Gulf War Reparations: Iraq, OPEC, and the Transfer Problem Author(s): Rodney J. Morrison Source: The American Journal of Economics and Sociology , Oct., 1992, Vol. 51, No. 4 (Oct., 1992), pp. 385-399 Published by: American Journal of Economics and Sociology, Inc. Stable URL: https://www.jstor.org/stable/3487447 JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org. Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at https://about.jstor.org/terms is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to The American Journal of Economics and Sociology This content downloaded from 147.251.68.36 on Wed, 24 Feb 2021 13:11:04 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms The AMERICAN JOURNAL of ECONOMICS and SOCIOLOGY Published Q UARTE R LY in the interest of constructive synthesis in the social sciences, under grants from the FRANCIS NEILSON FUND and the ROBERT SCHALKENBACH FOUNDATION. VOLUME 51 OCTOBER, 1992 NUMBER 4 Gulf War Reparations: Iraq, OPEC, and the Transfer Probl By RODNEY J. MORRISON* ABSTRACT. On February 27, 1991, the government Nations Security Council Resolution 674, a measure requi to the victims of its aggression in the Gulf Crisis of problems and consequences that may result as Iraq fac olution 674 are discussed. This latest example of inte pensation is placed in the context of the transfer p debate engendered by the experience of Germany in d burden after World War I. Lessons gained from this hist tions are then applied to the case of Iraq, one of the producers, a country that must rely on oil exports payments. Introduction THE COLLAPSE OF COMMUNISM has made all but obsolete the theories of containment and deterrence used to explain superpower relations during the Cold War. * [Rodney J. Morrison, Ph.D., is professor of economics, Wellesley College, Wellesley, MA 02181.] American Journal of Economics and Sociology, Vol. 51, No. 4 (October, 1992). ? 1992 American Journal of Economics and Sociology, Inc. This content downloaded from 147.251.68.36 on Wed, 24 Feb 2021 13:11:04 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms 386 American Journal of Economics and Sociology Now many analysts of world affairs speak of unipolar systems, the most famous of which is, of course, the New World Order. This latest model of international relations had its initial test in the Gulf War of 1990-1991, a conflict in which a United Nations coalition, led by the United States, drove Iraqi troops from Kuwait by force of arms. That the military dimension of the decision to confront and reverse Saddam Hussein's invasion of Kuwait captured world attention is indisputable. But there was another and far less visible dimension to the New World Order's intervention in the Gulf crisis: the United Nations directive that Iraq pay reparations to those who suffered from its acts of aggression. While less dramatic than high-tech warfare, this economic corollary of military action in the Gulf will nonetheless have serious long-term consequences for the nations of the Middle East and states bound to that region by commercial and economic ties. Postwar reparations are not new. Indeed, the demand that Iraq compensate its Gulf War victims is simply the latest chapter in the continuing story of victor in international conflicts exacting economic compensation from the vanquished The purpose of this paper is to put this newest addition to the history of reparations in context. The paper begins by reviewing the most famous example of such payments, Germany after World War I. It then applies knowledge gained from this historical case to several issues that must be considered as the proces of collecting economic recompense from Iraq unfolds. II Reparations: The Theoretical Debate THE GOVERNMENT OF IRAQ, on February 27, 1991, after suffering intensive ground and air operations inflicted by a coalition of United Nations forces led by the United States, acceded to United Nations Security Council Resolution 674. This was a twelve-part motion holding it liable "for any loss, damage or injury arising in regard to Kuwait and third states, and their nationals and corporations, as a result of. ... [its]. ... invasion and illegal occupation of Kuwait.. ." Consequently, Iraq found itself in a situation similar to what Germany faced in 1919 when it accepted Article 231 of the Versailles Treaty, the so-called "War Guilt Clause."2 Its government had been widely condemned and its economy was about to be mortgaged to redress wartime wrongs. Thus, as a result of the Gulf War of 1990-1991, the world community readied itself for yet another replay of an oft-repeated drama, an international aggressor paying reparations to its victims. Diplomats and historians are fascinated by reparations. Economists, however, regard them as simply a species of international financial transactions, little This content downloaded from 147.251.68.36 on Wed, 24 Feb 2021 13:11:04 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms Reparations 387 different from such seemingly div Marshall Plan), international constr visioning one's troops in a foreign The element common to all these transactions is that each ultimate across the borders of sovereign sta Economists may consider reparation as mundane as supplying soldiers w to foreigners, but they are no less fact, one of the most famous contr and the foremost name in twentiet first came to international promin the Treaty of Versailles and the c War opponents. The discussion attending German two closely related points: (1) how (2) how those payments would affe period. The first matter had both mestically, Germany had to achieve financial aspect of reparations could problem, and it was itself a subject over the size, capacity, and conditio and levels of government spendin was possible, once it was delivered to receive reparations, the internat external accounts of Germany and give up more than money to meet real resources. To do this, however, and those to whom it was paying r imbalances in international trade we economy's most famous debates, th Theoretical arguments about the context of a two-good, two-country to the other. It was assumed that i was in equilibrium and that full e both. The crux of the matter was transferred from the country payin The most famous commentator to o Maynard Keynes, who presented w This content downloaded from 147.251.68.36 on Wed, 24 Feb 2021 13:11:04 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms 388 American Journal of Economics and Sociology had revealed his qualms about the collection problem in his controversial treatise, The Economic Consequences of the Peace, and in his Revision of the Treaty. Now he expounded on his reservations about Germany's ability to meet the real burden of its reparations obligations. Germany would not be able to earn a sufficiently large trade surplus, he asserted, nor would its creditors incur sufficiently large trade deficits to effect completely the real transfer, because the relevant import and export elasticities were too low. Thus, Keynes maintained, Germany's terms of trade would have to decline for the full real transfer to occur.6 But a deterioration in a country's terms of trade can lead to a reduction in its real income. Which meant, by Keynes' reasoning, that Germany had to bear an additional or secondary burden: a further loss in real income caused by the decline in its terms of trade.7 The principal challenge to Keynes came from Swedish economist Bertil Ohlin. It is one of the ironies of the history of economic thought that Ohlin's thesis, a rebuttal of Keynes' classical argument, relied on a very Keynesian concept, aggregate demand. Ohlin claimed that when the country owing reparations met its financial obligations, its total purchasing power would decline, and this reduction in national income would lead to a decline in its imports. Conversely, national income in the country receiving the financial payment would increase, as would its imports. Assuming total purchasing power in the system at large remained constant, Ohlin asserted that the adjustments in imports triggered by changes in national income would be large enough to effect completely the real transfer. He concluded, therefore, that Keynes was wrong: the terms of trade did not have to shift; there would be no secondary burden; the real transfer would be accomplished through changes in national income.8 A third and final argument put forward in the theoretical debate over the transfer problem was known as the modern Keynesian case. Similar to Ohlin's thesis in its reliance on changes in national income, the modern Keynesian explanation broke with the assumption that full employment and flexible prices characterized the economies involved in the transfer. Thus it rejected the notion that the initial changes in national income would cause trade imbalances large enough to complete the real transfer without requiring any secondary burdens. In this model, an additional adjustment would be necessary, but contrary to the classical case, it would not come through changes in relative prices. It would be manifested in changes in national income and employment. That is, if the real transfer was not completely effected on the first round, further changes in national income would be required to produce the required trade imbalances in the countries making and receiving reparations. Having dispensed with the assumptions of full employment and flexible prices, this approach predicted This content downloaded from 147.251.68.36 on Wed, 24 Feb 2021 13:11:04 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms Reparations 389 that, absent devaluation or com ment in the country paying rep were to be completed.9 The classical thesis, Ohlin's reje Keynesian view dominated the d initial debate was couched in te but the argument has been extend in-kind, traded and non-traded volving more than two countries transfer problem was resolved trade and changes in national in includes a full multiplier analys save out of reparations payments First, if the relevant marginal completed without any seconda sum of these propensities is less t and a secondary burden will hav case, a classicist would argue, the paying reparations and it would s redistribution of real income. I pleted through income and subs undereffected transfer denies t Instead, it maintains that further are required. The third possible ginal propensities to import and is overeffected and the terms of Which means the reparations pa bution of income, that is, there w III Reparations: The Historical Debate THE SECOND CONTROVERSIAL ISSUE in the debate over Germany's post-World War I reparations-how those payments would affect its economy and political stability-was as contentious as the theoretical argument surrounding the transfer process. Germans (and many of their supporters in the international community) claimed their country could not make the payments demanded by its conquerers. Those seeking reparations were equally adamant in asserting Germany did have the capacity to meet their demands. This content downloaded from 147.251.68.36 on Wed, 24 Feb 2021 13:11:04 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms 390 American Journal of Economics and Sociology The popularly accepted version of this aspect of the World War I reparations story began with the publication of Keynes' The Economic Consequences of the Peace. In that polemical work, Keynes estimated that the Versailles Treaty, an open-ended arrangement, required Germany to pay some $40 billion in damages, a policy that would, he claimed, reduce it "to servitude for a generation."13 During the first two years following the war Germany delivered reparations in-kind and made territorial concessions, but specific terms on what it would have to pay its conquerors were not arrived at until the Allies formulated the London Schedule of Payments (1921). That agreement demanded that Germany pay compensation totaling 132 billion gold marks ($33 billion in current prices), a sum equal to two years' output of the entire German economy.'4 Many observers, then and now, considered that amount exorbitant and impossible for Germany to meet. Participation in the debate on how much Germany should or could pay was not limited to economists or politicians. In 1922, no less a figure than Ernest Hemingway, then a journalist writing from Paris, observed that the French, by trying to get as much from Germany as they could, "cannot see that they will only produce utter bankruptcy and get nothing."'5 Invariably, those who agreed with Hemingway (and Keynes) concluded that the hyperinflation that devastated Germany in 1923 resulted directly from the enormous reparations demanded by the Allies. Or they attributed the collapse of the Weimar Republic to inordinately large reparations. And some went so far as to claim that reparations and the War Guilt Clause had in fact paved the way for Adolph Hitler, National Socialism, and World War II. That the Allies demanded too much of Germany is a view that has prevailed to the present. A recent article in American Heritage (1991) describes World War I reparations as "crushing" and "one more millstone hung around Germany's neck."16 Whether such claims are valid is not just a debating point, not just a matter of interest limited to historians studying the interwar period. How economists and policymakers thought reparations affected reconstruction and the restoration of peace in Europe in the 1920s had serious practical significance some twenty-five years later. At the end of World War II, Allied decisions regarding reparations were colored in large measure by what had happened in Germany during the 1920s.17 This topic has surfaced again. Once more, lessons of the past, correct or not, are informing decisions of the present. In an article discussing Gulf War reparations, a major American publication, Business Week, noted, "Diplomats can't escape the ghost of post-World War I Germany, which, crippled by punitive reparations, turned to Hitler."'8 This content downloaded from 147.251.68.36 on Wed, 24 Feb 2021 13:11:04 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms Reparations 391 Not everyone agreed with the pop by the victorious Allies imposed a famous dissent from that belief w thaginian Peace, or The Economic view has two major themes: (1) Ger as had generally been thought; an capacity to meet its post-World W these points charge that Germany's the early 1920s and the hyperinfla 1923 did not result from economic liberate, inevitable outcomes of gov the country's external obligations. ernment had a "single-minded deter impossible."20 Empirical support for the view that Germany's World War I reparations were not so oppressive has been provided by economist Fritz Machlup, who found that even at their peak, in 1929, Germany's reparations payments required a transfer of only 3.5 percent of that year's national income. Over a longer period, between 1925-1932, they claimed annually on average about 2.5 percent of the country's national income. Little wonder Machlup took issue with those who saw reparations as a "millstone" about Germany's neck. "It is hard to understand why some economists," he wrote, "made such a fuss about the supposed severity of the German transfer problem."21 That fuss was further undermined by additional information offered by revisionist critics. They contend, for example, transfers in-kind and territorial concessions aside, reparations payments flowing out of Germany exceeded foreign capital inflows in only two years, 1930 and 1931. In short, before 1929, capital flows from the rest of the world, particularly from the United States, were the means whereby Germany was able to meet its international obligations.22 In effect, reparations payments made by Germany before 1929 were reverse transfers-from World War I's victors to its principal loser. The title of a major study of this period captures this irony rather well: American 'Reparations' to Germany, 1919-33.23 IV Iraq and the Gulf Crisis THE WORLD COMMUNITY is in the midst of yet another round of war reparations, this time in the Middle East, with Germany's post-World War I experience as This content downloaded from 147.251.68.36 on Wed, 24 Feb 2021 13:11:04 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms 392 American Journal of Economics and Sociology its historical model and the theory of international transfers as its analytical base. When Iraq accepted U.N. Resolution 674, a means was put in place for its victims to seek economic compensation for the destruction suffered at the hands of Saddam Hussein. To initiate this process, the Security Council invited all aggrieved parties-individual, corporate, and governmental-to submit damage claims to a U.N. commission charged with overseeing such requests. There are historical parallels for what Iraq will face when those bills come due. It will have to address, for instance, the dilemmas of a collection process and a transfer of real resources. But the past will not be a perfect guide for solving these problems, for there are major differences between this case of war reparations and those of an earlier time. Iraq is a small country and it relies heavily on export earnings for much of its national income. But it not so small that it will not affect world prices and real incomes by what it does to meet its reparations burdens. Much more than just the state of the Iraqi economy will be at risk as this reparations process goes forward. Other Middle Eastern nations and countries bound by economic ties to this region will also be affected. A major issue in the debate over Germany's post-World War I reparations bill was the base upon which those claims were imposed. Economists and historians investigating that question were at wide variance as to the size of German national income.24 Assessing Iraq's ability to pay poses similar difficulties. Data on Iraq's GNP exist, but they are less than reliable for any number of reasons, not the least of which is the Iraqi government's reluctance to release such information because of national security considerations.25 The Gulf War itself is another factor. According to U.N. observers, the bombing campaign of early 1991 reduced the country to a pre-industrial state. For what they are worth, the most recent estimates of Iraq's national income that are even remotely reliable are for 1986, a time when the war with Iran was still being fought. They put Iraq's nominal GNP at $55 billion. Distributional questions aside, with a population of about 16 million, per capita nominal GNP that year was somewhere in the neighborhood of $3400.26 Since 1986, Iraq's population has grown and inflation and another war have hit that country. Clearly, caution must be exercised in interpreting data regarding the current state of Iraq's economy. Reliable information about two aspects of Iraqi economic activity is, however, available. The first relates to structure; the second concerns oil. With respect to the former, in 1964 the regime then in power in Baghdad began an extensive campaign of economic nationalization. In 1983, that policy changed and the Baghdad government began to move away from state ownership toward an economy more dependent on market forces.27 Observers claim that by 1987 this shift towards the market had begun "in earnest," but Iraq had still not moved This content downloaded from 147.251.68.36 on Wed, 24 Feb 2021 13:11:04 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms Reparations 393 very far along the road to privatizat By no means had privatization tou Having been fully nationalized by under government control.29 It is difficult to exaggerate oil's r commodity have provided as much as of its foreign earnings, and 99 perc war with Iran, Iraq's oil exports f materials so critical to its ambitio much of the nation's daily consump in Iraq is imported. Despite its large import bills, Iraq's to produce current account surpluses assets. The government had hoped nation's overwhelming dependence the mid-1980s oil revenues decline deficits, and rather than accumulat abroad. Again, because they are regar on net foreign indebtedness are un ever, that Iraq owes approximatel banks, $10 billion to the Soviet Un States, about $85 billion in all.31 Gulf War Reparations THE FINAL BILL on Iraq's reparations large. The principal claimant is Kuw billion in damages. Private firms f $5 billion. Other Gulf States, Israel of the environment will demand r for reparations.32 Immigrant worker personnel killed in the war, and c conflict will seek compensation. Th in line. It has and will continue t missions sent to inspect and monit Iraq could face reparation demands more, Iraq has the foreign indebted be serviced. In the face of these exter This content downloaded from 147.251.68.36 on Wed, 24 Feb 2021 13:11:04 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms 394 American Journal of Economics and Sociology in which U.N. sanctions have frozen its holdings of $5 billion in foreign assets and its foreign exchange reserves are all but exhausted. Given these constraints, Iraq has but one means of meeting its external liabilities: oil. Revisionist critics of World War I reparations contend the German government never raised taxes and/or reduced its spending sufficiently to produce the domestic fiscal surplus required by the collection process.33 Keynes, and those who shared his opinion of those reparations, claimed Germany did not have the capacity to do so, at least not without forcing its standard of living to subsistence levels. As the collection problem applies to Iraq, the source of its reparations payments will most certainly be its oil revenues. However, because the oil industry is completely nationalized, those earnings do not flow into the treasuries of private firms and the hands of private individuals; they are taken directly by the government. Thus Iraq will not have to face one painful duty usually associated with reparations. Its government will not have to raise taxes, at least not explicitly, in order to deposit with a transfer agent the domestic currency that will be used to buy the foreign exchange earned in trade surpluses by private entities. Once it sells its oil abroad, the government will have in hand immediately the foreign exchange needed to effect the actual transfer. Implicit taxation is another matter entirely. If Iraq's oil exports return to prewar levels and there is no change in petroleum prices, two rather strong assumptions, in order to have a surplus in its trade balance, Iraq will have to reduce its imports. But this is not a matter for the private sector. Given the high degree of state ownership in the Iraqi economy, it is the government that will have to reduce directly its demand for foreign goods and services. But those imports have provided the capital used in Iraq's development programs and much of the food and other goods consumed by the Iraqi population. When the government reduces its import demands, which it must do if a trade surplus is to obtain, it will be raising taxes. This fiscal action will be implicit in nature but no less real in effect. The administrative difficulties usually associated with tax increases may be minimized, but the Iraqi people will still feel the impact of higher taxation. In 1981, Iraq's nominal oil export revenues peaked at $26 billion. Recently, its annual earnings have run between $17 and $18 billion, which is probably a reasonable range for what Iraq can hope to obtain from this sector.34 In 1991, when the United Nations offered to lift its sanctions and allow Iraq to export $1.6 billion worth of oil, it demanded 30 percent of the proceeds as reparations. Indeed, 30 percent has been the proportion frequently mentioned as the impost the U.N. would apply to all Iraqi oil sales once the full reparations process gets under way.35 Using $18 to $26 billion as a possible range for Iraq's oil revenues, This content downloaded from 147.251.68.36 on Wed, 24 Feb 2021 13:11:04 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms Reparations 395 a 30 percent levy will produce b butions to the UN's reparations f 10 and 15 percent of Iraq's $55 b magnitude is Carthaginian or no greater than anything Machlup fou of reparations. Several factors condition these calculations: the extent to which Iraq's economy was damaged during the war; the adjustment costs of moving from a wartime to a peacetime economy; and how import constraints will affect these efforts. Another important question concerns Iraq's external liabilities. Adding the service on $85 billion in foreign indebtedness to the tax burden, implicit or otherwise, required by reparations could increase considerably the severity of Iraq's economic problems. Capital inflows could ease this situation, but eventually they too would have to be repaid. VI The Transfer Problem THE TRANSFER PROBLEM is equally problematic. Iraq will pay reparations to man countries, but its principal creditor will be Kuwait. HarryJohnson has describe the conditions necessary to determine the degree to which the real transfer effected when more than two countries are involved. Stated specifically in terms of Iraq and Kuwait, the theoretical result rests on how the sum of Iraq's margina propensity to import from all sources, and Kuwait's marginal propensity to impor from Iraq, relates to unity. The destruction the Gulf War visited on these countrie makes any calculations of these marginal propensities impossible.36 Regardless this aspect of the transfer process may be far less important than something els that is all but certain to appear when Iraq gets back in the oil business: th classical phenomenon of changes in the terms of trade. Implicit in any consideration of Gulf War reparations is the assumption tha Iraq will honor the conditions of U.N. Resolution 674 and any subsequen agreements regarding its obligation to make good the damages it inflicted during that conflict. It is clear that oil will be the means Iraq will use to meet those responsibilities. When it was a member in good standing of OPEC, Iraqi oi accounted for approximately 15 percent of the cartel's supply. By the time th Gulf War ended, Iraq's share of OPEC production had fallen to zero, yet th cartel's total output (and prices) remained virtually unchanged because Saud Arabia and Iran filled in the gap. Barring any output changes by the other members of OPEC, when Iraq begins exporting petroleum to pay its reparations, th This content downloaded from 147.251.68.36 on Wed, 24 Feb 2021 13:11:04 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms 396 American Journal of Economics and Sociology addition of its production (and Kuwait's) to the cartel's supply is bound to lead to a decline in oil prices. But that means all members of OPEC will suffer deteriorations in their terms of trade, i.e., losses in real income. As for Iraq, it will be able to make its reparations payments but it will suffer a secondary burden. And finally, countries that are net oil importers will see their terms of trade improve and their real incomes increase. In the short run, this could aid efforts to end the current recession. If successful, in the long run, an international economic recovery could mean greater earnings for oil producers as higher world incomes increase the demand for petroleum. The preceding analysis assumes that once Iraqi wells come back on line the other members of OPEC make no supply adjustments. However, if the cartel's goal is to maintain current price levels, it will have to reduce its output. In this event, Iraq will not suffer a decline in its terms of trade and hence no secondary burden. Kuwait will have its reparations and no change in its terms of trade. And the rest of the world will have its reparations and also face unchanged terms of trade. But the members of the OPEC cartel that reduce supply to offset Iraq's production increases will see their revenues decline. In this instance, there will be two losers: Iraq and OPEC countries that make the necessary adjustments in supply. Saudi Arabia and Iran benefited most when OPEC moved to meet the supply reductions that occurred at the start of the Gulf crisis. Forgoing income once the crisis ended was not something they envisioned when they threw in their lot with the United Nations. This is particularly true of Saudi Arabia, OPEC's largest producer. Recently, deficits have appeared in that country's national budget and its government adamantly opposes any reduction in its market share. Indeed, the Saudi refusal to accept a lower quota and observe an OPEC production ceiling proposed at a February 1992 cartel meeting is clear evidence of that unwillingness to cut back at this time. Another outcome, unlikely but painful, could result from Iraq's attempt to satisfy its reparations payments. In this instance, OPEC members, insensitive to international considerations, reduce the cartel's supply by more than the increase occasioned by Iraq's resumption of production. Given the short-run inelasticity of the demand for petroleum, OPEC revenues will increase. Iraq's terms of trade will improve and its reparations burden will be mitigated by a perverse transfer. But now the rest of the world would face the unhappy prospect that higher oil prices could slow the recovery from the current recession and reduce further growth rates as well. Furthermore, in a turn reminiscent of the 1970s, there could be another redistribution of world income away from oil importers and to oil exporters. This is hardly the denouement expected by the nations that This content downloaded from 147.251.68.36 on Wed, 24 Feb 2021 13:11:04 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms Reparations 397 joined the New World Order to st cidentally, to stabilize world oil pr The analyses presented above are w is aware of them. Since the Gulf W attempts to bring its production meeting in Vienna refused to supp United Nations to end sanctions aga reported that, at an Istanbul confere nations, an overwhelming majority states who opposed another Iraqi plea a senior Arab-OPEC delegate at OP marked, "If we say the Saudis cont forever, what do we do when Kuwa ducers in the Gulf know full well ho obligations may affect their econom VII Conclusion FEW WOULD DISAGREE with the New World Order principles enunciated dur the Gulf War: a world allied against aggression and the conviction that th who attack their neighbors should be liable for the destruction they cause. H ever, before such retribution is exacted, all possible economic repercussi should be investigated. In almost every previous example of reparations, principal issues were how to get the offender to pay and how the real trans would be effected. That history, particularly the case of Germany in the 192 will serve to inform United Nations officials as they negotiate the final terms Iraq's reparations bill in the 1990s. But the Gulf War has added a new consi eration to the modalities of reparations: how to proceed when the guilty nat has the ability to affect world prices-even to the point where it may be ab to reduce its reparations burden and inflict real income losses on those seeki compensation. This twentieth-century case of Middle East reparations promi to add an interesting dimension to an already fascinating chapter in the hist of international economic relations. Notes 1. Charles Kindleberger, A Financial History of Western Europe (London: Allen, 1984) 2 250. This content downloaded from 147.251.68.36 on Wed, 24 Feb 2021 13:11:04 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms 398 American Journal of Economics and Sociology 2. Frank Tipton and Robert Aldrich, An Economic and Social History of Europe (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins UP, 1987) 267. 3. Kindleberger, Financial History 238-239, 250, 433-445. 4. Stephen Schuker, American 'Reparations' to Germany, 1919-1933: Implicationsfor the Third World Debt Crisis (Princeton, NJ: Princeton UP, 1988) 24-35. 5. Richard Caves and Ronald Jones, World Trade and Payments, 4th ed. (Boston: Little, Brown and Company, 1985) 55-58; Bo Sodersten, International Economics, 2nd ed. (New York: St. Martin's, 1980) 289-291; Harry Johnson, "The Transfer Problem and Exchange Stability,"Journal of Political Economy 64.3 (1956): 212-225. 6. John Maynard Keynes, "The German Transfer Problem," EconomicJournal39.153 (1929): 1-7; Caves and Jones, World Trade 55. 7. Such declines are not inevitable, given productivity changes of the right order of magnitude. See Kindleberger, Financial History 299. 8. Bertil Ohlin, "The Reparations Problem: A Discussion," EconomicJournal39.154 (1929): 172-173; Caves and Jones, World Trade 55. 9. Thomas Balogh and Andrew Graham, "The Transfer Problem Revisited: Analogies Between the Reparations Payments of the 1920s and the Problems of the OPEC Surplus," Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics 41.3 (1979): 183-188. 10. Johnson, "The Transfer Problem," 213-217. 11. Ibid., 217-221; Sodersten, International Economics, 289-290. 12. The three outcomes described here are theoretical propositions. How the trade imbalances they produce relate in size to the required reparations payments is strictly an empirical matter. See Johnson, "The Transfer Problem," 213. 13. John Maynard Keynes, The Economic Consequences of the Peace (New York: Harcourt, 1920) 161, 225. 14. Rondo Cameron, A Concise Economic History of the World (New York: Oxford UP, 1989) 351. 15. Toronto Star, Feb. 4, 1922. 16. Bernard Weisberger, "In the News," American Heritage 42.4 (1991): 22-23. 17. Balogh and Graham, "The Transfer Problem Revisited," 187-188. 18. Business Week, March 18, 1991. 19. Etienne Mantoux, The Carthaginian Peace or The Economic Consequences of Mr. Keynes (London: Oxford UP, 1946). 20. Schuker, American 'Reparations, 19. See Jon Jacobson, "Is There a New International History of the 1920s?" American Historical Review 88.3 (1983): 617-645. 21. Fritz Machlup, International Payments, Debts, and Gold (New York: Scribner's, 1964) 374-395. 22. Ibid., 382-383; Kindleberger, Financial History, 303. 23. Schuker, American 'Reparations'24-35. 24. See, for example, Douglas McIntosh, "Mantoux versus Keynes: A Note on German Income and the Reparations Controversy," EconomicJournal87.348 (1977): 765-767. 25. Helen Chapin, ed., Iraq: A Country Study (Washington: Library of Congress, 1990) 171. 26. Ian Skeet, OPEC: Twenty-Five Years of Prices and Politics (Cambridge: Cambridge UP, 1988) 239; Facts and Figures (Vienna: OPEC Secretariat, 1987) 29. 27. Kiren Choudry, "On the Way to Market," Middle East Report21. 3 (1991): 14-23. 28. Ibid., 15. This content downloaded from 147.251.68.36 on Wed, 24 Feb 2021 13:11:04 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms Reparations 399 29. Chapin, Iraq, 141. 30. Christine Helms, Iraq. Eastern Flank of t 1984) 118-119; Chapin, Iraq 125. 31. New York Times, March 1, 1991. 32. Iran's demand is related to its war wit 33. Arminio Fraga, German Reparations an NJ: Princeton UP, 1986) 7. 34. Iraq and OPEC oil production and pric Monthly Energy Review (Washington: Gove issues. 35. Manchester Guardian Weekly, June 23, 1991. 36. Available data, faulty as they are, indicate the sum of the marginal propensities is probably less than unity because of the insensitivity between Kuwait's income and its demand for Iraq's exports. However, Iraq's oil earnings, denominated in dollars, go directly to the state. The government's marginal propensity to import out of those revenues is probably close to unity. When the U.N. lifts its sanctions against Iraq, it could prohibit all capital flows into that country. Because its foreign assets have been frozen and its exchange reserves are all but depleted, when the U.N. takes 30 percent of Iraq's oil earnings as reparations, Iraq's imports would have to decline, thereby producing a trade surplus. 37. New York Times, June 15, 1991; Aug. 3, 1991; Feb. 15, 1992. TheJoan Robinson Legacy-A Review Article INGRID RIMA has assembled fifteen stimulating and insightful essays, ( TheJoan Robinson Legacy. Edited by Ingrid H. Rima. New York and London: M. E. Sharpe, Inc., 1991) in the main previously unpublished, the response of significant second and third generation post-Keynesian theorists to the opportunity she offered them to refine, extend and clarify their views of the message of that redoubtable First Lady of economic analysis, Joan Robinson. The collection is usefully embellished by the reproduction of Phyllis Deane's sympathetic biographical memoir, Maria Marcuzzo's scholarly Robinson bibliography of 378 items and Marjorie Turner's conjecture that Robinson's failure to be awarded the Nobel Prize in Economics was due to her gender, her political orientation and particularly to her unrelenting criticism of the neoclassical orthodoxy going so far as to repudiate her own well-known early work, The Economics of Imperfect Competition. Generally stopping well short of hagiography, the majority of the essays demonstrate the radical criticism proffered by Robinson. Hans Jurgen traces the metaphysical foundations of Robinson's theories to values she herself attributed to her upbringing. These views infused her analysis and contributed to her identification of the inherent weakness of contemporary theory, particularly its method of suppression of value-related and class-related characteristics of capital. This content downloaded from 147.251.68.36 on Wed, 24 Feb 2021 13:11:04 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms