Explaining the Severity of Civil Wars Author(s): Bethany Lacina Source: The Journal of Conflict Resolution, Vol. 50, No. 2 (Apr., 2006), pp. 276-289 Published by: Sage Publications, Inc. Stable URL: https://www.jstor.org/stable/27638487 Accessed: 08-11-2018 17:47 UTC JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org. Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at https://about.jstor.org/terms Sage Publications, Inc. is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to The Journal of Conflict Resolution This content downloaded from 147.251.55.52 on Thu, 08 Nov 2018 17:47:47 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms Explaining the Severity of Civil Wars BETHANY LACINA Political Science Department Stanford University The burgeoning literature on civil conflicts seldom considers why some civil wars are so much deadlier than others. This article investigates that question using a new data set of the number of combat deaths in internal conflicts from 1946 to 2002. The first section presents descriptive statistics on battle deaths by era, conflict type, and region. The article then tests state strength, regime type, and cultural characteristics as pre dictors of the number of combat deaths in civil war. The determinants of conflict severity seem to be quite different from those for conflict onset. Democracy, rather than economic development or state military strength, is most strongly correlated with fewer deaths; wars have also been less deadly on average since the end of the cold war. Religious heterogeneity does not explain the military severity of internal violence, and surprisingly, ethnic homogeneity may be related to more deadly conflicts. Keywords: civil war; battle deaths; democracy; state strength; ethnic violence v^ivil conflict is the most common form of warfare, accounting for all but three of the wars that broke out from 1990 to 2002{ and 90 percent of civilian and combatant battle deaths during the same period.2 As greater academic attention has been paid to internal warfare, scholars concentrating on large-/? statistical work have begun to converge on a handful of factors that seem most important in explaining civil conflict onset and dura tion (for reviews of the quantitative literature, see Lacina 2004; Sambanis 2002,2004). But wars come in different sizes, ranging from brief conflagrations that kill relatively few, to geographically isolated but prolonged insurgencies, to enormous military con tests sweeping across entire states. The number of deaths in these conflicts varies from the widely used threshold of 1,000 killed to the far more massive toll of the three 1. According to the Uppsala/PRIO list of state-based armed conflicts. SeeGleditschetal. (2002) and Eriksson, Wallensteen, and Sollenberg (2003). 2. Calculated from Lacina and Gleditsch (2005). AUTHOR'S NOTE: Sincere thanks are due to Jim Fearon, Nils Petter Gleditsch, and Scott Gates for help throughout this project. My Stanford colleagues will also notice how much I owe to their insights. Earlier versions of this article were presented at the 2004 Joint Session of Workshops of the European Consortium of Political Research, in Uppsala, Sweden, and the 2005 Annual Meeting of the International Studies Associa tion in Honolulu. The project benefited from financial support by the Centre for the Study of Civil War at the International Peace Research Institute, Oslo, where I began work on this project and remain an affiliated researcher. Replication data and the appendix are available at http://jcr.sagepub.eom/cgi/content/full/50/2/ 276/DC1/ and are posted with the Lacina and Gleditsch (2005) battle deaths data at http://www.prio.no/ cscw/cross/battledeaths. JOURNAL OF CONFLICT RESOLUTION, Vol. 50 No. 2, April 2006 276-289 DOI: 10.1177/0022002705284828 ? 2006 Sage Publications 276 This content downloaded from 147.251.55.52 on Thu, 08 Nov 2018 17:47:47 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms Lacina / EXPLAINING THE SEVERITY OF CIVIL WARS 277 largest internal wars of the post-World War II era?in Vietnam, China, and Afghani stan?which combined to destroy more than 3 million people in combat. Yet, to date, academic work has focused on the incidence of civil war rather than accounting for this variation in severity. Knowing why some conflicts tend to be more deadly than others is a question of inherent interest. The legacies of internal violence are poverty (Bayer and Rupert 2004; Collier et al. 2003; Murdoch and Sandier 2002) and poor public health (Gho barah, Huth, and Russett 2003; Krug et al. 2002). In 2000, seven of the ten countries with the worst mortality rates among children younger than age five had recently suf fered a civil war (Black, Morris, and Bryce 2003). And the depth of these impacts is likely in part determined by the severity of the conflict that has taken place. More deadly conflicts may also be more likely to recur (Fortna 2004). Do wars generate high numbers of battle deaths when widespread grievances trans form a marginal insurgency into a mass movement? Are political institutions tied to conflict size? Or is the opportunity to rebel against a disorganized and poor state suffi cient to cause large numbers of battle deaths, even if the insurgents are a small group? These questions parallel the debate found in studies of conflict onset, some of which stress the importance of factors that provide resources and pecuniary incentives for rebellion (Collier and Hoeffler 2001) or the opportunities for insurgency offered by a weak state (Fearon and Laitin 2003), while others argue for the importance of ethnic or religious factors, political repression, or regime type (Elbadawi and Sambanis 2002; Ellingsen 2000; Hegre et al. 2001; Reynal-Querol 2002). This article presents data on battle deaths in civil conflicts worldwide from 1946 to 2002, providing both a descriptive account of these data and a test for correlates of severity among civil wars. The first section discusses the use of battle deaths as a mea surement of the severity of civil conflict and presents new combat deaths data on civil conflicts from 1946 to 2002. Second, I propose a series of hypotheses on possible determinants of the severity of civil conflict. Finally, regression analysis is used to identify factors that explain the variation in civil war battle deaths. In contrast to most analyses of civil war onset and duration, political variables outperform measures of state strength in predicting battle violence. CONFLICT SEVERITY AND BATTLE DEATHS DATA Gauging the "size" or "severity" of civil wars is by no means straightforward. A number of factors could be relevant to determining whether one civil war was more devastating than another: how many people and resources were devoted to fighting in the conflict, the geographic range of violence, and the indirect and direct losses due to the war, in both human and economic terms. There is a dearth of theory on how to esti mate the full impact of war and an even more serious lack of cross-national informa tion about these losses (Lacina and Gleditsch 2005). But it is possible to compare the military severity of civil conflicts based on battle deaths, meaning combatants and civilians killed by means of violence in the course of a military contest. Such fatalities can be distinguished from indirect deaths caused by war-related hardships, as well as This content downloaded from 147.251.55.52 on Thu, 08 Nov 2018 17:47:47 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms 278 JOURNAL OF CONFLICT RESOLUTION o 500000 1000000 1500000 Total Battle Deaths -1 2000000 Figure 1 : Histogram of Total Battle Deaths in Civil War, 1946-2002 from deaths in unorganized violence (such as rioting) or in one-sided violence (such as genocide). A focus on battle deaths would not necessarily be a useful way to determine which wars have had the greatest humanitarian cost, but it is a reasonable measure of the scale of combat. I explore civil conflict severity here with a new data set of battle fatalities (Lacina and Gleditsch 2005) based on incidents in the Uppsala/PRIO list of state-based armed conflicts (Eriksson, Wallensteen, and Sollenberg 2003; Gleditsch et al. 2002). I com piled the Lacina and Gleditsch (2005) fatalities data into estimates of total battle deaths in 114 civil wars that took place between 1946 and 2002 in which at least 900 persons were killed.3 Perhaps the most notable feature of these data is the enormous skew in the number of battle deaths caused in various civil wars over the past half century (see Figure 1). The battle toll of civil wars clusters toward the low end of a range that runs from 900 to more than 2 million in Vietnam. The median civil war in these data killed a total of about 10,500 in combat (less than 0.5 percent of the maximum), while the average number killed is almost six times that figure. Conflict fatality data also reveal signifi 3. The appendix to this article lists the civil conflicts used and the number of battle deaths recorded in each. It is available online with the replication data for this article. See Lacina and Gleditsch (2005) for a full description of the battle deaths data set used here, a complete definition of battle deaths, and a discussion of the differing explanatory power of various measures of the human costs of conflict. This content downloaded from 147.251.55.52 on Thu, 08 Nov 2018 17:47:47 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms Lacina / EXPLAINING THE SEVERITY OF CIVIL WARS 2 79 TABLE 1 Civil War Battle Deaths, 1946-2002, Median Estimates by Era, Conflict Type, and Region Category Total Battle Deaths Rate of Battle Deaths Deaths per 100,000 People Population of Country in War (Millions) Role of cold war Wars begun prior to 1989 18,000 2,700 Wars begun in 1989 or later 4,300 1,350 Conflict type Nonsecessionist conflict 10,000 2,000 Secessionist conflict 9,100 2,300 Region Sub-Saharan Africa 15,000 2,000 Americas 4,500 2,000 Central and South Asia 3,600 1,600 East and Southeast Asia and Oceania 24,000 2,400 Europe 8,800 4,700 Middle East and North Africa 15,000 2,800 130 35 140 26 130 160 14 39 31 170 17 15 67 9 4 47 57 23 cant variation by era, conflict type, and region4 (see Table 1). Post-cold war conflicts have tended to be less deadly in terms of absolute numbers killed, rate of deaths, and deaths normalized by population than cold war conflicts. Secessionist conflicts have not been much less deadly in absolute terms or in deaths per year than nonsecessionist conflicts, contradicting the assumption that because such wars are geographically iso lated, they tend to be small.5 But wars of secession do seem to induce far fewer deaths per capita than other conflicts, despite a similar annual rate of fatalities, because sepa ratist conflict seems to occur primarily in large countries?the median population of a country in secessionist conflict is almost eight times that of a country in a nonseparatist civil war. Larger countries are probably more likely to have enclaves that are ethnically or lingually distinct from the group controlling the capital and have the economic potential to be viable states. By geographic region, conflicts in East and Southeast Asia killed the most people in combat, while wars in America, Europe, and Central and South Asia have had the smallest battle death tolls. Europe's wars are the only ones to stand out in terms of rate of fatalities, tending to kill relatively quickly; in fact, there have been only seven civil wars in Europe since 1946, and only one (in Northern Ireland) lasted for more than four years. Normalization by population size yields figures that are largest in the small states of the Americas, as well as in the Middle East and sub-Saharan Africa, while deaths in East and Southeast Asia, Central and South Asia, and Europe are signifi cantly discounted. The r??valuation by population size is quite dramatic in some cases: 4. For a definition of the regions used, see Lacina and Gleditsch (2005). 5. Secessionist conflict was defined following the Uppsala/PRIO data set (Eriksson, Wallensteen, and Sollenberg 2003). This content downloaded from 147.251.55.52 on Thu, 08 Nov 2018 17:47:47 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms 280 JOURNAL OF CONFLICT RESOLUTION the absolute number killed in the median conflict in Central and South Asia is 80 per cent of the similar figure for the Americas, but the Asian death rate per person is just 9 percent of the American rate. I will return to the relationship between battle deaths, conflict duration, and total population in the regression analysis below. WHAT DETERMINES CONFLICT SEVERITY? Scholars of civil conflict onset have engaged in a debate over whether variables relating to the opportunity to fight or the motivation to fight are most important to understanding where civil war will occur. The severity of military conflict should also relate to both opportunity and impetus, tending to be more deadly as the sides become better armed and organized and as they become increasingly convinced that military activity is their best strategy for obtaining their goals. Current civil war literature sug gests that state capacity, regime type, and ethnic and religious diversity may determine ability or willingness to initiate a civil conflict. By contrast, I discuss the potential of each of these variables to predict conflict severity. It is important to keep in mind that the question being investigated is what explains the variation in the numbers of battle deaths among observed civil wars. In other words, conditional on suffering a civil war, how deadly is combat likely to be? Factors that make a country high risk for civil war may not have much predictive power for explaining variation in deaths among civil wars. For example, if countries that fall into internal conflict are generally poor, it may be that poverty is too ubiquitous to explain much about which of these wars become most deadly. This study thus complements, rather than replaces, work on civil conflict onset.6 STATE STRENGTH Models for the onset of civil war have found that war is most likely to occur in impoverished states. Fearon and Laitin (2003) have argued that low gross domestic product (GDP) per capita is a strong predictor of civil war because it proxies for state incapacity, while Collier and Hoeffler (2001) emphasize factors they believe strengthen the states' challengers, such as large numbers of unemployed young men, unregulated markets, lootable resources, and porous borders. A corollary hypothesis might be that state capacity, which is associated with strong counterinsurgency, gen eral institutional strength, and high opportunity costs to rebellion, explains which states will have the smallest civil wars: Hypothesis 1A: Among states experiencing civil conflicts, more severe conflicts will occur in weak states. 6. It would be incorrect to use the results presented here to make predictions about how many civil war combat deaths are likely to occur in a country selected at random, without first taking into account the selection process that determines whether that state s likely to fall into civil war at all. However, I am not convinced that a selection effects model for civil coni let severity is more useful than estimating conditional probabilities, as random assignment of the "treatment ' of civil war is not just unobservable but conceptually meaningless. This content downloaded from 147.251.55.52 on Thu, 08 Nov 2018 17:47:47 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms Lacina / EXPLAINING THE SEVERITY OF CIVIL WARS 281 But while a weak state and aids to rebellion may make a war easy to start, they do not necessarily determine how deadly the conflict will be, at least not in a straightfor ward manner. On one hand, strong states are certainly less likely than weak states to be faced with well-matched opponents, suggesting that weak states may have more trou ble containing internal violence. On the other hand, civil conflicts in very weak states and very poor societies are likely to feature militaries with limited organizational capacity and limited access to technologies such as aircraft, tanks, and heavy artillery. A small insurgent movement and a weak state may be in a stalemated civil war simply because neither is able to seriously challenge the other's strongholds. And in wars of outright state collapse, which Kalyvas (2005, 88) aptly characterizes as "symmetric non-conventional" warfare, all combatant groups have minimal military strength and organizational coherence. The resulting anarchic and disorganized conflict is typified more by humanitarian crisis, predatory violence, and warlordism than sustained com bat (Herbst 2004; Mueller 2003). Thus, there may not be any unidirectional relation ship between weak states and severe civil wars: Hypothesis IB: Among states experiencing civil conflicts, the severity of civil conflicts will be uncorrelated with state strength. A nonrelationship would be particularly plausible if the military capacity of both the regime and its challengers is determined less by domestic economics than by out siders' economic and military support. When foreigners support parties that would not otherwise be able to sustain a military challenge or undertake competitive sponsorship of different sides of a civil conflict, internal wars are likely to be more severe. Regan (2000) has found that while external, military intervention in civil war may sometimes create an overwhelming advantage on one side and end the war, in general, outside participation on either or both sides of a conflict prolongs fighting. Thus, the following can be predicted: Hypothesis 1C: Among states experiencing civil conflicts, more severe conflicts will occur when there is external military assistance to the government and/or its challengers. Finally, the literature on state capacity and civil war onset calls attention to the importance of geography to counterinsurgency. Fearon and Laitin (2003, 80) argue that rough terrain aggravates state weakness because of the expensive infrastructure investment necessary to control thinly populated territories, the easy cover it offers insurgents, and the ease of monitoring the sparse population. Statistical analysis does find a correlation between rough terrain, low population density, and conflict onset (Collier and Hoeffler 2001; Fearon and Laitin 2003). In predicting civil war battle deaths, however, it may be less important to note that terrain can create the possibility for conflict and more important to note how terrain is likely to affect combat tactics. In rough terrain, both sides will probably be forced to deploy in relatively small units, reducing the number of people involved per engage ment. Conflicts that feature large numbers of battle deaths usually include at least some battles in urban and open territories where large numbers and heavy weaponry This content downloaded from 147.251.55.52 on Thu, 08 Nov 2018 17:47:47 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms 282 JOURNAL OF CONFLICT RESOLUTION can be deployed, soldiers can be targeted with aerial strikes and artillery bombard ment, and civilians are caught in the crossfire. It is probable that, conditional on being able to launch an insurgency, wars fought in densely populated areas and through con ventional battle methods are the most deadly. Thus, the relationship between terrain and conflict severity seems likely to be the reverse of that between terrain and conflict onset: Hypothesis ID: Among states experiencing civil conflicts, less severe conflicts will occur in states with rougher terrain. REGIME TYPE The severity of civil war may also be related to political considerations that influ ence willingness to continue, escalate, and deescalate fighting. Thus far, there is only mixed evidence of a role for regime type in conflict onset7 but some indication of a relationship to conflict severity. Carey (2005) finds that the presence of executive con straints, open executive recruitment, and breadth of political participation are all nega tively associated with the probability of civil conflict escalation and the onset of large civil wars, although they seem to make no difference in the likelihood of minor civil conflicts. There are at least three possible reasons to expect that regime type might relate to combat severity, even if it does not relate to conflict onset. These are selection effects, democratic norms, and the political adaptability of institutions. I consider the last to be the most plausible link between regime type and conflict severity, although this study cannot distinguish among the explanations in its empirical tests. Selection effects play a major role in the literature on regime type and interstate war. Democracies tend to win interstate wars, and it has been argued that this is in part due to their tendency to pick fights they can win and minimize casualties to avoid pub lic backlash (Bennett and Stam 1996, 243; Bueno de Mesquita and Lalman 1992,153 4; Siverson 1995). Democratic leaders, likely under public pressure to avoid blood shed at home as well as abroad, may tend to grant concessions when faced with a severe insurgent threat. As a result, one may observe only rather small, easily con trolled insurgencies in states with publicly accountable leaders. A second, normative perspective would argue that regime type influences conflict severity because democratic governments are unwilling to use the harshest measures against rebels or to inflict great collateral loss of life among civilians. Democratic leaders may be constrained due to norm internalization, through institutional checks on their powers (such as courts to prosecute cases of war crimes), or public pressure arising from sympathy with insurgents or bystanders. Valentino, Huth, and Balch Lindsay (2004) argue that democratic governments are less likely to resort to mass 7. Collier and Hoeffler (2001) and Fearon and Laitin (2003) find that economic measures trump democracy in explaining conflict outbreak. But Elbadawi and Sambanis (2002) find that democracy, espe cially several years of democracy, is negatively associated with the prevalence (onset and duration) of con flict. Benson and Kugler (1998, 199) emphasize the immunity from conflict of democracies that are also strong states. This content downloaded from 147.251.55.52 on Thu, 08 Nov 2018 17:47:47 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms Lacina / EXPLAINING THE SEVERITY OF CIVIL WARS 283 killings of the civilian supporters of elusive guerillas. Democracy is also negatively associated with the incidence of genocide (Harff 2003). The third possible link between regime type and conflict severity is the possibility that democracies are better equipped to co-opt, contain, and negotiate with rebels than are other governments. Democracies have structures of government that allow for power rotation and public participation in policy formation and provide for checks on the center, such as an independent judiciary or federalism. These institutions are avail able to incorporate insurgents as additional players in a peaceful political contest. For example, India has dealt with internal insurgencies by developing a looser federalism among its states (Brass 1994). The threat of post-World War II communist insurgency in European countries such as Italy dissipated as far-left factions became incorporated in the electoral process. Note that the responsiveness of a democratic political system does not necessarily guarantee that civil conflict will not break out?if concessions can be won through insurgency, there remains an incentive to launch violent acts?but only that civil con flict will be more readily contained. In fact, there may be greater incentives to launch small insurgencies in democracies if such governments are both more sensitive to political pressure to end internal disorder and have available institutions that make concessions less costly compared to similar adaptations in an autocracy. By contrast, in nondemocracies, challengers may assume that their best hope of achieving their goals is military victory or the collapse of the current regime and accordingly choose more deadly tactics (Lacina 2005).8 Combining the arguments regarding selection effects, norms, and institutional adaptability yields the following hypothesis:9 Hypothesis 2: Among states experiencing civil conflicts, less severe conflicts will occur in democracies. THE ROLE OF ETHNICITY AND RELIGION The third and final set of possible determinants of the combat severity of civil wars are cultural characteristics that may cement the willingness to bear the costs of con flict. Ascriptive identities, especially ethnolinguistic and religious loyalities, are often suggested to be less flexible than political ideologies (Horowitz 1985; Huntington 1997; Thies 2004), leading some to contrast relatively civilized ideological warfare to bloody, primordial ethnic conflicts (Duffield 1998; Kaldor 1999; Snow 1996; Thies 2004). If ethnic or religious conflicts are grounded in particularly strong antipathy or are inherently zero sum in nature, it may be impossible for the parties to ratchet down 8. Some violent groups operating in democracies, such as the Euskadi Ta Askatasuna (ETA) in Spain or the Orange Volunteers in Northern Ireland, have been known to alert the authorities prior to attacks so that few or no casualties are inflicted (Pape 2003, 345). It is difficult to imagine this tactic, which is essentially about political communication, being effective in the absence of a free press or against a regime that was not publicly accountable for law and order. 9. Some studies of conflict onset stress regime stability over regime type (Hegre et al. 2001). A vari able for anocracy (regimes falling between -6 and 6 on the combined Polity index) is not a significant corre late of conflict severity when it is added to the models presented here. This content downloaded from 147.251.55.52 on Thu, 08 Nov 2018 17:47:47 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms 284 JOURNAL OF CONFLICT RESOLUTION violence in favor of cohabitation. These dynamics are particularly likely to result in severe combat if each antagonistic group comprises a substantial population, suggest ing the following hypotheses:10 Hypothesis 3A: Among states experiencing civil conflicts, more severe conflicts will occur in states that are ethnically polarized. Hypothesis 3B: Among states experiencing civil conflicts, more severe conflicts will occur in states that are religiously polarized. On the other hand, the search for a statistical relationship between cultural factors and conflict onset has uncovered only mixed results, and it would be quite surprising if ethnic and religious hatreds made civil wars especially vicious without also making them more likely.11 Also, despite the recent attention paid to it, ethnic conflict is nei ther a new phenomenon (Kalyvas 2001) nor uniquely bloody. The Vietnamese and Chinese civil wars, the largest of the post-World War II era, were primarily "ideologi cal" in nature. Many civil conflicts with an ethnic dimension?for example, in Afghanistan, Ethiopia, and Mozambique?escalated due to external military assis tance provided in the name of cold war ideological schisms. And although cultural demands are generally thought to be exceptionally rigid, any struggle for political power can be zero sum if the players are sufficiently intractable. Regionally based cul tural elites may be ready to accept power devolution and partial autonomy arrange ments; competition for control of the center seems to admit, if anything, less chance for compromise (Walter 1997). MODELING CONFLICT SEVERITY I now turn to an empirical test of the three groups of variables discussed?state power, regime type, and cultural diversity?as determinants of the number of battle deaths in civil conflicts between 1946 and 2002. The dependent variable is the severity of battle violence in a civil conflict, measured as the natural log of total battle deaths. The regression controls for variation in conflict duration and population by using the log of each as independent variables.12 The first variable chosen to measure state capacity is military quality, the best avail able indicator of counterinsurgency capabilities. Military quality is defined as military 10. Recall that one-sided violence is not included in battle deaths. Certain types of one-sided violence, especially genocide, may be more closely related to cultural identity than are battle deaths. For a discussion of determinants of massacres and other one-sided violence, see Harff and Gurr (1988), Harff (2003), and Valentino, Huth, and Balch-Lindsay (2004). 11. Collier and Hoeffler (2001 ) and Fearon and Laitin (2003) find that ethnicity and religion do not explain war outbreak, while Hegre et al. (2001 ) and Elbadawi and Sambanis (2002) report that ethnic hetero geneity correlates with civil war. Ellingsen (2000) considers ethnic, religious, and linguistic identities simul taneously and finds higher conflict risk in diverse nations. 12. In the case of ongoing conflicts, duration refers only to the number of years for which battle deaths information was collected. The Lacina and Gleditsch (2005) fatalities data include low and high estimates of battle deaths as well as best estimates, which are used here. My results are similar to those reported when I use the low and high estimates. See replication data for details. This content downloaded from 147.251.55.52 on Thu, 08 Nov 2018 17:47:47 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms Lacina / EXPLAINING THE SEVERITY OF CIVIL WARS 285 expenditure divided by number of military personnel (following Bennett and Stam 1996).13 The variable is log transformed and lagged by a single year. Therefore, these figures may reflect the regime's accurate forebodings of conflict but not any upsurge in spending or recruitment after the outbreak of war. I also test GDP per capita, adjusted for purchasing power and for inflation, logged, and measured in the year prior to fight ing. 14 GDP per capita is the most common proxy for state strength in the civil war liter ature and seems to predict conflict onset consistently (Sambanis 2004). I have suggested that domestic capacities may be less important than external mili tary intervention in determining the severity of civil conflict. I test this hypothesis with a dummy variable for wars beginning during the cold war, when there was a greater availability of military assistance to states and rebel groups (Karp 1988; also compare SIPRI 1969, 1978, 1988).15 As a final variable in the investigation of state strength, I test the role of rough terrain by noting the log of the percentage of mountainous terrain in the country.16 Turning to regime characteristics, I code a dummy variable for democracy, defined as a score of 6 or higher on a combined Polity scale of regime type (Marshall and Jaggers 2003).1V Finally, I note ethnic and religious polarization dummy variables, coded as 1 where an ethnic or religious minority compromised at least 8 percent of the total population.18 FINDINGS Table 2 shows the results of ordinary least squares (OLS) regressions for battle deaths in civil conflicts. Model 1 presents the regression of total battle deaths, and model 2 is a trimmed specification using only variables significant in the first regres sion; there are no missing observations for this model. Not surprisingly, the total num ber of battle deaths increases as a function of time in conflict.19 However, a larger pop ulation does not predict a higher number of deaths. The nonrelationship between total 13. Inflation-adjusted data on military spending and data on numbers of military personnel are from the Correlates of War National Militaries Capabilities data set, version 3.01 (Singer, Bremer, and Stuckey 1972), and were downloaded with EUGene (Bennett and Stam 2000). 14. Data are from Fearon and Laitin (2003) and World Bank (2003). 15. The cold war dummy variable is coded for wars starting prior to 1989, following Collier and Hoeffler (2001). The dummy succeeds in capturing some variation in the incidence of foreign military inter vention, which featured in 61 percent of conflicts that began before 1989 and just 45 percent of those begin ning after that time (calculated from replication data for Regan 2000). War-specific data on the incidence of foreign military activity do predict more severe internal conflicts, but problems of endogeneity mean that it is unclear whether this result is due to interventions being a cause of severe conflict or a response to it. 16. From Fearon and Laitin (2003). 17. The Polity scale gives regimes scores from 0 to 10 in terms of both democratic and autocratic char acteristics. Changing the sign on the autocracy scores and adding the two scores places states along a range from-10 to 10. 18. This coding rule follows Fearon and Laitin (2003). I also tested Fearon and Laitin's measures of ethnic and religious fractionalization, defined as the probability that two members of a population are of the same ethnicity or confession. They were not significant predictors of civil conflict severity. 19. Perhaps more interesting is that there is no statistically significant relationship between deaths per year and conflict duration. A faster death rate does not seem to generate a countervailing tendency toward shorter conflict. Thus, factors that predict large numbers of deaths should also predict high rates of death. This content downloaded from 147.251.55.52 on Thu, 08 Nov 2018 17:47:47 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms 286 JOURNAL OF CONFLICT RESOLUTION TABLE 2 Ordinary Least Squares (OLS) Regressions of Battle Deaths in Civil Conflicts, 1946-2002 Independent Variable OLS Regression of In Total Battle Deaths Coefficient (SE) p-Value Model Ia In Duration 0.81 In Population -0.044 In Military quality 0.10 In Gross domestic product -0.19 Cold war 0.67 In Percentage mountainous territory 0.10 Democracy -0.87 Ethnic polarization -0.98 Religious polarization 0.12 Intercept 9.50 Model 2b In Duration 0.86 Cold war 0.59 Democracy -0.91 Ethnic polarization -1.00 Intercept 8.60 (0.12) (0.081) (0.12) (0.18) (0.31) (0.12) (0.36) (0.34) (0.32) (2.00) (0.11) (0.27) (0.33) (0.30) (0.35) .000 .580 .400 .280 .036 .400 .017 .005 .710 .000 .000 .030 .006 .001 .000 a. n = 105. Adjusted R2 = 0.40. b. n= 114. Adjusted/?2 = 0.43. deaths and total population means that normalizing deaths by population may too heavily discount deaths in large countries, as war does not seem to scale up in populous nations. Variables proxying state and rebel strength have no predictive power in these mod els. Military quality has an unexpected positive sign and is not significant. GDP per capita has the expected negative sign but is also insignificant. These results are unlikely to be due to multicollinearity as an F test easily rejects the joint significance of military quality and GDP per capita.20 The results here suggest that because state capacity has contradictory significance for the likelihood of parity between combat ants and their military capacity, it is difficult to find a correlation between state capac ity and conflict severity.21 Terrain also has no explanatory power. What seems to be more important for determining the military severity of a civil war is the availability of foreign aid and intervention. The dummy variable for the cold war predicts civil wars with about 1.8 times the number of battle deaths of later civil conflicts. 20. An F test comparing model 2 to a similar specification, including gross domestic product/capita and military quality, returns a test statistic of 0.62 (p-value = 54 percent). 21. A recentered quadratic term for military quality or gross domestic product/capita returns no evi dence of a simple curvilinear function. This content downloaded from 147.251.55.52 on Thu, 08 Nov 2018 17:47:47 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms Lacina / EXPLAINING THE SEVERITY OF CIVIL WARS 287 Political characteristics also strikingly outperform state power variables. More democratic regimes are associated with smaller civil conflicts. The substantive effect is even larger than that of the cold war, as civil wars in democracies are expected to have less than half the battle deaths seen in conflicts in nondemocracies. Finally, there are mixed results for variables measuring the cultural makeup of the state. Religious diversity displays no significant correlation with conflict size. Inter estingly, there is a significant and large negative coefficient on the variable for ethnic polarization.22 The results were unexpected, but a post hoc explanation might be that in ethnically homogeneous societies virtually the entire population can be implicated in the conflict, and it is more difficult to determine who is on what side, leading to more indiscriminate use of force. What is clear is that there is no indication in these results that cultural diversity provides elites with remarkable advantages in mobilizing their followers and convincing them to bear the costs of war, nor is there support here for a thesis of bloody ethnic wars as opposed to civilized ideological wars, a distinction that has always been tenuous at best. CONCLUSION It has been argued that grievances are so common across all societies that it is opportunity?weak states and aids to rebellion?that determines where and when wars begin. This may seem to suggest that political factors have little to contribute to civil peace and that investment in counterinsurgency is the only road to stability. This article has introduced a cautionary note against such a conclusion by pointing out that knowing why wars start does not necessarily reveal when they will be most devastating. In the statistical work presented here, state strength variables do not explain why some civil wars kill more people in combat than others. Nor does ethnic or religious heterogeneity explain the severity of internal war. Instead, there is an unexpected link between ethnic homogeneity and large wars. A strong predictor that a civil war will be severe is the availability of foreign assistance to the combatants. Democracy is also associated with fewer battle deaths; selection of conflicts, democratic norms, and institutional adaptability may all play a role in explaining this finding. Further research should focus on both testing the robustness of the relationship between regime type and conflict severity found here and developing a more precise theory of how chal lengers choose tactics against liberal and illiberal political regimes and how such governments tend to respond to political violence. 22. The result in model 2 is not overturned even after exclusion of outliers from quite homogeneous East Asian countries?namely, the Vietnam War, the Chinese Civil War, and the Cambodian Civil War from 1967 to 1975. This content downloaded from 147.251.55.52 on Thu, 08 Nov 2018 17:47:47 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms 288 JOURNAL OF CONFLICT RESOLUTION REFERENCES Bayer, R., and M. C. Rupert. 2004. Effects of civil wars on international trade, 1950-92. Journal of Peace Research 41 (6): 699-713. Bennett, D. S., and A.C. Stam. 1996. The duration of interstate wars, 1816-1985. American Political Science Review 90 (2): 239-57. -. 2000. EUGene: A conceptual manual. International Interactions 26 (2): 179-204. Benson, M., and J. Kugler. 1998. Power parity, democracy, and the severity of internal violence. Journal of Conflict Resolution 42 (2): 196-209. Black, R., S. Morris, and J. Bryce. 2003. Where and why are 10 million children dying every year? Lancet 361 (9376): 2226-34. Brass, P. 1994. The politics of India since independence: Vol. 1. The new Cambridge history of India. Cam bridge, UK: Cambridge University Press. Bueno de Mesquita, B., and D. Lalman. 1992. War and reason: Domestic imperatives and international imperatives. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press. Carey, S. C. 2005. Patterns of authority and the escalation of intrastate conflict. Paper presented at the gen eral meeting of the European Consortium for Political Research, September 8-10, Budapest. Collier, P., L. Elliott, H. Hegre, A. Hoeffler, M. Reynal-Querol, andN. Sambanis. 2003. Breaking the conflict trap: Civil war and development policy. Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press. Collier, P., and A. Hoeffler. 2001. Greed and grievance in civil war. World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 2355, World Bank, Washington, D.C. Duffield, M. 1998. Post-modern conflict: Warlords, post-adjustment states and private protection. Civil Wars 1 (1): 65-102. Elbadawi, I. A., and N. Sambanis. 2002. How much war will we see? Explaining the prevalence of civil war. Journal of Conflict Resolution 46 (3): 307-34. Ellingsen, T. 2000. Colorful community or ethnic witches' brew? Journal of Conflict Resolution 44 (2): 228 49. Eriksson, M., P. Wallensteen, and M. Sollenberg. 2003. Armed conflict, 1989-2002. Journal of Peace Research 40 (5): 593-607. Fearon, J. D., and D. D. Laitin. 2003. Ethnicity, insurgency, and civil war. American Political Science Review 97(1): 75-90. Fortna, V. P. 2004. Does peacekeeping keep peace? International intervention and the duration of peace after civil war. International Studies Quarterly 48 (2): 269-92. Ghobarah, H. A., P. K. Huth, and B. Russett. 2003. Civil wars kill and maim people?long after the shooting stops. American Political Science Review 97 (2): 189-202. Gleditsch, N. P., P. Wallensteen, M. Eriksson, M. Sollenberg, and H. Strand. 2002. Armed conflict, 1946 2001: A new dataset. Journal of Peace Research 39 (5): 615-37. Harff, B. 2003. No lessons learned from the Holocaust? Assessing risks of genocide and political mass mur der since 1955. American Political Science Review 97 (1): 57-73. Harff, B., and T. R. Gurr. 1988. Toward empirical theory of genocides and politicides: Identification and measurement of cases since 1945. International Studies Quarterly 32 (3): 359-71. Hegre, H., T. Ellingsen, N. P. Gleditsch, and S. Gates. 2001. Towards a democratic civil peace? American Political Science Review 95 (1): 33-48. Herbst, J. 2004. African militaries and rebellion: The political economy of threat and combat effectiveness. Journal of Peace Research 41 (3): 357-69. Horowitz, D. L. 1985. Ethnic groups in conflict. Berkeley: University of California Press. Huntington, S. 1997. The clash of civilizations and the remaking of the world order. New York: Simon & Schuster. Kaldor, M. 1999. New and old wars: Organized violence in a global era. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press. Kalyvas, S. N. 2001. "New" and "old" civil wars: A valid distinction? World Politics 54 (1): 99-118. -. 2005. Warfare in civil wars. In Rethinking the nature of war, edited by I. Duyvesteyn and J. Ang strom, 88-108. London: Frank Cass. This content downloaded from 147.251.55.52 on Thu, 08 Nov 2018 17:47:47 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms Lacina / EXPLAINING THE SEVERITY OF CIVIL WARS 289 Karp, A. 1988. The trade in conventional weapons. In SIPRI yearbook 1988: World armaments and disarma ment, 175-201. Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press. Krug, E. G., L. L. Dahlberg, J. A. Mercy, A. B. Zwi, and R. Lozano. 2002. World report on violence and health. Geneva, Switzerland: World Health Organization. Lacina, B. 2004. From side show to centre stage: Civil conflict after the cold war. Security Dialogue 35 (2): 191-205. -. 2005. Rebels as lobbyists: A political theory of asymmetrical insurgency. Paper presented at the general meeting of the European Consortium for Political Research, September 8-10, Budapest. Lacina, B., and N. P. Gleditsch. 2005. Monitoring trends in global combat: A new dataset of battle deaths. European Journal of Population 2-3:145-66. Marshall, M. G., and K. Jaggers. 2003. Polity IVproject. College Park: Center for International Development and Conflict Management at the University of Maryland. Mueller, J. 2003. Policing the remnants of war. Journal of Peace Research 40 (5): 507-18. Murdoch, J. C, and T Sandier. 2002. Economic growth, civil wars, and spatial spillovers. Journal of Conflict Resolution 46(1): 91-110. Pape, R. A. 2003. The strategic logic of suicide terrorism. American Political Science Review 97 (3) : 343-61. Regan, P. 2000. Civil wars and foreign powers: Outside intervention in intrastate conflict. Ann Arbor: Uni versity of Michigan Press. Reynal-Querol, M. 2002. Ethnicity, political systems, and civil wars. Journal of Conflict Resolution 46 (1): 29-54. Sambanis, N. 2002. A review of recent advances and future directions in the quantitative literature on civil war. Defence and Peace Economics 13 (3): 215-43. -. 2004. What is a civil war? Conceptual and empirical complexities of an operational definition. Jour nal of Conflict Resolution 48 (6): 814-58. Singer, J. D., S. Bremer, and J. Stuckey. 1972. Capability distribution, uncertainty, and major power war, 1820-1965. In Peace, war and numbers, edited by B. Russett, 19-48. Beverly Hills, CA: Sage. SIPRI. 1969. SIPRI yearbookof world armaments and disarmament 1968/9. New York: Humanities Press. -. 1978. SIPRI yearbook 1978: World armaments and disarmament. London: Taylor & Francis. -. 1988. SIPRI yearbook 1988: World armaments and disarmament. London: Taylor & Francis. Siverson, R. M. 1995. Democracies and war participation: In defense of the institutional constraints argu ment. European Journal of International Relations 1 (4): 481-9. Snow, D. M. 1996. Uncivil wars: International security and the new internal conflicts. Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner. Thies, C. G. 2004. State building, interstate and intrastate rivalry: A study of post-colonial developing coun try extractive efforts, 1975-2000. International Studies Quarterly 48 (1): 53-72. Valentino, B., P. K. Huth, and D. Balch-Lindsay. 2004. "Draining the sea": Mass killing and guerilla warfare. International Organization 58 (2): 375-407. Walter, B. 1997. The critical barrier to civil war settlement. International Organization 51 (3): 335-64. World Bank. 2003. World development indicators. Washington, D.C.: World Bank. This content downloaded from 147.251.55.52 on Thu, 08 Nov 2018 17:47:47 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms