Chapter 1 Political versus Apolitical Ecologies ■ What is Political Ecology? ■ Five Dominant Narratives in Political Ecology For many of us who are unable to travel to the plains of East Africa, our images of the region are given life on late-night cable wildlife television, in bold IMAX presentations at natural history museums, or perhaps in the vivid spectacle of Disney's The Lion King. The imagined patterns of the "circle of life" in these media - complete with lions, hyenas, and baboons - play out on a yellow-filtered savanna where migrations of wildebeest cross the Serengeti chasing seasonal rainfall, hunted in turn by stoic predators. The scenes are compelling and they inspire in us a justifiable affection for the beauty and complexity of the non-human world around us. These images are also ecologically important, since they give us a picture of connectedness, which is essential to understanding life on the savanna. Across the borderlands of Kenya and Tanzania forage grasses follow rainfall, wildebeest pursue forage, predators pursue wildebeest, scavengers pursue predators, and so on. The absence of people from these imaginary landscapes seems in no way strange for most of us; these are natural landscapes, apparently far from farms, factories, and the depredations of humankind. It is perhaps inevitable, therefore, that an intuitive reaction to the news that wildlife populations are in crisis - including declines in giraffe, topi, buffalo, warthog, gazelle, and eland - is to imagine that the intrusion of humankind into the system is the cause of the problem. Growing populations of impoverished African Political Ecology: A Critical Introduction, Second Edition. Paul Robbins. ® 2012 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Published 2012 by John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. 12 What is Political Ecology? Banton / Shutterstock. people, we might imagine, have contaminated the natural rhythm of the wilderness. Indeed, the sense of loss in contemplating the declining biodiversity and destroyed landscapes may inspire frustration, coupled with a feeling of helplessness; the situation in the Serengeti and the steady march of growing populations seem far beyond the control and influence of life where we live. Stepping back from the savanna, however, and gazing across the Serengeti-Mara ecosystem both in time and in space, habitat loss and wildlife decline appear more complex and more connected to the daily lives and routines of urban people in the developed world. Cross-border analysis shows that the decline in habitat and wildlife in Kenya is far higher than in Tanzania. Why? Rainfall, human population, and livestock numbers do not differ significantly. Rather, private holdings and investment in export cereal grains on the Kenyan side of the border have led to intensive cropping and the decline of habitat. These cereals are consumed around the world, as part of an increasingly globalized food economy. As Kenya is increasingly linked to these global markets and as pressure on local producers increases, habitat loss is accelerated. Less developed agricultural markets and less fully privatized land tenure systems in Tanzania mean less pressure on wildlife. The wildlife crisis in East Africa is more political and economic than demographic (Homewood et al. 2001). These facts undermine widely held apolitical views about ecological relations in one of the most high-profile wildlife habitats in the world. They also point to faulty assumptions about the nature of "wild" Africa. Firstly, the image of a Serengeti without people is a fallacious one. The Masai people and their ancestors inhabited the Central Rift Valley for thousands of years before European contact, living in and around wildlife for generations. Indeed, their removal from wildlife park areas has led to violent conflicts (Collett 1987). More generally, the isolation of these places is also a mistaken perception. Export crops from Kenya, including tea and coffee in other parts of Political versus Apolitical Ecologies 13 Kenya beyond the Central Rift Valley, continue to find their way to consumers in the first world, even as their global prices fall, constraining producers who must increase production, planting more often and over greater areas, further changing local ecological conditions. With three-quarters of the population in agriculture, economic margins for most Kenyans become tighter every year, and implications for habitat and wildlife more urgent. The migration of the wildebeest, and its concomitant implications for grasslands and lions, therefore, does not occur outside the influences of a broader political economy. Land tenure laws, which set the terms for land conversion and cash cropping, are made by the Kenyan and Tanzanian states. Commodity markets, which determine prices for Kenyan products and the ever-decreasing margins that drive decisions to cut trees or plant crops, are set on global markets. Money and pressure for wildlife enclosure, which fund the removal of native populations from the land, continue to come largely from multilateral institutions and first-world environmentalists. All of these spheres of activity are further arranged along linked axes of money, influence, and control. They are part of systems of power and influence that, unlike the imagined steady march of the population "explosion," are tractable to challenge and reform. They can be fixed. The difference between this contextual approach and the more traditional way of viewing problems like this is the difference between a political and an apolitical ecology. This is the difference between identifying broader systems rather than blaming proximate and local forces; between viewing ecological systems as power-laden rather than politically inert; and between taking an explicitly normative approach rather than one that claims the objectivity of disinterest. When the bottom drops out of the coffee market, as it did in the late summer of 2001, what happens to the peasants who depend upon it and the forests in which it is harvested? When the World Bank helps to fund massive afforestation programs around the world, aimed at preserving tree cover and animal biodiversity, what actually happens to the hill forests designated for enclosure and the tribal people who live there? These are the questions of political ecology, a field of critical research predicated on the assumption that any tug on the strands of the global web of human-environment linkages reverberates throughout the system as a whole. This burgeoning field has attracted several generations of scholars from the fields of anthropology, forestry, development studies, environmental sociology, environmental history, and geography. Its countless practitioners all query the relationship between economics, politics, and nature but come from varying backgrounds and training. Some are physical scientists (e.g., biologists, geomorphologists, and hydrologists), others are methodological technicians (e.g., geographic information or remote sensing specialists), while most are social and behavioral scientists. All share an interest in the condition of the environment and the people who live and work within it. These researchers, moreover, advocate fundamental changes in the management of nature and the rights of people, directly or indirectly working with state and non-governmental organizations (NGOs) to challenge current conditions. This book reviews the work that these people do, pointing towards the common factors evident in a research area often noted for its diversity, and revealing the strengths and weaknesses in a field that has grown far too quickly to prepare a comprehensive survey or census of its accomplishments and failures. 14 What is Political Ecology? What is Political Ecology? The term political ecology is a generous one that embraces a range of definitions. A review of the term from its early use (first used to describe this kind of work by Wolf in 1972) to its most recent manifestations shows important differences in emphasis. Some definitions stress political economy, while others point to more formal political institutions; some stress environmental change, while others emphasize narratives or stories about that change (see Table 1.1). Even so, there seems to be a set of common elements. The many definitions together suggest that political ecology represents an explicit alternative to "apolitical" ecology, that it works from a common set of assumptions, and that it employs a reasonably consistent mode of explanation. Challenging apolitical ecologies If there is a political ecology, by implication there must be an apolitical one. As such, research in the field commonly presents its accounts, whether explaining land degradation, local resource conflict, or state conservation failures, as an alternative to other perspectives. The most prominent of these apolitical approaches, which tend to dominate in global conversations surrounding the environment, are "ecoscarcity" and "modernization" accounts. It is not my intention to provide sustained criticisms of these two approaches here; later chapters of the book should reveal the characteristics of these perspectives and demonstrate their ethical and practical weaknesses. An outline of each should suffice to present their basic arguments, with which readers are probably already very familiar, common as these approaches are to most environmental explanation. Ecoscarcity and the limits to growth The dominant contemporary narrative of environmental change and human-environment interaction is a well-established one with a long history. In Western Europe since the late 1700s, when human influence and response to the environment was first submitted to scientific scrutiny, the central driving explanation for social/ecological crisis has been increasing human population, measured in absolute numbers. Following from Thomas Malthus's Essay on the Principle of Population, the argument is straightforward: as human populations grow out of proportion to the capacity of the environmental system to support them, there is a crisis both for humans, whose numbers fall through starvation and disease-based mortality, and for nature, whose overused assets are driven past the point of self-renewal. This argument took many forms during the twentieth century, from the "population bomb" of Paul Ehrlich (1968) to the Club of Rome's "Limits to Growth" (Meadows et al. 1972), but its elements are consistent. All hold to the ultimate scarcity of non-human nature and the rapacity of humankind's growing numbers. For ecoscarcity proponents, this is nowhere a more serious problem than in the underdeveloped world, where growth rates and absolute numbers of people remain the highest in the world. That the poorest regions of the world are the repositories for what are viewed Table 1 fining political ecology. Cockburn and Ridgeway (1979) Blaikie and Brookfield (1987) Greenberg and Park (1994) Peet and Watts (1996b) Hempel (1996) "a useful way of describing the intentions of radical movements in the United States, in Western Europe and in other advanced industrial countries ... very distant from the original rather sedate operations of the eco-lobby" (p. 3) "combines the concerns of ecology and a broadly denned political economy. Together this encompasses the constantly shifting dialectic between society and land-based resources, and also within classes and groups within society itself" (p. 17) A synthesis of "political economy, with its insistence on the need to link the distribution of power with productive activity and ecological analysis, with its broader vision of bio-environmental relationships" (p. 1) "a confluence between ecologically rooted social science and the principles of political economy" (p. 6) "the study of interdependence among political units and of interrelationships between political units and their environment... concerned with the political consequences of environmental change" (p. 150) Explicate and describe first-world urban and rural environmental degradation from corporate and state mismanagement; document social activism in response. Explain environmental change in terms of constrained local and regional production choices within global political economic forces, largely within a third-world and rural context. "Synthesize the central questions asked by the social sciences about the relations between human society, viewed in its bio-cultural-political complexity, and a significantly humanized nature" (p. 1). Locates "movements emerging trom the tensions and contradictions of underproduction crises, understands the imaginary basis of their oppositions and visions for a better life and the discursive character of their politics, and sees the possibilities for broadening environmental issues into a movement for livelihood entitlements, and social justice" (pp. 38-39). Explore and explain community-level and regional political action in the global sphere, in response to local and regional degradation and scarcity. Continued 16 What is Political Ecology? Political versus Apolitical Ecologies 17 Table 1.1 Continued Author/Source Watts (2000) Definition of "political ecology" Goal Stott and Sullivan (2000) "to understand the complex relations between nature and society through a careful analysis of what one might call the forms of access and control over resources and their implications for environmental health and sustainable livelihoods" (p. 257) "identified the political circumstances that forced people into activities which caused environmental degradation in the absence of alternative possibilities... involved the query and reframing of accepted environmental narratives, particularly those directed via international environment and development discourses" (p. 4) Explain environmental conflict especially in terms of struggles over "knowledge, power and practice" and "politics, justice and governance" "Illustrating the political dimensions of environmental narratives and in deconstructing particular narratives to suggest that accepted ideas of degradation and deterioration may not be simple linear trends that tend to predominate" (p. 5) as important and scarce environmental goods makes the problem doubly serious. In this way of thinking, the perilous decline of Kenya's wildlife, as described above, can be predicted to follow inevitably from the growth of Kenya's population. The problems with this line of argument are many. In general terms, and as will be shown throughout this book, the demographic explanation is a consistently weak predictor of environmental crisis and change. Firstly, this is because the mitigating factors of affluence and technology (following Commoner 1988) tend to overwhelm the force of crude numbers. A very few members of the global village consume the majority of its resources. When these factors are considered, overpopulation, to the extent that such a thing exists on a global or regional scale, appears to be a problem strictly of smaller, wealthier populations, especially the United States, rather than the apparently larger populations of the global south (Table 1.2). The more fundamental problem with this formulation, however, is that it posits the environment as a finite source of basic unchanging and essential elements, which set absolute limits for human action. However intuitive (divide a limited stock of earth materials by a potentially infinite hungry human population and the result always approaches zero), this assumption has proved historically false and conceptually flawed. Market "optimists," expressing the problem in economic terms, suggest that any form of resource scarcity creates a response that averts serious crisis. As a good becomes scarcer, they suggest, its price tends to rise, which results either in the clever use of substitutes and new technologies to increase efficiency, or in a simple decreased demand for that good. The result is that apparently finite resources are stretched to become infinitely available as Table 1.2 Who is overpopulated? Comparative per capita consumption of resources and production of waste (World Resources Institute 2010). India is three times larger than the United States, in terms of population, but consumes a comparatively tiny quantity of key resources and produces a fractional amount of waste. Resource India United States Meat (kg, 2002) Paper(kg, 2005) Water (m') Energy (kg oil equivalent, 2005) Carbon emissions (tonnes, 2005) 5 5 633 514 1 125 297 1,687 7,921 20 consumers use less and producers supply more efficient alternatives and substitutes (Rees 1990). Even if populations rise on a limited land area, for example, the demand for land and rising land rents will increase its efficiency of use, with more and better production on each unit of land. Even if petroleum becomes scarce, the rising price per barrel will encourage the use of otherwise expensive alternatives like wind and solar power, or simply cause consumers to drive less, endlessly stretching the world's energy supply. While such optimistic prognoses are themselves fraught with problems, they do point to an important and increasingly well-accepted truism: resources are constructed rather than given. This is not to argue that the number of organisms versus the extent and character of local resources is not an important issue; ask anyone who is in charge of extending water services to suburbs outside of Denver or Phoenix. To be sure, the number of people who use trees, food, water, metals, and other materials in part determines proximate demands on the environment. So too, the adaptation of natural systems to meet changing needs, whether driven by absolute numbers or changing consumption patterns, is an important element of human-environment interactions. Even so, the Malthusian population pressure model poorly reflects the complexity of global ecology. The argument does, however, hold serious implications for the use and management of resources. When it was first offered up in Malthus's 1793 formulation, the ecoscarcity argument was presented as an explicit justification for social policy. In particular, Malthus insisted that since famine and starvation were essential to controlling runaway human populations, such events are "natural" and inevitable. England's Poor Laws, the modest redistributive welfare subsidies to feed the most marginal groups, were pointless and counter-environmental. By increasing rather than decreasing their numbers, such subsidies were the source not the solution of misery. So too, in such a conceptualization, the crisis for the poor lay not in the larger economy or ecology of their subsistence, but instead in and amongst the poor themselves: "In searching for objects of accusation, [the poor man] never adverts to the quarter from which all his misfortunes originate. The last person he would think of accusing is himself, on whom, in fact, the whole blame lies" (Malthus 1992, book 4, ch. 3, p. 227). The implications for contemporary global environmentalism are equally programmatic, environmental crises as demographic problems exist at the site of resource use, in and <3D 18 What is Political Ecology? amongst the world's poor, who are simply too numerous. Subsidies of the poor do little to alleviate the crisis, since they only serve to reinforce the demographic trend. Population control, rather than reconfiguration of global distributions of power and goods, is the solution to ecological crisis. The continued advocacy of an apolitical natural-limits argument, therefore, is implicitly political, since it holds implications for the distribution and control of resources. Demographic explanations of environmental change have become considerably more sophisticated than those outlined by Malthus and the Club of Rome. Attention to high-density urban development and the associated energy costs and infrastructure demands of megacities has created justifiably renewed attention to population as an important driver for environmental change. More recent research has come to demonstrate that the position of women in the workforce and their increased access to decision-making, calories, and education are closely linked not only to changing environmental conditions but also to decreased fertility and population growth. New approaches have come to redefine our ways of thinking about population, power, and environment. Even so, crude Malthusianism regrettably remains a typical way of thinking about environmental change, and so provides a unifying target for many political ecologists. Other apolitical ecologies: Diffusion, valuation, and modernization Other prominent accounts of environmental change also dominate current thinking, asserting apolitical answers to extremely political questions. It is commonly argued, for example, that ecological problems and crises throughout the world are the result of inadequate adoption and implementation of "modern" economic techniques of management, exploitation, and conservation. Generally, this way of thinking is underpinned by a commitment to economic elficiency. These approaches to environmental management and ecological change generally assert that efficient solutions, determined in optimal economic terms, can create "win-win" outcomes where economic growth (sometimes termed "development") can occur alongside environmental conservation, simply by getting the prices and techniques right. Such approaches are persuasive, at least insofar as they reject the cataclysmic prognoses of Malthusian catastrophe described above. The assertion that economic efficiency pays environmental dividends is further supported by many examples over the recent period of industrial technological change. The historically dirty pulp and paper industry, in a prominent example, has simultaneously increased profit margins and decreased emissions through efficient industrial ecological practices (Pento 1999). By freeing individuals and firms to seek their own best and most efficient use of resources, propelled by competition on an open market and sustained by modern technology, waste, environmental destruction, and resource degradation can be tamed. Moreover, the sometimes perverse influence of strong state bureaucracies over the environment is perhaps avoided through market- and technology-based solutions. For global ecology, such an approach suggests several general principles and policies. (1) Western/northern technology and techniques need to be diffused outwards to the underdeveloped world. (2) Firms and individuals must be connected to larger markets and given more exclusive property controls over environmental resources (e.g., land, air, wildlife). (3) For wilderness and biodiversity conservation, the benefits of these efficiencies Political versus Apolitical Ecologies 19 must be realized through institutionalizing some form of valuation; environmental goods like wildebeest, air, and stream quality must be properly priced on an open market. The debates and critiques surrounding such approaches and the logics that underpin them are too numerous to summarize here; even so, there are some serious general conceptual and empirical problems with this perspective. First, the assertion that modern technologies and markets can optimize production in the underdeveloped world, leading to conservation and environmental benefits, has proven historically questionable. The experience of the green revolution, where technologies of production developed in America and Europe were distributed and subsidized for agrarian production around the world, led to what even its advocates admit to be extensive environmental problems: exhausted soils, contaminated water, increased pest invasions (Lai et al. 2002). Beyond these failings, the more general assertion that superior environmental knowledge originates in the global north for transfer to the global south is in itself problematic, reproducing as it does paternalistic colonial knowledge relations and a priori discounting the environmental practices of indigenous and local communities (Uphoff 1988). Articulation with global markets, as will be shown in the case materials presented here, has also proved to be a mixed environmental blessing at best. Changes in markets, falling commodity prices, and altered land values that have followed from globalized exchange have often led to land degradation and social disorder in the less developed world. A call to intensify these forms of exchange must be viewed skeptically. More generally, even in free and open markets, monopoly control of resources commonly perverts allocation and distribution, leading to far from optimal social and ecological outcomes. Indeed, the tradition of conservation in the United States is largely based on the understanding that collective control of environmental resources is necessary for fair and sustainable distribution. Asserting and adopting the apparently apolitical approach to the environment suggested in market and modernization approaches, because of the institutional and political changes that such an approach mandates, is also inherently political. To individuate and distribute "collective" goods like forests or water by necessity requires the alienation of previous user groups. To implement new technological approaches in agriculture, resource extraction, or wilderness management requires a transformation of existing institutions. Increasingly open markets demand deregulation of labor and environmental controls. There is nothing apolitical about such a proposal. The first lesson to draw is that the dominant contemporary accounts of environmental crisis and ecological change (ecoscarcity and modernization) tend to ignore the significant influence of political economic forces. As we shall see, this is to ignore the most fundamental problems in contemporary ecology. The other lesson is that apolitical ecologies, regardless of claims to even-handed objectivity, are implicitly political. It is not so much that political ecology is "more political" than these other approaches to the environment. Rather it is simply more explicit in its normative goals and more outspoken about the assumptions from which its research is conducted. Common assumptions and modes of explanation Following Bryant and Bailey, political ecological accounts and research efforts also share ommon prem.se, that environmental change and ecological conditions are the product 20 What is Political Ecology? of political process. This includes three fundamental and linked assumptions in approaching any research problem. Political ecologists: "accept the idea that costs and benefits associated with environmental change are for the most part distributed among actors unequally... [which inevitably] reinforces or reduces existing social and economic inequalities . . . [which holds] political implications in terms of the altered power of actors in relation to other actors" (Bryant and Bailey 1997, pp. 28-29). Research tends to reveal winners and losers, hidden costs, and the differential power that produces social and environmental outcomes. As a result, political ecological research proceeds from central questions, such as: What causes regional forest loss? Who benefits from wildlife conservation efforts and who loses? What political movements have grown from local land use transitions? In answering, political ecologists follow a mode of explanation that evaluates the influence of variables acting at a number of scales, each nested within another, with local decisions influenced by regional polices, which are in turn directed by global politics and economics. Research pursues decisions at many levels, from the very local, where individual land managers make complex decisions about cutting trees, plowing fields, buying pesticides, and hiring labor, to the international, where multilateral lending agencies shift their multi-billion-dollar priorities from building dams to planting trees or farming fish. Such explanation also tends to be highly (sometimes recklessly) integrative. Bryant (1999) described the field as a series of "disciplinary transgressions," where researchers trace their personal and professional trajectories from political studies and sociology to geography or from geography to development studies. And as we shall see, a group of people and institutions has emerged around such interdisciplinary transgressions, a global assemblage of diverse practitioners who make certain kinds of movies, write certain kinds of books, and advance certain kinds of arguments. So, rather than adding yet another definition to a crowded field, it is best to suggest at the outset that political ecology is a term that describes a community of practice united around a certain kind of text. The nature of this community and the quality of these texts, as well as the theory and empirical research that underpins them, are the topic of the remainder of this volume. But broadly they can be understood to address the condition and change of social/environmental systems, with explicit consideration of relations of power. Political ecology, moreover, explores these social and environmental changes with an understanding that there are better, less coercive, less exploitative, and more sustainable ways of doing things. The research is directed at finding causes rather than symptoms of problems, including starvation, soil erosion, landlessness, biodiversity decline, human health crises, and the more general and pernicious conditions where some social actors exploit other people and environments for limited gain at collective cost. Finally, it is a field that stresses not only that ecological systems are political, but also that our very ideas about them are further delimited and directed through political and economic process. As a result, political ecology presents a Jekyll and Hyde persona, attempting to do two things at once: critically explaining what is wrong with dominant accounts of environmental change, while at the same time exploring alternatives, adaptations, and creative human action in the face of mismanagement and exploitation: offering both a "hatchet" to take apart flawed, dangerous, and politically problematic accounts, and a "seed," to grow into new socio-ecologies (see Chapter 4). Political versus Apolitical Ecologii 21 Five Dominant Narratives in Political Ecology In this sense, political ecology characterizes a kind of argument, text, or narrative, born of research efforts to expose the forces at work in ecological struggle and document livelihood alternatives in the face of change. This does not mean that political ecology is something that people must write and think about all the time. Much of this work is carried out by people who might never refer to themselves as political ecologists, who count writing, researching, or arguing as only one part of their job, or who might do so in only one sphere of their work. Neither is political ecology restricted to academics from the "first world." Indeed, the critical ideas and arguments of political ecology are often produced through the research and writing, blogging, filming, and advocacy of countless NGOs or activist groups around the world, surveying the changing fortunes of local people and the landscapes in which they live. This may actually comprise the largest share of work in political ecology. Published only in local meeting and development reports, or uploaded as short documentary videos or slide presentations, this work is as much a part of the field as the well-circulated books or refereed journal articles of formal science. Big questions and theses What unites the diverse work in these many locations is a general interest in five big themes Over-simply, political ecology research has demonstrated (or attempted to demonstrate) the general theses shown in Table 1.3, each of which receives a chapter later in this volume. The degradation and marginalization thesis Otherwise environmentally innocuous production systems undergo transition to overex-ploitation of natural resources on which they depend as a response to state development intervention and/or increasing integration in regional and global markets. This may lead to increasing poverty and, cyclically, increasing overexploitation. Similarly, sustainable community management is hypothesized to become unsustainable as a result of efforts by state authorities or outside firms to enclose traditional collective property or impose new/ foreign institutions. Related assertions posit that modernist development efforts to improve production systems of local people have led contradictorily to decreased sustainability of local practice and a linked decrease in the equity of resource distribution. The conservation and control thesis Control of resources and landscapes has been wrested from producers or producer groups (associated by class, gender, or ethnicity) through the implementation of efforts to preserve sustainability,""community," or "nature." In the process, local systems of livelihood, production, and socio-political organization have been disabled by officials and global interests seeking to preserve the "environment." Related work in this area has further demonstrated that where local production practices have historically been productive and relatively 22 What is Political Ecology? Table 1,3 Five theses of political ecology and the things they What is explained? attempt to explain. Relevance Thesis Degradation and marginalization Conservation and control Environmental conflict and exclusion Environmental subjects and identity Political objects and actors Environmental conditions (especially degradation) and the reasons for their change Conservation outcomes (especially failures) Access to the environment and conflicts over exclusion from it (especially natural resources) Identities of people and social groups (especially new or emerging ones) Socio-political conditions (especially deeply structured ones) Environmental degradation, long blamed on marginal people, is shown in ils larger political and economic context. Usually viewed as benign, efforts at environmental conservation are shown to have pernicious effects, and sometimes fail as a result. Environmental conflicts are shown to be part of larger gendered, classed, and raced struggles and vice versa. Political identities and social struggles are shown to be linked to basic issues of livelihood and environmental activity. Political and economic systems are shown to be underpinned and affected by the non-human actors with which they are intertwined. benign, they have been characterized as unsustainable by state authorities or other players in the struggle to control resources. The environmental conflict and exclusion thesis Increasing scarcities produced through resource enclosure or appropriation by state authorities, private firms, or social elites accelerate conflict between groups (gender, class, or ethnicity). Similarly, environmental problems become "socialized" when such groups secure control of collective resources at the expense of others by leveraging management interventions by development authorities, state agents, or private firms. So too, existing and long-term conflicts within and between communities are "ecologized" by changes in conservation or resource development policy. The environmental subjects and identity thesis Institutionalized and power-laden environmental management regimes have led to the emergence of new kinds of people, with their own emerging self-definitions, understandings of the world, and ecological ideologies and behaviors. More firmly: people's beliefs Political versus Apolitical Ecologies 23 and attitudes do not lead to new environmental actions, behaviors, or rules systems; instead, new environmental actions, behaviors, or rules systems lead to new kinds of people. Correlatively, new environmental regimes and conditions have created opportunities or imperatives for local groups to secure and represent themselves politically. Such movements often represent a new form of political action, since their ecological strands can connect disparate groups, across class, ethnicity, and gender. Political objects and actors thesis Material characteristics of non-human nature and its components (dung, climate, refrigerators, bacteria, lawn grass, road salt, goats, and tropical soils) impinge upon the world of human struggles and are entwined within them, and so are inevitably political. Yet as these characteristics and agents assume new roles and take on new importance, they are also transformed by these interactions. People, institutions, communities, and nations assemble and participate in the networks that emerge, leveraging power and influence, just as non-human organisms and communities do. in recent history, hegemonic institutions and individuals (environmental ministries, multinational corporations, corrupt foresters) have gained disproportionate influence by controlling and directing new connections and transformations, leading to unintended consequences and often pernicious results. In the process, resistance emerges from traditional, alternative, or progressive human/non-human alliances marginalized by such efforts (especially along lines of class, ethnicity, and gender). The target of explanation Of course, each of these theses actually seeks to explain something somewhat different. While degradation and marginalization offers an explanation of why environmental systems change (because of capital accumulation), environmental subjectivity research seeks to explain why social identities change (because of transformed environmental institutions). This diversity of targets tor explanation has been the source of some confusion in the field (Vayda and Walters 1999) and reflects its historic development. Research linking environmental change to political and economic marginalization emerged first in the 1970s and 80s as an attempt to apply dependency theory to the environmental crises of the period (see Chapter 8). The problematic effects of global and regional conservation efforts, including World Heritage Sites, national parks, and biodiversity zones, also became increasingly apparent in the 1990s, and political ecology on the topic benefited from a growing interest in the historical development of conservation (Chapter 9). Interest in environmental conflict soon followed, as many environmental issues became increasingly politicized in both regional contexts, from Love Canal to the Amazonian rainforest, as well as global ones, with the emergence of global agreements and debates on climate and biodiversity (Chapter 10). Interest in the new environmental activism and identities grew from all of the issues above, and was placed squarely on the agenda by local people themselves, including Andean peasant movements, the Zapatistas, chipko, and a host of other movements (Chapter 11). An interest in political objects and agents 's the most recent addition to debate in political ecology, rooted in its deep historical 24 What is Political Ecology? materialism, but also in an emerging concern more generally for the way the non-human world impinges on the human one (Chapter 12). The diversity of political ecology research also results from innumerable, smaller, differing arguments addressing, among many issues: possibility for community collective action; role of human labor in environmental metabolism; nature of risk-taking and risk-aversion in human behavior; diversity of environmental perceptions; causes and effects of political corruption; relationship between knowledge and power. These many topics and concerns overlap, and, as I hope to show by the end of the book, a coherent set of answers to these questions is beginning to achieve something of a consensus. They also provide bridges to one another, creating a kind of lattice-work of investigation. Understanding how changing forms of knowledge, like computerized mapping, for example, lead to new systems of control over a forest probably leads a researcher to ask; What are the concomitant changes in the behavior of foresters, and does this create new patterns of actual forest ecology? Moreover, in their linkages to local communities and NGOs, political ecologists, whether they are more interested in the biophysical or social aspects of a problem, have helped to build practical, detailed, integrated, empirical databases on all these diverse issues, recording land covers, farming practices, wildlife management systems, technological innovations and diffusions, local folk tales and oral histories, and informal markets and economies. These basic empirical findings help communities make decisions, aid in advocacy for social and environmental causes, and serve as a record to future scholars about the way things looked at the dawn of the twenty-first century. The value of this last contribution, providing an historical record, is not a trivial one. Much of what we know about the political economy of the environment is bequeathed to us by political ecologists of previous generations. Indeed, political ecology can arguably said to be very old, since nineteenth- and twentieth-century environmental research in geography, anthropology, and allied natural and social sciences has a long critical tradition. Even before a semi-coherent body of political ecological theory emerged in the late twentieth century, many explicitly political practitioners emerged from the ranks of field ecologists, ethnographers, explorers, and other researchers. These represent the deep roots of the field. Chapter 2 A Tree with Deep Roots The Determinist Context The Building Blocks Peter Alexeivich Kropotkin was born a Russian aristocrat in 1842, but by the time he died in 1921 he had become a globally known anarchist philosopher whose writings had done as much to explore the linkage between people and the environment as any in that tumultuous century. As an activist, a keen observer of nature, and a scientific explorer and ethnographer, Kropotkin was an early political ecologist. As a geographer, Kropotkin set out in 1865 to explore the most remote areas of the Russian Far East where the Sayan highlands border Manchuria. There were no charts of the region at this time and in preparing for the expedition he came across a map prepared by a Tungus hunter with the point of a knife on tree bark. "This little map," the explorer explained, "so struck me by its seeming truth to nature that 1 fully trusted to it" (Woodcock and Avakumovic 1990, p. 72). This trust for the environmental knowledge of local people was reinforced throughout his journey. Traveling for months with a local Yakut man, Kropotkin traversed 800 miles of rugged mountains. During his journey he encountered and described farmers, herders, and hunters who all organized their lives to thrive under what urban Russians would have considered unthinkably adverse conditions. Like his previous expeditions, this arduous trip reinforced his growing appreciation for "the constructive work of the unknown masses, which so seldom finds any mention in books, and the importance of that constructive work in the growth of forms of society" (Woodcock and Avakumovic 1990, pp. 59-60). The evidence amassed during these Mtical Ecolox Wiley & ions, Ltd. Pub|ished 2Q12 by John w.fey & ^ ^