Cambridge Journal of Economics 2001, 25, 809–825 CRITICAL SURVEY This is the latest in our series of Critical Survey articles. The aim of the series is to report on recent developments, to provide an assessment of alternative approaches and to suggest lines of future inquiry. The intention is that the articles should be accessible not only to other academic researchers but also to students and others more practically involved in the economy. Recent Survey articles include Ron Martin on ‘The New “Geographical Turn in Economics”’, Sergio Cesaratto on ‘Saving and Economic Growth in Neoclassical Theory’ and Ben Fine on ‘Endogenous Growth Theory’. New trade theory versus old trade policy: a continuing enigma Sonali Deraniyagala and Ben Fine* This paper examines the theoretical and empirical grounds for trade liberalisation. We note that many of the conventional arguments relating to the static and dynamic gains from liberalisation are based on fragile theoretical grounds. We also show that, although new trade theory takes account of some of the complexities of international trade and although the analytical thrust of many models justifies intervention, such policy conclusions are rejected even by those at the forefront of these theories on the grounds of political economy arguments which do not stand up to careful scrutiny. Finally, we show that arguments favouring trade liberalisation are not supported by existing empirical research, which generally fails to capture the complex and ambiguous effects of liberalisation and openness. Keywords: Trade, Trade policy, Country and industry studies of trade JEL classifications: F12, F14, F43 Introduction As reported in Prasch (1996), support for free trade amongst academic economists in the USA is astonishingly high at 97%! It has enabled Anne Krueger (1997),1 Chief Economist at the World Bank during the 1980s and chief promoter of the neoliberal Washington consensus, to engage in a history of economic thought in which the central question becomes one of explaining why economists should have resisted the charms of free trade Manuscript received 9 April 1999; final version received 25 November 1999. Address for correspondence: Professor B. Fine, Department of Economics, SOAS, University of London, Thornhaugh Street, Russell Square, London WC1H 0XG, UK; email bf@soas.ac.uk * SOAS, University of London. This article was completed while Ben Fine was in receipt of a Research Fellowship from the UK Economic and Social Research Council (ESRC) under award number R000271046 to study ‘The New Revolution in Economics and Its Impact upon Social Sciences’. It draws upon Fine (1997). 1 See also Krueger (1998) and response from Ocampo and Taylor (1998). © Cambridge Political Economy Society 2001 CJE 25/6 pps. FINAL 809-825 19/9/01 9:54 am Page 809 810 S. Deraniyagala and B. Fine for so long, given both its virtues in practice and its centrality within standard theory of comparative advantage. Her answer essentially boils down to the idea that otherwise idle theorists have made mischief by deploying models of market imperfections without due regard to the stylised facts. In short, for her, if the stylised (neoclassical) theory does not support the stylised policies, it’s time to get real. However, as will be shown in much of the discussion that follows, the recent trade literature has, within the confines of an evolving neoclassical theory of market imperfections, made great attempts to address at least some of the realities of trade. By doing so, from the perspective of neoliberalism, it has been extremely mischievous, if not troublesome, in view of the extent to which its conclusions have been over-ruled by the forward march of support for trade liberalisation. This paper critically examines the theoretical and empirical grounds for trade liberalisation. We note that many of the conventional arguments relating to the static and dynamic gains from liberalisation are based on fragile theoretical grounds. We also show that, although new trade theory takes account of some of the complexities of international trade and although the analytical thrust of many models justifies intervention, such policy conclusions are rejected even by those at the forefront of these theories, on the grounds of political economy arguments which do not stand up to careful scrutiny. Finally, we show that arguments favouring trade liberalisation are not supported by existing empirical research, which generally fails to capture the complex and ambiguous effects of liberalisation and openness. Section 1 examines conventional theoretical arguments relating to trade liberalisation and Section 2 reviews recent developments in new trade theory. Section 3 examines the empirical research relating to liberalisation dealing with both cross-country research and industry and firm-level studies. We close with a brief summary. 1. Conventional arguments for trade liberalisation The literature on trade liberalisation differentiates between the static and dynamic gains from trade policy reform. While the economic arguments relating to static gains are straightforward, it is also generally acknowledged that the magnitude of these gains is fairly low. Static, once-and-for-all gains arise as the misallocation of resources under protection and import substitution is corrected, and resources shift from inefficient to efficient sectors, activities and firms. The gains take the form of the well-known Harberger welfare triangles. However, empirical estimates of the welfare costs of these relative-price distortions rarely exceed 2 or 3 percentage points of GDP (Bhagwati, 1993; Pursell, 1990). The response of mainstream theorists to these negligible welfare gains has been to extend these welfare triangles by emphasising the dynamic, long-term gains from liberalisation. While a range of arguments relating to long-term benefits have been produced, closer scrutiny shows them to hinge on fairly arbitrary assumptions, and to be thus lacking both theoretical consistency and empirical validity. One way of inflating welfare triangles has been to incorporate rent seeking, with the focus being on the calculation of welfare losses from government trade interventions, especially the introduction of import quotas. It has been argued that the resource costs of trade interventions are multiplied severalfold by the existence of rent seeking. Empirical estimates have shown the magnitudes of the costs to be large (de Melo and Robinson, 1982; Gallagher, 1991; Tarr, 1992). As Ocampo and Taylor (1998) note, however, it is difficult to accept these estimates at face value; if quotas cover only a fraction of imports and if imports are only a fraction of GDP, rents and rent-seeking outlays cannot be CJE 25/6 pps. FINAL 809-825 19/9/01 9:54 am Page 810 New trade theory versus old trade policy 811 significant. It is also interesting to note that there has been little empirical research on whether rents have actually declined following liberalisation. This is especially so of institutions such as the research department of the World Bank, which has undertaken large multi-country studies to establish the gains from liberalisation. Onis (1991) is a notable exception, showing that Turkish policy moves towards export orientation gave rise to a new type of rent seeking directed at obtaining export quotas. Another argument relating to the dynamic gains from liberalisation centres around X-efficiency and entrepreneurial effort. By reducing competition and increasing relative prices in import-competing sectors, protection encourages entrepreneurial slack. Formal representations of this argument have revealed its fragility (Tybout, 1992). It only holds when the entrepreneurial labour supply curve is upward sloping in the relevant range and when changes in work incentives operate in the same direction for both exporters and import-substituting producers. As we show in Section 3, the empirical evidence relating to trade policy and efficiency also fails to provide conclusive support for this argument. Increasing returns to scale (IRS) are frequently cited as an important source of dynamic gains from liberalisation. Firms in more open trade can supposedly operate at lower costs owing to higher levels of output, available through participating in world markets. This argument, however, is based on the assumption that liberalisation necessarily expands IRS activities. If scale economies are mainly concentrated in protected sectors which decline following trade reform, this type of dynamic gain will not materialise. As Rodrik (1994, p. 159) notes, ‘whether scale effects add or subtract from resource allocation effects depend on a variety of factors with no clear-cut presumption either way’. Another variant of this argument is that protection increases profitability and leads to the coexistence of too many firms producing at below minimum efficient scale. Liberalisation, therefore, leads to industry rationalisation and allows firms to benefit from scale effects and produce at lower average costs. Again, this argument is also questionable, as it assumes easy and frictionless entry into and exit from markets. Long-term productivity gains are also seen to ensue from the correction of the anticompetition, anti-export bias of protection which will have discouraged cost-cutting technological change. In much of the policy literature on developing countries, the precise mechanism by which trade reform has promoted technological dynamism has never been fully spelt out (e.g., Balassa, 1988). Increased levels of competition are taken as sufficient to generate increased innovative activity and productivity gains across all sectors. The fact that relative-price distortions such as tariffs may adversely affect learning and technology development in some sectors but not in others, and the possibility that various instruments of trade intervention may have differential consequences for innovative activity, have not always been considered. More importantly, the simplistic notion that high levels of competition unambiguously promote technological change ignores the well-established body of research on market structure and innovation, which indicates that this is not necessarily true (Evenson and Westphal, 1995). Such assertions about the beneficial effects of trade-related competition on innovation are also found in recent analyses which otherwise claim to question the mainstream approach to trade policy adopted by the World Bank and the International Monetary Fund (IMF), in forming a new ‘PostWashington Consensus’ (Stiglitz, 1998). Overall, a general feature of conventional arguments relating to the dynamic effects of trade liberalisation is that they are not located within a coherent theory of industrial performance. In recent years, considerable attention has been focused on technology-related factors in influencing firm and industry-level productivity and the fact that technology CJE 25/6 pps. FINAL 809-825 19/9/01 9:54 am Page 811 812 S. Deraniyagala and B. Fine development is the outcome of a complex interaction of supply-side and demand-side factors. That these are highly sector and country specific (such as technological skills and institutions, scientific and technological paradigms, relative price and demand changes and so on) has been emphasised (Evenson and Westphal, 1995). The adaptive and incremental types of below-the-frontier type of technological activity typically undertaken by developing country firms have also been shown to be the outcome of such processes (Bell and Pavitt, 1992). In this context, to expect productivity improvement to be largely determined by trade liberalisation and international competition alone is naïve. As we show below, such notions of industrial performance are evident both in recent trade models which incorporate increasing returns, imperfect competition and technology spillovers and in empirical analyses of liberalisation. 2. New trade theory New trade theory is now entering its middle age, having been established in the 1980s (Ethier, 1982; Krugman, 1984,1986; Brander and Spencer, 1985; Eaton and Grossman, 1986; Grossman and Horn, 1988; Grossman and Helpman, 1991). In general, its models attempt to address the shortcomings of standard trade theory by dealing with some of the realities of trade in a more complex and sophisticated manner by incorporating a fuller range of factors. However, they provide few, if any, unambiguous conclusions. New trade models incorporate four innovations within neoclassical economics: market imperfections, strategic behaviour and the new industrial economics, new growth theory and political economy arguments. Many of the models based on market imperfections and strategic behaviour justify interventionist trade policy. While much of the literature linking trade and new growth theory favours trade liberalisation (mainly on the grounds of knowledge spillovers), here too the possibility that free trade may be detrimental to economic growth is allowed for. Overall, however, interventionist trade policies are rejected even by those at the forefront of these theories, mainly on the basis of political economy arguments (such as rent seeking). Below, we examine the fragility of these political economy arguments when we discuss the four innovations linked to new trade theory in detail. 2.1 Market imperfections and strategic behaviour First, the IRS conventionally used to justify protection have been complemented by a range of other market imperfections. These include informational asymmetries and imperfections which inform so much of recent innovation within mainstream microeconomics, which is itself usually seamlessly transformed into understandings of the economy as a whole. Second, new trade theory also draws upon the new industrial economics, with models incorporating the strategic behaviour of all agents, firms as well as governments. This involves game theory, intertemporal optimisation, and issues of time consistency, especially for government policy (the possibility of changing policy commitments after the private sector has invested, of which the latter can be aware).1 We shall address the literature around these two sets of innovations together. Informational asymmetries and adjustment costs are dealt with in models which consider optimal technology choice over time. Ohyama and Jones (1995) allow for one 1 See McKay and Milner (1997) for problems in the design of policy so that ex post outcomes coincide with ex ante intent. CJE 25/6 pps. FINAL 809-825 19/9/01 9:54 am Page 812 New trade theory versus old trade policy 813 country deliberately to fall behind another so that, with adjustment costs, leaping ahead in the future becomes less expensive. It becomes possible to explain both falling behind, catch-up and leapfrogging. Leahy and Neary (1996) consider such issues in the context of R&D rivalry, although Durkin (1997) shows that pursuit of comparative advantage in producing technological progress itself can lead to inefficiency (home country may be better at producing innovation in the factor-rich sector of the other country!). In models involving strategic behaviour, results differ depending upon stylised assumptions. Various assumptions about the sorts of competition and oligopolistic behaviour considered are made. Thus, Bhattacharjea (1995) finds that both strategic industrial policy (on entry/exit) and tariffs are necessary under imperfect competition at home and abroad and endogenous market structure. Fuerst and Kim (1997) and van Long and Soubeyran (1997) take account of heterogeneity in costs functions, with trade policy affecting the distribution of production across (more or less efficient) firms within countries as well as across countries. The effect of vertical integration is modelled by Bernhofen (1997), Ziss (1997), Holm (1997) and Jie-A-Joen (1997). Pal and White (1998) incorporate considerations of privatisation (the removal of a firm that acts strategically to maximise domestic welfare rather than profit), and Devereux and Lee (1999) address interaction with internationalisation of financial markets and extent of trading in productive assets across countries. Strategic trade models also involve consideration of the policy instruments that governments are allowed to deploy and the sequencing of decision-making. Sleuwagen et al. (1998) examine the issue of cascading protection—to what extent and in what circumstances is protection passed on and how are its costs and benefits distributed. Karp and Perloff (1995) find differential effects of protection when policy instruments are targeted at investment as opposed to output (not affecting or affecting long-term outcomes, res- pectively). The relevance of these new trade models to developing countries has been debated (Lucas, 1988; Bardhan, 1995; Ruttan, 1998). While some strategic models with oligopolistic players dominating world markets may be of limited relevance to low-income developing countries (Stewart, 1991), arguments for intervention based on scale economies and imperfect competition are widespread in developing countries, rendering these theories especially relevant for them (Helleiner, 1992). Empirical evidence indicates that imperfect competition is indeed rampant (Lee, 1992), although the evidence on scale economies is much more limited. Thus, models based on strategic behaviour are highly diverse, given the underlying factors and assumptions over which they range. But, what they all tend to have in common is the result that strategic trade policy is justified and, in addition, that it should be complemented by other forms of policy (or take a variety of forms). Such a conclusion should not come as a surprise, for it is presumably only by accident that free trade will be optimal in the presence of market imperfections and, further, the more numerous the imperfections, the more instruments we need to deal with them. Further, given the diversity of the models, it also follows that interventions will need to be selective and country/ sector specific depending upon the type and strength of market imperfections involved. Of course, the standard neoliberal response to these models is to claim that government has neither the knowledge nor the ability to be selective in its policy interventions. The supposedly large informational requirements are one reason why the analytical thrust of trade theory in justifying interventionist trade policy has been rejected even by those at the forefront of the theory. Yet, the literature is itself well suited to handle such issues, since it CJE 25/6 pps. FINAL 809-825 19/9/01 9:54 am Page 813 814 S. Deraniyagala and B. Fine has drawn upon the economics of imperfect and asymmetric information. If governments are less well-informed than the private sector (and less able), does it follow they should do nothing? The answer is resoundingly in the negative and should not come as a surprise. For the implication is that we should leave the generals and the military industrial complex to make defence policy since they know more about waging war and the true costs and capabilities of weapons.1 Clearly, as in any principal–agent problem, there is a trade-off between (lesser) knowledge and (others’) motives. Brainard and Martimort (1997) address the issue directly as suggested by the title of their paper.2 Their conclusion is striking: Attainment of the informationally constrained social optimum requires a complicated menu of contracts combining per-unit subsidies and lump-sum transfers. (p. 56) Even more remarkable is the conclusion reached by Creane (1998) to the effect that policymakers may be better off, and justified in using trade policy, the less information that they have. It is not, however, necessary to engage in trade theory to see why this conclusion arises in the context of imperfect competition. For, consider a monopolist who wishes to exercise product discrimination. To do so, customers (including countries contemplating trade policy) must have the knowledge to discriminate between products (as is recognised in practice by advertising irrespective of whether ‘genuine’ differences are created). Without this, monopolists may be forced to rely upon a more Pareto-efficient but less profitable strategy and be unable to exploit product discrimination. Nor is this some esoteric point in the context of development where, both for welfare and growth, economies may be better served by supplying a cheap mass market than in targeting a more profitable elite. 2.2 Links with new growth theory Apart from strategic behaviour and market imperfections, the new trade theory is integrated with the new growth theory, which is also essentially based upon market imperfections (translated into variable growth rates rather than deadweight loss).3 In endogenous growth theory, the long-run growth rate can be improved by government policy to induce a higher saving rate and/or to incorporate externalities. Models linking trade and endogenous growth have examined the various channels through which trade can influence growth, but provide few generalisable conclusions. Technology and knowledge spillovers are key mechanisms which link international trade and endogenous growth.4 In their classic work, Grossman and Helpman (1991) show how international trade can boost a country’s Research and Development (R&D) sector (the sector which drives economic growth) by transmitting technological information, increasing competition and entrepreneurial effort and expanding the size of the market in which innovative firms operate. But, trade can also have negative effects on the R&D sector by displacing innovative activities, making the overall effects of trade openness ambiguous. Other technology-based models emphasise the positive effects of openness by focusing on the role of capital goods imports in promoting economic growth (Coe et al., 1995; Lee, 1995; Pissarides, 1997). In these models, technology spillovers are generally proportional 1 Alternatively, to be topical, chemical companies should be allowed to make policy on genetic engineering. 2 See also Wong and Chow (1997) and Wright (1998). 3 For a critical account, see Fine (1999). 4 For an overview of trade, growth and knowledge, see Zhang (1994). CJE 25/6 pps. FINAL 809-825 19/9/01 9:54 am Page 814 New trade theory versus old trade policy 815 to capital goods imports. Imported capital goods embody information about new technologies, and producers who are exposed to this information are seen as more likely to innovate. Romer (1992) describes this as ‘using ideas’ (as opposed to ‘producing ideas’) and Pack (1992) sees them essentially as a free dividend for being a latecomer. Many of these models imply that increased amounts of resources will be devoted to R&D following trade liberalisation. The positive conclusions about openness in these models are largely dependent on specific assumptions about the nature of technology and technology transfer and can be reversed when the definition of technology is refined. Most models assume that technology can be perfectly codified and easily transferred. If, however, we acknowledge that learning by importing capital goods is partly dependent on the absorptive capacity of countries, the gains from trade (especially for poorer countries) may be more limited. Keller (1996) presents a model which differentiates between technology embodied in capital goods and capabilities (or ‘absorptive capacity’). Using a Rivera-Batiz and Romer (1991) type endogenous growth model, he shows that the productivity and growth effects of increased access to foreign capital goods will be short lived unless absorptive capacity increases at a more rapid rate than during the period prior to trade reform. In the long run, the rate of growth of output is forced down to the rate of human capital growth. Similarly, Van de Klundert and Smulders (1996) allow for technology spillovers between North and South, but the latter’s low level of high-tech production limits learning by doing.1 In the light of recent evidence, that increased openness leads to less investment in human capital at the secondary and tertiary levels (Wood and Ridao-Cano, 1999), this all implies that the gains for poor countries from access to technology imports can be limited. A negative conclusion about the effects of openness is also reached by a few recent endogenous trade models which revisit infant industry arguments by explicitly dealing with the role of learning under protection in countries with low levels of industrialisation. In these models, poor countries are shown to specialise in low technology products if free trade is allowed, but trade restrictions allow them to develop complex industries (see Reddy, 1999). These ambiguous results of endogenous growth/trade models are complicated further by the fact that growth-enhancing trade policies do not always improve welfare. Thus, Westerhout (1995) focuses on consumer variety and allows firms to exit and enter. With trade liberalisation, consumer prices and costs of production are lower but so can be product variety, as domestic producers are eliminated, and this can outweigh the other effects on consumer welfare. For a small open economy, Osang and Pereira (1996) find that all tariffs are damaging to long-run growth but there can be increases in welfare in the short run.2 In addition, there is no reason to presume that tariffs should be uniform across goods in maximising intertemporal welfare. Models linking growth and trade also deal with the issue of convergence. Again, they provide few robust conclusions, with convergence or divergence depending upon how openly competitive is international trade. Boileau’s (1996) model allows for international externalities, but with non-traded and non-market production within countries. He is able to generate growth and cycles in which, contrary to most models and in conformity with received wisdom, cross-country correlations on output exceed those of consumption 1 See also Walde (1996), who suggests that, with perfect international technical spill-over, convergence will depend upon conditions of competition. 2 See also Kaneda (1995) who shows in presence of increasing returns that the one country of two with lower time preference is liable to industrialise first. CJE 25/6 pps. FINAL 809-825 19/9/01 9:54 am Page 815 816 S. Deraniyagala and B. Fine and productivity. Lau and Wan (1994) argue that trade is necessary but not sufficient for poorer countries to converge. For middle-income countries will be able to accrue the benefits of catch-up since the costs of doing so declines with growth, whereas the poorest countries will experience a widening income gap. A complex model is provided by Fischer and Serra (1996) in which the domestic economy grows faster the greater the level of equality because of higher incentives and returns to investment in human capital.1 As growth rises, unskilled labour may be rewarded more as it becomes scarcer, but inequality may also increase as the wealthier invest more in human capital. With a world economy of rich and poor countries, free trade is in part disadvantageous for the former in raising inequality at once (skilled labour is immediately worth more in opening up to trade) and over time, and in lowering the growth rate as poorer countries converge. Poor countries unambiguously gain from each of these effects. The implication is free trade for poor countries and subsidised education for the worse-off in rich countries. 2.3 Political economy arguments In short, the marriage between new trade and growth theories serves to render each more complex. In addition, they also tend to share a particularly underdeveloped notion of what constitutes a nation. Indeed, in conformity with longstanding traditions in trade theory, the nation is simply a special individual, usually with both benevolent goals (social welfare) and special powers (policy).2 A simple step is taken to progress beyond such simplicity once account is taken of internal influences upon government policy, thereby incorporating a fourth factor in new trade theory, that of political economy in general and rent seeking in particular. Rodrik and Fouroutan (1998), for example, debate whether trade liberalisation has stalled in Africa because of a combination of distributional and informational problems (who knows consequences and who gets compensated for them).3 Fung (1995) examines the redistribution between capital and labour as rents are shifted and shared with change in trade policy in the presence of oligopoly. In a model of electoral competition, Riezman and Wilson (1997) find that limits on number of donors and amounts of donations by interest groups can lead to inefficiency in the making of trade policy. Most important, though, in the political economy of trade policy have been the rentseeking arguments. It is as if all of the above can be set aside, since to act upon their prescriptions is to solicit unproductive rent seeking through trade policy. Here, however, there is a major problem. If there are underlying economic and political interests in favour of trade policy, why would they allow trade liberalisation to proceed? And, if they have no choice, might they not engage in even more costly forms of pursuing their advantage? This is exactly what is perceived to have happened, if not anticipated, in the wake of the Uruguay Round, with trade policy pursued by other means and, most notably, through antidumping measures which have become the new form of (privatised) trade policy in the WTO era.4 1 See also Gould and Ruffin (1995) for the case that human capital is crucial to growth and trade. 2 Hence the capacity for the theory to move effortlessly between lower and higher levels than the nation. See Krugman and Elizondo (1996) for the idea that third world cities are too large because of economies of linkages accruing out of ISI. See also Lall (1998). For new trade theory and regional integration (and idea that this can even intensify internal protection), see Bilal (1998). 3 See also Edwards (1997). 4 This is the subject of a separate paper in preparation. But for a comprehensive empirical overview, see Miranda et al. (1998). CJE 25/6 pps. FINAL 809-825 19/9/01 9:54 am Page 816 New trade theory versus old trade policy 817 3. Empirical evidence Empirical research has examined the effects of trade liberalisation on growth, productivity and efficiency at cross-country, industry and firm level. Below, we discuss each of them in turn. 3.1 Cross-country research The country-level research on liberalisation and growth consists of cross-section ‘before and after’ studies (Greenaway et al., 1997), and ‘with and without’ studies (Mosley et al., 1991; World Bank, 1990) as well as of country-specific time-series analysis (Papageorgiou et al., 1991; Greenaway and Sapsford, 1994; Onafowora et al., 1996). In general, many of these studies suggest that the effects of liberalisation on growth are ambiguous and complex: while some groups of countries show an improvement in growth (as well as other indicators such as investment), others show a marked deterioration. Here again, however, the alternative models provide very different estimates of the long-run effects on growth (with the pay-off ranging from 2% to 46% !), indicating the limitations of capturing complicated growth effects using cross-country single-equation growth regressions (discussed below). At best, most of the literature seeking to investigate the effects of shifts in trade policy (towards liberalisation) develops a model from which a reduced form is estimated. At worst, simple regressions are run on some index of economic performance against some index of openness (although the best and worst often coincide in practice). Here, we leave aside perennial problems (like much of the literature!) concerning the data, and how we measure openness,1 the value for an individual country’s development over time for what are often cross-section studies, the fallacy of composition—if all liberalise, export prices may fall2 —and the direction of causation between variables. Consider, however, two problems that are generally overlooked. The first is that only a single equation tends to be estimated rather than a model. However, even if a significant and desired result is obtained, this is not a proper test of the theory. For, within the model, there will be implicit mechanisms through which trade policy has affected trade performance. These include both shifts in composition of output and in capital–labour ratios as well as shifts in domestic prices, factor rewards and composition of consumption. These usually remain unexamined. If, as is to be expected,3 such empirical regularities do not hold, to what extent is the theory properly tested? To be more concrete, if trade liberalisation in a labour-rich economy is associated with growth in capital-intensive exports, there will be an apparent connection between trade reform and export growth, but not for the reasons posited. The second point is a more developed form of the first and is to be learnt from the more sophisticated treatments of the endogenous growth literature.4 The models involved in 1 See Greenaway et al. (1998) for a discussion. Note that the problems in measuring openness are recognised theoretically by the wish to construct sensible indices, as in the notion of a uniform-tariff welfareequivalent to any existing level of protection. See Anderson (1995, 1998) and Anderson and Neary (1996). These measures, however, depend upon genuine equilibrium comparative statistics and cannot eliminate the problem of perverse prices, that increases in a tariff may be equivalent to a decrease in (effective) protection. In addition, in the absence of perfect competition, as is well-known, export subsidies and tariff reductions (or other trade measures) are not equivalent to one another for a variety of reasons for both partial and general equilibrium. See Chen and Devereux (1997) and Okawa (1997), for example. 2 See Bandyopadhyay (1996). 3 Not least from the theory itself in view of the discussion above! 4 These points are discussed at length in Fine (1999) and carry over, if less observed in the literature, from statistical investigation of growth to trade performance. CJE 25/6 pps. FINAL 809-825 19/9/01 9:54 am Page 817 818 S. Deraniyagala and B. Fine the new trade theory, even with a few factors, are extremely complicated in terms of their outcomes—potentially generating multiple equilibria and complex patterns of adjustment to or around them. For a single economy, this raises issues of what exactly we are estimating—comparison of static equilibria or paths between equilibria. For a cross-section of economies, trade performances cannot be taken to be independent of one another. Countries serve the same world market, one country’s exports are another’s imports, and economic variables are not independent of one another, given flows of capital, labour and technology, quite apart from strategic behaviour of firms and governments, etc. Ideally, of course, the dynamics of trade performance would be properly modelled, and models fully estimated across panel data. The literature generally falls far short. Even so, it is far from supportive of the trade liberalisation hypothesis. Neatly illustrating some of these observations is the study of Greenaway et al. (1998), who use panel data across liberalisers and non-liberalisers (with/without and before/after) to come to a negative conclusion on the effect of trade reform on growth but then suggest this may be due to a shorter-run J-curve impact of liberalisation. 3.2 Industry and firm-level studies A substantial body of empirical literature has focused on the dynamic effects of trade liberalisation and has investigated the effects of trade policy and openness on total factor productivity and efficiency at the industry level. Evidence from these studies, however, is inconclusive. Some early empirical exercises found a negative (but weak) correlation between import substitution and productivity growth (Nishimuzu and Robinson, 1984), others showed TFP growth rates to be high in highly protected industrial sectors (Waverman and Murphy, 1992), while continued and accelerating TFP growth rates in both periods of high and low protection have also been reported (Aswicahyono et al., 1996). High levels of import penetration have also been found to be associated with low rates of productivity growth (Nishimuzu and Page, 1991). Given the varying country coverage of these studies, the different industrial sectors included and the varying definitions of liberalisation and openness used, attempting to provide a rigorous net balance of the evidence would serve little purpose. Some key weaknesses of these industry-level studies, however, must be noted. None of them discriminates between the effects of trade policy and macro policy choices and it is, therefore, difficult to attribute causality to trade policy itself. Many of them also fail to control adequately for other influences on productivity growth. In particular, the failure to control for industry effects is especially problematic. The firm-level literature circumvents the need to control for industry effects, but still fails to establish a direct causal link between trade liberalisation and improved economic performance. Much of this literature examines the link between trade liberalisation, openness and firm-level efficiency estimated using frontier-production-functions. Some studies find support for the conjecture that efficiency levels are highest among industries experiencing the largest declines in protection (Tybout et al., 1991). The firm-level literature also examines the relationship between export-orientation and productivity/ efficiency, although the link between trade liberalisation and exporting is not empirically investigated. Several studies have found exporting firms to be more efficient than their domestically oriented counterparts (Chen and Tang, 1987; Haddad, 1993; Aw and Hwang, 1994; Tybout and Westbrook, 1995; Aw and Batra, 1998), and have attributed this result to the positive learning effects which accrue from contact with foreign buyers. There are three major weaknesses with this firm-level literature. First, most studies CJE 25/6 pps. FINAL 809-825 19/9/01 9:54 am Page 818 New trade theory versus old trade policy 819 examine one-time changes in the level of efficiency and their findings are consistent with the claim that trade liberalisation generates static gains. They, do not however, provide conclusive evidence relating to long-term, dynamic improvements in firm-level efficiency. Secondly, the indicator of firm performance used by many of the studies, total factor productivity, is characterised by theoretical inconsistencies and estimation problems (with Nelson, 1981, providing a critical discussion of these issues). Thirdly, they fail to establish the causal links between trade policy, export orientation and efficiency. For instance, the literature on exporting generally does not ask whether the direction of causality runs from exporting to efficiency or vice versa. The latter is a strong possibility, as more efficient firms are more likely to be competitive in export markets. A study of exporters in Colombia and Morocco attempted to address the causality issue by plotting long-term cost and productivity trajectories (Clerides et al., 1998). They found that entry into export markets does not significantly shift the cost and productivity functions of firms and conclude that the association between exporting and efficiency is most plausibly explained by low-cost producers choosing to become exporters. Finally, much of the firm-level research fails to shed light on the various channels through which trade liberalisation might affect productivity and efficiency in changing populations of heterogeneous firms. A few studies have attempted to do so, focusing on the effects of trade policy on industry rationalisation and entry and exit patterns and costprice ratios (Tybout, 1992; Roberts and Tybout, 1991). Overall, however, no strong conclusions emerge. There is little evidence of an association between import penetration and entry and exit patterns, contrary to predictions that import liberalisation is likely to result in the exit of inefficient firms and the entry of low-cost ones. There is also little support for the argument that liberalisation allows firms to benefit from scale economies. Positive firm-level effects of liberalisation are reported by Steel and Webster (1992) in their study of small firms in Ghana; they found new firms (i.e., those entering after liberalisation) to have faster growth rates than older firms and concluded that this demonstrated that liberalisation brings forth dynamic new entrants. This, however, is highly misleading as the negative relationship between the age of a firm and growth is well established empirically (McPherson, 1995), having little to do with trade policy. The dynamic gains from liberalisation are supposed to accrue largely from technology upgrading but few empirical studies have directly examined the technological response to liberalisation at firm-level. One group of studies has examined the relationship between technology imports and domestic technology development. Both Basant (1993) and Fikkert (1993) found that domestic R&D and foreign technology were substitutes in the case of India. Braga and Wilmore (1991) and Katrak (1997) examine whether improved access to imports increased the extent of R&D at firm-level. They report a positive but weak association between measures of technology imports and R&D. In general, the evidence indicates that the extent to which foreign technology can stimulate R&D depends on factors such as availability of necessary skills and expertise (Evenson and Westphal, 1995). In the context of developing countries, informal technological effort (mainly to modify and adapt foreign technologies) is more relevant than formal R&D, but the links between trade policy and such informal technological activity have rarely been explicitly examined. Some exceptions are Deraniyagala and Semboja (1999) and Latsch and Robinson (1999), who examine the technological response to liberalisation in sub-Saharan African countries. They find very little evidence of widespread technology development following import liberalisation, with most firms being hesitant or unable to invest in new technologies in the CJE 25/6 pps. FINAL 809-825 19/9/01 9:54 am Page 819 820 S. Deraniyagala and B. Fine face of very intense import competition. Well-known qualitative studies of interventionist trade and industrial policies in East Asia have demonstrated in detail their impact on technology strategies, learning effects, entry and exit dynamics and the micro-level aspects of industrial performance, and have highlighted the point that these effects vary considerably according to the type of trade policy and according to the specificities of industrial sectors (Amsden, 1989; Wade, 1990). It is important that empirical research on the effects of trade liberalisation also examines such factors and provides an in-depth analysis of the manner in which various policy instruments affect aspects of performance in specific sectors and in countries at specific levels of development. In general terms, then, existing empirical research on trade liberalisation allows us to make the following observations. First, there is little to suggest that trade policy is itself an important determinant of industrial performance and, even so, a positive role will derive from export expansion (through export performing requirements, for example) rather than from import liberalisation.1 As Helleiner (1994, p. 31) concludes: On the basis of currently available evidence, it is difficult to escape the conclusion that trade policy has not been the major influence on productivity growth in manufacturing that many analysts have said that it should be. Such associations as there have been between productivity growth and trade phenomena relate to the probable positive role of manufactured export expansion, and not to import liberalization. Secondly, at least as important as trade policy have been the other elements of industrial policy, such as R&D, and the impact of technology transfer and the scale and growth of domestic markets. Also important has been the macroeconomic environment, especially the level and stability of the exchange rate, the level of domestic demand and real wage restraint. At a more detailed level of targeting, favourable access to credit can be used to promote exports, especially to complement low levels of domestic demand relative to scale economies. Given the significance of stability in the macroeconomic environment and the structure of incentives to industry, it is hardly surprising that liberalisation beyond trade, to capital markets, has not been favourable to industrial performance. The impact of speculative movements of capital can discourage long-term investment; and attempts to stabilise capital movements and the exchange rate can lead to high interest rates further discouraging domestic economic activity. Thirdly, trade policy involves a very wide variety of complex instruments with an equally varied set of outcomes depending upon how the trade policies interact with other policies and factors in the specific economic conditions in which they operate. Consequently, trade policy should not be seen in isolation from other policies and as a bias in one direction or another. Rather, it needs to be situated carefully in a sectoral context [see, for example, Agosin and Ffrench-Davis (1995) for Latin America and Soludo (1998) for Africa]. But, even more important, the process of restructuring industries, both vertically and horizontally, needs to range far beyond considerations of trade policy alone and to recognise how the structure and functioning of sectors are very different from one to 1 See also the review provided by Edwards (1993, p. 1389), who concludes on the mixed results in favour of trade liberalisation: Much of the cross-country regression based studies have been plagued by empirical and conceptual shortcomings. The theoretical frameworks used have been increasingly simplistic, failing to address important questions such as the exact mechanism through which export expansion affects GDP growth, and ignoring important potential determinants of growth such as educational attainment. All of this has resulted . . . in unconvincing results whose fragility has been exposed by subsequent work. CJE 25/6 pps. FINAL 809-825 19/9/01 9:54 am Page 820 New trade theory versus old trade policy 821 another—by virtue of technology, markets, sources of finance and ownership, vertical integration with other sectors as well as established historical patterns. In short, the factors underlying appropriate trade policy are not only varied and complex but require trade-offs to be made. Macroeconomic conservatism, for example, in order to provide stability for potential investors and exporters, could prove to be a selfdefeating exercise if the level of domestic demand is insufficient to support scale economies. Certainly, however, there is no rationale for accepting the general case in favour of trade liberalisation, and the merits of trade policy need to be examined at a detailed and specific level. Given infant industry considerations, the sequencing as well as the content of policy is crucial, especially as trade, macroeconomic or other policy could kill off infants or even adolescents before they have the opportunity to attain maturity. 5. Concluding remarks A number of conclusions follow from our review. First, free or freer trade is heavily favoured by the economics profession and is gathering momentum under the WTO regime. Secondly, the thrust of theoretical and empirical literature is far from supportive of such postures.1 Thirdly, it is totally inappropriate to address trade theory and policy separately from other aspects of industrial policy and performance and macroeconomic considerations. Fourthly, crude dichotomies such as those between free trade and protection should be rejected and the need recognised for sophisticated, sector- and countryspecific trade and industrial policy and, lastly, in this respect, to the extent that the neoliberal consensus has promoted trade liberalisation, it has done a double disservice both by undermining interventionist trade policy and its integration with other policy areas. Bibliography Agosin, M. and Ffrench-Davis, R. 1995. Trade liberalization and growth: recent experiences in Latin America, Journal of InterAmerican Studies and World Affairs, vol. 37, no. 3, 9–58 Amsden, A 1989. Asia’s Next Giant: South Korea’s Late Industrialisation, Oxford, Oxford University Press Anderson, J. 1995. Tariff index theory, Review of International Economics, vol. 3, no. 2, 156–73 Anderson, J. 1998. Effective protection redux, Journal of International Economics, vol. 44, no. 1, 21–44 Anderson, J. and Neary, J. 1996. A new approach to evaluating trade policy, Review of Economic Studies, vol. 63(1), no. 214, 107–25 Aswicahyono, H., Bird, K. and Hill, H. 1996. What happens to industrial structure when countries liberalise? Journal of Development Studies vol. 32, no. 3, 340–63 Aw, B. and Batra, G. 1998. Technological capability and firm efficiency in Taiwan, World Bank Economic Review, vol. 12, no. 1, 59–79 Aw, B. and Hwang, 1994. ‘Productivity and the Export Market: A Firm-Level Analysis’, Pennsylvania State University, mimeo Balassa, B. 1988. Interests of developing countries in the Uruguay Round, World Economy, vol. 11, no. 1, 39–54 Bandyopadhyay, S. 1996. Growth, welfare and optimal trade taxes: a fallacy of composition, Journal of Development Economics, vol. 50, no. 2, 369–80 Bardhan, P. 1995. The contribution of endogenous growth theory to the analysis of development problems: an assessment, in Behrman, J. and Srinivisan, T. (eds), Handbook of Development Economics, Vol. 3B, Oxford, Elsevier 1 This is despite Krueger’s (1998, p. 1517–18) ironic claim the traditional infant industry argument of dynamic gains outweighing static losses has now been overturned. CJE 25/6 pps. FINAL 809-825 19/9/01 9:54 am Page 821 822 S. Deraniyagala and B. Fine Basant, R. 1993. ‘R&D, Foreign Technology Purchase and Technology Spillovers on Indian Industrial Productivity’, Maastricht: United Nations University Institute for New Technologies, mimeo Bell, M. and Pavitt, K. 1992. Accumulating technological capability in developing countries, Supplement to World Bank Economic Review, 257–81 Bernhofen, D. 1977. Strategic trade policy in a vertically related industry, Review of International Economics, vol. 5, no. 3, 429–33 Bhagwati, J. 1993. India’s Economy: The Shackled Giant, Oxford, Clarendon Press Bhattacharjea, A. 1995. Strategic tariffs and endogenous market structures: trade and industrial policies under imperfect competition, Journal of Development Economics, vol. 47, no. 2, 287–312 Bilal, S. 1998. Political economy considerations on the supply of trade protection in regional integration agreements, Journal of Common Market Studies, vol. 36, no. 1, 1–31 Boileau, M. 1996. Growth and the international transmission of business cycles, International Economic Review, vol. 37, no. 4, 737–56 Braga, H. and Wilmore, L. 1991. Technological imports and technological effort: an analysis of their determinants in Brazilian firms, Journal of Industrial Economics, vol. 39, no. 4, 421–32 Brainard, S. and Martimort, D. 1997. Strategic trade policy with incompletely informed policymakers, Journal of International Economics, vol. 42, no. 1–2, 33–66 Brander, J. and Spencer, B. 1985. Export subsidies and market share rivalry, Journal of International Economics, vol. 18, no. 1/2, 83–100 Chen, L. and Devereux, 1997. Trade neutrality: a clarification, Journal of Developing Areas, vol. 31, no. 3, 357–66 Chen, T. and Tang, D. 1987. Comparing technical efficiency among import substituting and exportoriented foreign firms in a developing country, Journal of Development Economics, vol. 26, no. 2, 277–89 Clerides, S., Lach, S. and Tybout, R. 1998. Is learning by exporting important? Micro-dynamic evidence from Colombia, Mexico and Morocco, Quarterly Journal of Economics, vol. CXIII, no. 3, 903–47 Coe, D., Helpmann, E. and Alexander, W. 1995. ‘North–South R&D Spillovers’, CEPR Discussion Paper, no. 1133, Centre for Economic Policy Research, London Creane, A. 1998. Ignorance is bliss as trade policy, Review of International Economics, vol. 6, no. 4, 616–24 De Melo, J. and Robinson, S. 1982. Trade adjustment policies and income distribution in three archetype developing countries, Journal of Development Economics, vol. 10, no. 1, 67–92 Deraniyagala, S. and Semboja, H. 1999. Technology upgrading and trade liberalisation in Tanzania, in Lall, S. (ed.), The Technological Response to Import Liberalisation in Sub-Saharan Africa, London, Macmillan Devereux, M and Lee, K. 1994. Endogenous trade policy and gains from international financial markets, Journal of Monetary Economics, vol. 43, no. 1, 35–9 Durkin, J. 1997. Perfect competition and endogenous comparative advantage, Review of International Economics, vol. 5, no. 3, 401–11 Eaton, J. and Grossman, G. 1986. Optimal trade and industrial policy under oligopoly, Quarterly Journal of Economics, vol. 101, no. 2, 383–406 Edwards, S. 1993. Openness, trade liberalization, and growth in developing countries, Journal of Economic Literature, vol. XXXI, no. 3, 1358–93 Edwards, S. 1997. Trade policy, growth, and income distribution, American Economic Review, vol. 87, no. 2, 205–10 Ethier, W. 1982. National and international returns to scale in the modern theory of international trade, American Economic Review, vol. 72, no. 3, 389–405 Evenson, R. and Westphal, L. 1995. Technological change and technology strategy, in Behrman, J. and Srinivisan, T. (eds), Handbook of Development Economics, Vol. 3B, Oxford, Elsevier Fikkert, R. 1993. ‘Complementary Technology Imports and Domestic R&D’, Princeton University, mimeo Fine, B. 1997. Industrial policy and South Africa: a strategic view, NIEP Occasional Paper Series, no. 5, Johannesburg, National Institute for Economic Policy Fine, B. 1999. Endogenous growth theory: a critical assessment, Cambridge Journal of Economics, vol. 24, no. 2, 245–65 (a shortened and amended version of identically titled, SOAS Working Paper, No. 80, February 1998, 1–49) CJE 25/6 pps. FINAL 809-825 19/9/01 9:54 am Page 822 New trade theory versus old trade policy 823 Fischer, R. and Serra, P. 1996. Income convergence within and between countries, International Economic Review, vol. 37, no 3, 531–51 Fuerst, T. and Kim, K. 1997. Two part trade policy under imperfect competition, Review of International Economics, vol. 5, no. 1, 63–71 Fung, K. 1995. Rent shifting and rent sharing: a re-examination of the strategic industrial policy problem, Canadian Journal of Economics, vol. XXVIII, no. 2, 450–62 Gallagher, M. 1991. Rent Seeking and Economic Growth in Africa, Boulder, CO, Westview Press Gould, D. and Ruffin, R. 1995. Human capital, trade, and economic growth, Weltwirthschaftliches Archiv, vol. 131, no. 3, 425–45 Greenaway, D. and Sapsford, D. 1994. What does liberalisation do for exports and growth? Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv, vol. 130, no. 1, 152–74 Greenaway, D. et al. 1997. Trade liberalization and growth in developing countries: some new evidence, World Development, vol. 25, no. 11, 1885–92 Greenaway, D., Morgan, W. and Wright, P. 1998. Trade reform, adjustment and growth: what does the evidence tell us? Economic Journal, vol. 108, no. 3, 1547–64 Grossman, G. and Helpman, E. 1991. Innovation and Growth in the Global Economy, Cambridge, MA, MIT Press Grossman, G. and Horn, H. 1988. Infant industry protection reconsidered: the case of international barriers to entry, Quarterly Journal of Economics, vol. CIII, no. 4, 767–87 Haddad, M. 1993. ‘How Trade Liberalization Affected Productivity in Morocco’, World Bank, Policy Research Working Paper, No. 1096 Helleiner, G. 1992. Introduction, in Helleiner, G. (ed.), Trade Policy and Industrialization in Turbulent Times, London, Routledge Helleiner, G. (ed.) 1994. Trade Policy and Industrialization in Turbulent Times, London, Rout- ledge Holm, P. 1997. Vertically integrated oligopoly and international trade policy, Canadian Journal of Economics, vol. XXX, no. 1, 194–207 Jie-A-Joen, C. 1997. Strategic Trade Policy, Multinational Firms, and Vertically Related Industries, Amsterdam, Thesis Publishers Kaneda, M. 1995. Industrialization under perfect foresight—a world economy with a continuum of countries, Journal of Economic Theory, vol. 66, no. 2, 437–62 Karp, L. and Perloff, J. 1995. Why industrial policies fail: limited commitment, International Economic Review, vol. 36, no. 4, 887–905 Katrak, H. 1997. Developing countries’ imports of technology, in-house technological capabilities and efforts: an analysis of the Indian experience, Journal of Development Economics, vol. 53, no. 1, 67–83 Keller, W. 1996. Absorptive capacity: on the creation and acquisition of technology in development, Journal of Development Economics, vol. 49, no. 1, 199–228 Krueger, A. 1997. Trade policy and economic development: how we learn, American Economic Review, vol. 87, no. 1, 1–22 Krueger, A. 1998. Why trade liberalisation is good for growth, Economic Journal, vol. 108, no. 3, 1513–22 Krugman, P. 1984. Import protection as export protection, in Kierkowski, H. (ed.), Monopolistic Competition and International Trade, Oxford, Oxford University Press Krugman, P. 1986. Strategic Trade Policy and the New International Economics, Cambridge, MA, MIT Press Krugman, P. and Elizondo, R. 1996. Trade policy and the third world metropolis, Journal of Development Economics, vol. 49, no. 1, 137–50 Lall, S. 1998. Exports of manufactures by developing countries: emerging patterns of trade and location, Oxford Review of Economic Policy, vol. 14, no. 2, 54–73 Latsch, W. and Robinson, P. 1999. Technology upgrading in post-liberalisation Zimbabwe, in Lall, S. (ed.), The Technological Response to Import Liberalisation in Sub-Saharan Africa, London, Macmillan Lau, M. and Wan, H. 1994. On the mechanism of catching up, European Economic Review, vol. 38, no. 3–4, 952–63 Leahy, D. and Neary, J. 1996. International R&D rivalry and industrial strategy without government commitment, Review of International Economics, vol. 4, no. 3, 322–38 CJE 25/6 pps. FINAL 809-825 19/9/01 9:54 am Page 823 824 S. Deraniyagala and B. Fine Lee, J. 1995. Capital goods imports and long-run growth, Journal of Development Economics, vol. 48, no. 1, 91–110 Lee, N. 1992. Market structure and trade in developing countries, in Helleiner, G. (ed.), Trade Policy, Industrialisation and Development, Oxford, Clarendon Press Lucas, R. 1988. On the mechanics of economic development, Journal of Monetary Economics, vol. 22, 3–42 McKay, A. and Milner, C. 1997. Strategic trade policy, learning by doing effects and economic development, World Development, vol. 25, no. 11, 1893–900 McPherson, M. 1995. The hazards of small firms in Southern Africa, Journal of Development Studies, vol. 32, no. 1, 31–54 Miranda, J., Torres, R. A. and Ruiz, M. 1998. The international use of antidumping—1987–1997, Journal of World Trade, vol. 32, no. 5, 5–71 Mosley, P., Harrigan, J. and Toye, J. 1991. Aid and Power: The World Bank and Policy-Based Lending, London, Routledge Nelson, R. R. 1981. Research on productivity growth and differences: dead ends and new departures, Journal of Economic Literature, vol. 19, no. 3, 1029–64 Nishimuzu, M. and Page, J. 1991. Trade policy, market-orientation and productivity in industry, in de Melo, J. and Sapir, A. (eds), Trade Theory and Economic Reform: Essays in the Honour of Bela Balassa, Oxford, Basil Blackwell Nishimuzu, M. and Robinson, S. 1984. Trade policy and productivity in semi-industrialised countries, Journal of Development Economics, vol. 16, no. 1–2, 177–206 Ocampo, J. and Taylor, L. 1998. Trade liberalisation in developing economies: modest benefits but problems with productivity growth, macro prices, and income distribution, Economic Journal, vol. 108, no. 3, 1523–46 Ohyama, M. and Jones, R. 1995. Technology choice, overtaking and comparative advantage, Review of International Economics, vol. 3, no. 2, 224–34 Okawa, M. 1997. A general equilibrium approach to the non-equivalence of tariffs and quotas under international duopoly, Japanese Economic Review, vol. 48, no. 2, 156–65 Onafowora, O., Owoye, O. and Nyatepepe Coo, A. 1996. Trade policy, export performance and economic growth: evidence from sub-Saharan Africa, Journal of International Trade and Economic Development, vol. 5, no. 3, 341–60 Onis, Z. 1991. Organisation of export-led industrialisation: the Turkish foreign trade companies in comparative perspective, in Nas, T. and Odekan, M. (eds), Politics and Economics of Turkish Liberalisation, London, Associated Universities Press Osang, T. and Periera, A. 1996. Import tariffs and growth in a small open economy, Journal of Public Economics, vol. 60, no. 1, 45–7 Pack, H. 1993. Technology gaps between industrial and developing countries, Supplement to World Bank Economic Review, 283–302 Pal, D. and White, M. 1998. Mixed oligopoly, privatization, and strategic trade policy, Southern Economic Journal, vol. 65, no. 2, 264–81 Papageorgiou, D., Michaely, M. and Choksi, A. M. (eds) 1991. Liberalising Foreign Trade, Oxford, Basil Blackwell Pissarides, C. 1997. Learning by trading and returns to human capital in developing countries, World Bank Economic Review, vol. 11, no. 1, 17–21 Prasch, R. 1996. Reassessing the theory of comparative advantage, Review of Political Economy, vol. 8, no. 1, 37–55 Pursell, G. 1990. Industrial sickness, primary and secondary: the effects of exit constraints on industrial performance, World Bank Economic Review, vol. 4, no. 1, 104–14 Reddy, S. 1999. Dynamic comparative advantage and the welfare effects of trade, Oxford Economic Papers, vol. 51, no. 1, 15–39 Riezman, R. and Wilson, J. 1997. Political reform and trade policy, Journal of International Economics, vol. 42, no. 1–2, 67–90 Rivera-Batiz, L. and Romer, P. 1991. International trade with endogenous technological change, European Economic Review, vol. 35, no. 4, 971–1001 Roberts, M. and Tybout, J. 1991. Size rationalisation and trade exposure in developing countries, The World Bank Working Paper Series, no. 594 CJE 25/6 pps. FINAL 809-825 19/9/01 9:54 am Page 824 New trade theory versus old trade policy 825 Rodrik, D. 1994. ‘Coordination Failures and Government Policy: A Model with Application to East Asia and Eastern Europe’, Columbia University, mimeo Rodrik, D. and Fouroutan, F. 1998. Why is trade reform so difficult in Africa? Journal of African Economies, vol. 7, Suppl., 10–36 Romer, P. 1992. Two strategies for economic development: using ideas and producing ideas, Supplement to World Bank Economic Review, 63–91 Ruttan, V. 1998. The new growth theory and development economics: a survey, Journal of Development Studies, vol. 35, no. 2, 1–26 Sleuwaegen, L., Belderbos, R. and Jie-A-Joen, C. 1998. Cascading contingent protection and vertical market structure, International Journal of Industrial Organization, vol. 16, no. 6, 697–718 Soludo, C. 1998. ‘Trade Policy Reforms and Supply Responses in Africa, African Development in a Comparative Perspective’, Working Paper, No. 6, UNCTAD Steel, W. and Webster, L. 1992. How small firms in Ghana responded to adjustment, World Bank Economic Review, vol. 6, no. 3, 423–38 Stewart, F. 1991. A note on strategic trade theory and the south, Journal of International Development, vol. 3, no. 5, 467–84 Stiglitz, J. 1998. More instruments and broader goals; moving towards the post-Washington consensus, 1998 WIDER Annual Lecture, Helsinki, Finland Tarr, D. 1992. ‘Rent-Seeking and the Benefits of Price and Trade Reform in Poland: The Automobile and Colour Television Cases’, World Bank, mimeo Tybout, J. 1992. Linking trade and productivity, World Bank Economic Review vol. 6, no. 2, 189–211 Tybout, J. and Westbrook, M. 1995. Trade liberalization and the dimensions of efficiency change in Mexican manufacturing industries, Journal of International Economics, vol. 39, no. 1–2, 53–78 Tybout, J., de Melo, J. and Corbo, V. 1991. The effects of trade reform on scale and technical efficiency: new evidence from Chile, Journal of International Economics, vol. 31, no. 3–4, 231–50 Van de Klundert, T. and Smulders, S. 1996. North–south knowledge spill-overs and competition: convergence versus divergence, Journal of Development Economics, vol. 50, no. 2, 213–32 Van Long, N. and Soubeyran, A. 1997. Cost heterogeneity, industry concentration and strategic trade policies, Journal of International Economics, vol. 43, no. 1–2, 207–20 Wade, R. 1990. Governing the Market: Economic Theory and the Role of Government in East Asian Industrialisation, Princeton, NJ, Princeton University Press Walde, K. 1996. Proof of global stability, transitional dynamics, and international capital flows in a two-country model of innovation and growth, Journal of Economics, vol. 64, no. 1, 53–84 Waverman, L. and Murphy, S. 1992. Total factor productivity in automobile production in Argentina, Mexico, Korea and Canada, in Helleiner, G. (ed.), Trade Policy, Industrialisation and Development, Oxford, Clarendon Press Westerhout, E 1995. Trade policies, imperfect competition and endogenous growth, De Economist, vol. 143, no. 1, 15–40 Wong, K. and Chow, K. 1997. Endogenous sequencing in strategic trade policy games under uncertainty, Open Economies Review, vol. 8, no. 4, 353–69 Wood, A. and Ridao-Cano, C. 1999. Skill, trade and international inequality, Oxford Economic Papers, vol. 51, no. 1, 89–119 World Bank 1990. Report on adjustment lending II: Policies for the recovery of growth. Document R90099, Washington, World Bank Wright, D. 1998. Strategic trade policy and signalling with unobservable costs, Review of International Economics, vol. 6, no. 1, 105–19 Zhang, W. 1994. Knowledge, growth and patterns of trade, Annals of Regional Science, vol. 28, no. 3, 285–303 Ziss, S. 1997. Strategic trade policy and vertical structure, Review of International Economics, vol. 5, no. 1, 142–52 CJE 25/6 pps. FINAL 809-825 19/9/01 9:54 am Page 825 CJE 25/6 pps. FINAL 809-825 19/9/01 9:54 am Page 826