 tusuunible development. Finance and Development 30(4): 11-13. Daily, O. C. and P. R. Ehrlich. 1992. Populitton, sextain- ability and Ike Earth's carrying capacity Bioscience 43: 761-771. Daly, H. E. 1991. Sustainable growth: a bad oxymoron Grassroots Development 1S(3):39. -. 1995. Consumption and welfare: two views of valae added. Review of Social Economy 51:451-473. Daly, H. E, and I. Cobb 1994. For the cammaa good. Beacon Press, Boston, Ntassacmueos, USA. Dasgupts, P., and C Heal. 1979. Economic theory and exhaustible resostcei. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, Enfland. Ehrlich, P., and A. Ehrlich. 1989a. Too many rich folks. Popoii M(3):3-29. Ehrlich, P., and A. Ehrlich. 1989* How die rieh cm save the poor and themselves. PaciAc and Asian Journal of Energy 3:53-0. Ehrlich, P. R., and J. P. Ho Wren L 974. Impact of population growth. Science 171:1212-1217. El Serafy, S. 1993. Country ntaeroecoaomic work sod nar unl resources Environment working paper number 51. TV1. WorM Bank, Washington. DC, USA ■ 1991. The environmeac as capital. Pages 16S-175 in R. Coatanzj, editor. Ecological Economic*. Columbia University Press, New York. New York. USA. Ooodlattd, R. 1992. The cue that the world has reached limit*. Population and Environment 13(2):iä7-182. Ooodlaad, R„ aad U. E. Daly. 1993a. Why Northern income; growth is not the soletion to Southern poverty. Ecological Economics 8:85-101. Goodlwd, R-, and H. E. Daly. 19936. Poveny alleviation in essential far environmental srurainabUlty. Environment waiting paper aamber 42. The World Bank, Washington. D.C., USA. Haavelno, T, and S. Hansen. 1992. Go the strategy of tryinj to reduce economic inequality by expanding (he scale of human activity. Pages 38-31 in R. Goodlud, H. Daly, nnd S. El Serafy, editors. Population technology lifestyle: the transilioa to sitsUinaJbiliiy. Island Pre**. Washington, D.C.. USA. Hardt«, G. 1993. Living within limit*. Oxford University Preis. New York, New York. USA. Kick*, J R.,Sir. 1946. Value and capital. Clarendon, Oxford, England. Ludwig, D. (993. Uncertainty, resource exploitation aad coucrvatioa: lessoaf Crom history. Science 140(2 April): 17. M. Latz, E., editor. 1993. Toward improved accounting Cot die environment. Proceedings of an UN STAT [United Nations Statistical Offtee)-WoeLd Bank symposium The World Bank, Wuhiagto«, D.C, USA. Meadows, D., D. Meadow*, and J. Randen. 1992. Beyond the limits. Chelsea Orceo, Post Mill*. Vermont, USA. Mies. M. 1991. Consumption patterns of the North: the cause of environmental destruction and poverty in the South: women and chüdrest first. United Nations Conuniision an Environment and Development, Geneva, Switrertaod. Orr, D. W. 1992. Environmental literacy: education and the masition to a postmodern world. SUNY [Sua University of New York) Press, Albany, New York, USA Parin*. J., tnd K. Parikh. 1991. Consumption pattern*: the driving force of environmental «res*. Geneva, UNCED November 1996 EJNfVTRONMENTAL SERVICES ARE NOW UMTTTNG I0I7 Pimemel, D., t— McLaughlin, A. Zepp, B, Lakitan, X Kraus, P. KJeinman, F. Vuicini, W. X. Roach, E. Cuaip, W. S. Km ton, and G. Seiig. 1993. Environmental and economic ef-fecu of reducing pesticide use in agriculture. Agriculture, Ecosystems & Environment 44:273-288 Pimemel. D., G. Rodrigues, T Wang, R. Abrams, K. Goldberg, H Staecker. £. Ma, L. Brueckaer, L Trovato, C. Chow, U. Oovindarsjnla, and S. Boerke. 1994. Renewable energy: economies and environmental issues. Bioscience 44:336-547. Pimeatel, D, U. Sue bow, D. A Takacs, H. W. Bra baker, A. R. Dumas, J. I. Meaney, J. A. S. O'Neil, D. E. Onri, and D. B. Corztfius. 1992. Conserving biological diversity in agriculture/forestry systems. Bioscience 41.354-362- Putnam, R. D. 1993d. Social capital and public affairs The American Prospect 13{£pring):t-S. Putnam, R D., R, Leonard!, and R. Y Naneui. 1993*. Making democracy work: civic traditioas in modem Italy. Princeton University Press, Princeton. New Jersey, USA. Serageldin, t. 1993a. Making development sustainable. Finance and Development 30(4);6-I0. -. 1993ft. Development partners: aid and cooperation in the 1990s. Swedish International Development Ageacy, Stockholm, Sweden. Simonia, U. E. 1990. Beyond growth; elements of tustaiaabie development. Sigma, Berlin, Germany. Solow, R. 1974. The economics of resources or the resources of economics. American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings 64:1-14. Solow, R. M. 1991. Sustainability: an economist's perspective The Eighteenth Seward Johnson Lecture (14 June). The Woods Hole Oceanogrxphic Insritacon, Woods Hole, Massachusetts, USA. Solow, R. 1992. An almost practical step toward susonas-bility. (40th Anniversary Lecture.) Resources for the Future, Washington, D.C., USA. Steer, A., and E. Lots. 1993. Measuring environmentally sustainable deveLopmeol Finance &. Development 30(4): 20-23. Tietenoerg, T. 1990. The poverty connection to environ-mental policy. Challenge 33(5) 26-3 ■ ■ - '■■ 1992. Environmental sed aarural resource economics. Harper Collins. New York, New York, USA. Tinbergen, ]., aad R. Huetiog 1991. CNP and marketpricci: wrong signals for sustainable economic luccest thai musk environmental destruction Pages 36-42 in R. Goodtaud, H- Daly, and S. El Serafy. editors. Eavitonmenully avs-tainxble ecoaonlic development: building on BruadtUnd. Environment Paper 36. The World Bank, Washington, D.C , USA. United Nations. 1992. Agenda 21. Report of the United Natiotw Conference on environment and Development, 3 14 Jone 1992, Rio de Janeiro E.93;1.8. Untied Ninons. New York, New York, USA, Vitouaek, P. M , P. Ehrlich, A. Ehrlich, and P. Matson. 1986. Human appropriation of the products of photosynthesis. Bioscience * 368-173. Westra, L. 1994. Aa environmental proposal for ethics: the principle of integrity. Rowan and Little held. Laotian:, Maryland. USA. World Bank. 1990. World develop meat report 1990. The World Bank. Washington DC, USA. -. 1991. World development report 1991. The World Bank, Washington O.C., USA-- 1992a. Environmental assessment sourcebook. (Three volumes.) The World Bank, Waahingcoa, DC. USA. -. 19926. World development report 1992: development and the environment. Oxford University Press, New York. New York, USA. -. 1993a. The World Bank and the environment 1993. The World Bank, Washington, D.C, USA. -. 19930. World development report 1993: investing is health. Oxford University Press. New York, New York. USA. -. 1*95. World development report 1993. Infraatiuc« tute for development. Oxford University Press, New York, New York, USA. World Commission an Environment and Development [o H. Bruodtiand, Chair] 1987. Oar common future. Oxford. University Press, New York. New York, USA.