1 A Theory ofSultanism 1 A Type of Nondemocratk Rule H. E. Chehabi and Juan J. Linz The concept of "sultanistic regime" emerged from Juan Linz's comparative analysis of nondemocratic regimes, which systematically developed the differences between totalitarian and authoritarian forms of rule.1 At the time Linz developed this distinction in the early 1970s, political democracies were few, whereas the range of nondemocratic regimes was enormous. Since totalitarian regimes were rare and limited to the communist world,2 it was tempting to group all other nondemocratic regimes in the residual category "authoritarian," which denotes a wide range of governments with distinctive characteristics that allow their societies a limited pluralism short of genuine democracy. Authoritarian regimes can thus be mostly civilian one-party states, ranging from a highly institutionalized authoritarian regime such as Franco's Spain to the ephemeral single-party regimes of Africa in the very early days of independence; nonhierarchical or hierarchical military regimes like the bureaucratic-authoritarian regimes of the Southern Cone of South America;3 or even royal dictatorships like those in the Balkans in the interwar years (as opposed to traditionally legitimated monarchies). The structural differences among them are therefore vast.4 But as vast as they are, some regimes appeared distinct on all the major dimensions used in the conceptualization of nondemocratic rule; Linz called them "sultanistic." The differencesjpetween these and authoritarian or totalitarian regimes are not Tnerely a matter of degree but He in-their, rulers'over airconceptfonoT politics, 4 " COMPARATIVE STUDIES A Theory ofSuhanism 1 • 5 the structure of power, and the relation to the social structure, the economy, and ultimately the subjects of such rule. But before analyzing "sultanistic" regimes, the use of the term should be explained. Excursus on "Sultanism" The term "sultanism" was<>riginaJlygoinedby Max Weber, whe-nsed-iHo-rgfef •• Jo an extreme case of patrimonialism, which in his tripartite classification of j the forms of legitimate authority is a form of traditional authority: Patrimonialism and, in the extreme case, sultanism tend to arise whenever traditional domination develops an administration and a military force which are purely personal instruments of the master. . . . Where domination is primarily ■■ traditional, even though it is exercised by virtue of the ruler's personal autonomy, it will be called patrimonial authority; where indeed it operates primarily on the basis of discretion, it will be called sultanism. . . . Sometimes it appears that sultanism is completely unrestrained by tradition, but this is never in fact the case. The non-traditional element is not, however, rationalized in impersonal terms, but consists only in an extreme development of the rulers discretion. It is this which distinguishes it from every form of rational authority.5 I Weber's notion of patrimonialism caught on and was used extensively, and in an influential article Guenther Roth applied it to Third World politics.6 Given the differences between the modern states in which the patrimonial logic \ operates and the traditional patrimonial systems Weber had in mind, the term "neopatrimonialism" came to be widely used.7 But Weber's formulation of j| patrimonialism's extreme form, "sultanism," was neglected by scholars.8 The term was adopted by Juan Linz in his classification of nondemocratic governments. When he began working on Spain's Franco regime in the late 1950s, he soon realized that the model of "totalitarianism" then current, based on the Stalinist and Nazi experience, did not fit. The result was the conceptualization of the "authoritarian" regime, whose different aspects he explored in a series of essays.9 A meeting with a Spanish exile was to convince him that the [ authoritarian/totalitarian dichotomy did not exhaust the range of nondemo- j cratic regimes either. In the early 1950s Linz met his Spanish compatriot Jesus J de Galindez, a representative of the exiled Basque government, who had taught \ international law in the Dominican Republic. Although a republican emigre, \ Galindez was treated courteously by Spanish diplomats in New York. But when | he wrote a doctoral dissertation at Columbia University revealing some of the ; inside workings of the Trujillo regime, he confided to Juan Linz in 1955 that he feared for his life, and that he had deposited his manuscript in a safe place in 1 case something happened to him. Soon afterward the dictator had Galindez abducted in New York and taken to the Dominican Republic, where he was tortured to death.10 The contrast between Franco's nondemocratic regime and Trujillo's rule led to the conceptualization of a regime type for which Linz borrowed Weber's term "sultanism," since it too rested on the extreme development of the ruler's discretion. Moreover, Weber, although constructing the ideal type of sultanism in a section on traditional authority, explicitly contrasted the traditional basis of patrimonialism with the discretionary aspect of sultanism (see quotation above), implying that tradition played little role in the latter. Just as Franco's rule became the archetype of an authoritarian regime, Trujillo's became that of a sultanistic regime in Linz's 1973 classification of nondemocratic regimes." Subsequently a number of scholars confirmed the applicability of Linz's paradigm to a number of regimes not mentioned in the 1975 article. Crawford Young and Thomas Turner wrote about Mobutu's regime in Zaire that "in the personalist patrimonial state fashioned by Mobutu, we may discern much that resembles what Linz, borrowing a Weberian term, has labelled 'sultanism.' "12 Terry Karl characterized the regimes of Juan Vicente Gomez and Marcos Perez Jimenez in Venezuela as sultanistic, and H. E. Chehabi explored how the Shah of Iran's sultanism contributed to the Islamic revolution. For the Philippines, John Thayer Sidel applied it to local politics, and Mark Thompson to Marcos's rule. Finally, Samuel Huntington..wro^ such as those of Marcos and Ceausescu, like.those.of.Somoza, Duvalier,,Mobutu, and the Shah, exemplified Weber's model of sultanistic regime characterized by patronage, nepotíšmrcfonýism, and-corruption."13 The criticism so often leveled against inductively derived theoretical concepts—that since, in Pareto's words, they lead "from facts to concepts, and from concepts back to facts,"14 they produce circular argument—does not apply to sultanism as a concept, since it has fruitfully been applied to a different set of facts. Independently of Linz's revival of the term, Richard Sandbrook called Weber's notion of sultanism "more relevant to the circumstances of contemporary Africa." He added that it nourished "under a number of guises: civilian, quasi-military or military forms of government, one-party or competitive-party systems or even under the socialist veneer of Guinea, Benin, and the Republic of Congo."15 At the 1990 conference on which this book is based, the late David Nicholls pointed out that whereas Weber's sultanism was a subtype of traditional authority, our cases were characterized by the decay or incomplete development of modern legal-rational authority rather than by the disappearance of all 6 " COMPARATIVE STUDIES 1 A Theory ofSultanism 1 • 7 TABLE 1.1 Types of Patrimonial Rule Type of Authority Extreme Form Traditional form Modern form Patrimonialism Ne op atrimonialism Sultanism Neosultanism remnants of traditional •authority^It4s4ndeed-lMe-lbat-fee^epraes-we-stu that sultanism subverts accountability and predictability, it thwarts sustainable '-, accumulation. The characteristics of sultanistic regimes can further be grasped if we com-| pare them with the other types of nondemocratic systems. ; Sultanism and Other Types of Nondemocratic Rule Since so many of our cases are in Latin America, it is important to define the difference between sultanistic rulers and the traditional caudillos of that continent. Caudillos were a product of the nineteenth century. In the wake of independence, as state authority disintegrated, military leaders based in the rural areas seized power at the head of armed bands of loyal followers and thus filled the vacuum of authority.94 Some became state builders: Uruguay owes its existence to General Jose Gervasio Artigas. Unlike modern sultanistic rulers, whose 1 power derives from existing structures at the center of the polity, the caudillos had a more local base, possessed genuine leadership qualities, and at least initially, inspired personal loyalty.95 Although there is some resemblance between caudillism and sultanism, and though such sultanistic dictators as Rafael [ Trujillo and the first Somoza perhaps evinced some continuity with the caudi- i llos of an earlier age, the typical sultanistic ruler does not partake of the heroic world of the traditional caudillo; the sort of mythology and folklore that caudillism begot is unlikely to be engendered by sultanism. Sultanism differs from totalitarianism in that, like authoritarianism, it lacks S a genuine ideology, articulated by pro-regime intellectuals, to legitimizeit and guide its policy formulation, Romania and North Korea, where Ceausescu and ■ Kim Il-sung did take Marxism-Leninism seriously, are obvious exceptions here, but in the Dominican Republic too, ideologues such as Joaquin Balaguer elabo- 24 • COMPARATIVE STUDIES A Theory ofSultanism 1 ' 25 rated a detailed ideology that claimed to guide Dominicans toward democracy but was honest enough not to call the regime democratic.96 As we have seen, some sultanistic rulers produce (or have ghostwriters produce) something they like to call "ideology." But we have only to think of the appeal totalitarian ideologies have for intellectuals not subject to their rule, for young people, and for students to perceive the absence of anything remotely similar under sultan-ism. No one not subject to-their rule, not-even most-of-thcirsupportcrs and probably not even the rulers themselves, takes these ideological efforts seriously: they are pseudo-ideologies. Another major difference from totalitarian regimes is the fusion between the private and the public roles of the ruler and the lack of commitment to impersonal purposes. Totalitarian dictators such as Stalin, Hitler, Mao, and Castro believe in meir.,qwii mission, and so do their followers. ThereJs a purpose to :heir ru e other than personal enrVhrrunt. and for this cause they succeed in mobilizing intellectuals not only in their own societies but also outside. In addition, they cultivate an ascetic image (which may or may not reflect their true nature) that is quite at variance with the undisguised hedonism of most (but not all) sultanistic rulers and especially their relatives and cronies. „A IhW.difference with. totalitarian regimes, and a consequence of the previous two, is the absence not only of a single party but also of the ancillary organizations such.as women's groups and youth groups that were so essential toj^fazism andcommunism. Related to this is the absence of continuous political mobilization for a variety of tasks that provide a sense of participation in social and political life. As inaufJioritarian systems, passivity and apathy characterize sultanistic regimes, which offer few, if any, channels for participation, even to their supporters. Thi final rfiffftiyn^fairn^atitarianiCTn is that sultanistic regimes penetrate their societies very unevenly. Those areas ofpublic rtfeTHaTthreaten the ruling group's extraction ofresource^ such as the press, may be cqntroUedto a degree approximating totalitarianism, while others are left alone. Somoza's acquiescence to de facto autonomy for the Indians of the Atlantic coast is an example,97 Even in tightly centralized Pahlavi Iran, the state's penetration of distant Baluchistan province was less thorough than elsewhere. As in all regimes, the specific traits of a sultanistic regime are most developed at the top, elite level. In a modern society, the post office and certain administrations like the judiciary (political cases excepted) will work in similar ways for most people no matter what the political regime. In rural areas village life may go on relatively untouched by the changes at the center. Sultanistic regimes differ from authoritarian regimes in a number of ways. * Authoritarian regimes are more institutionalized, and the limited political,, and I "even more important, social pluralism they tolerate creates a variety of struc- | tures that support the regime, which recruits its elites from them. The much I simpler clientelist structures, the absence of predictable paths of career ad- f vancement in the bureaucracy and the army, the arbitrary recruitment by the ; ruler of his lieutenants thus contrast with authoritarian regimes, although in '■ this case the contrast is less sharp than with totalitarianism. I The secpjxd,difference js the absence of the rule of law, be it a repressive one: '• sultanistic regimes constantly violate their own norms. Moreover, in line with I the constitutional facade they maintain, sultanisttc.regimes.ciften privatize re- ; pression, in the sense that it is carried out by informal groups in the service of the ruler as well as by formally, constituted state agencies implementing ex-pliritly repressive legislation.98 Ujjd-e.^ of peo- ple's basic human rights, is arbitrary rand may strike supporters and opponents : S of the regime alike, giving rise to pervasiveJgaiuand. suspicion in society." In ! any event, sultanistic regimes can exercise degrees of repression ranging from ;« the relatively benign reign of Batista100 to the demented paranoia of Macias Nguema, who is estimated to have been responsible for a minimum of fifty ■ I thousand deaths, drove a third of his country's population into exile, and eliminated its intelligentsia on a scale comparable only to the Khmer Rouge.101 I Regimes that act illegally according to their own laws create uncertainty and : I unpredictability in public life.This capriciousness has an adverse effect on eco- : nomic development, among other things, since entrepreneurs who lack con- t nections to the ruler cannot plan ahead rationally, a point we will come back to. Oppositional, actiyity:against sultanistic regimes otter, coikvir.r.iios abmac. ■ as sultanistic domination drives many citizens, especially intellectuals, into exile. These exiles can be a fertile base for oppositional undertakings, since they i deeply resent not only the corruption and repression at home, but also the ideological vacuum behind it. Intellectuals are more likely to excuse repression when it is carried out in the name of a transformational ideology ("You can't make an omelette without breaking eggs") than when it is exercised for private gain. This resentment is heightened by the tendency in many sultanistic regimes to expand the repressive activities of the state abroad: opponents in exile : are often kidnapped or killed. The existence of an opposition in exile compli- cates political life in the event of an overthrow of the sultanistic regime.102 f 2 A Theory ofSultanism 2 Genesis and Demise of Sultanistic Regimes H. E. Chehabi and Juan J. Linz The Genesis ofSultanism Sultanistic regimes have been relatively few in number, and almost all have by now disappeared. However, the appearance of new sultanism cannot be excluded. Sultanistic regimes are unlikely to be established in advanced industrial soaetiesjjyet an underdeveloped economy is not a sufficient precondition for . the emergence of sultanism, The factors favoring the emergence of sultanism are both macrostructural and institutional, but these variables do not explain everything: the presence or absence in a given society of individuals who are willing to become sultanistic rulers matters as well.1 Macrostructural Factors Two sets of factors stand out: economic conditions and the international environment. Socioeconomic Conditions About patrimonial structures Weber wrote that "little can be said about purely economic preconditions for [their] rise.'" Matters are slightly different for modern sultanistic regimes: although there are no necessary and sufficient A Theory of Sultanism 2 ' 27 conditions for their emergence, it is nonetheless possible to identify certain factors that help bring them about. The stabilization and continuity of sultanistic regimes require a certain modernization of transportation and communications as well as of the military and police organizations and some civilian administrations, to provide funds to sustain the rule and prevent threats to it. Thej.soJa,ticalj0! the; rural masses, their Ja.ds-fit-Cdiicatj.Qn, and their poverty are probably necessary to ensure their passivejjubnji^