Greed and Grievance in Civil War Author(s): Paul Collier and Anke Hoeffler Source: Oxford Economic Papers , Oct., 2004, Vol. 56, No. 4 (Oct., 2004), pp. 563-595 Published by: Oxford University Press Stable URL: https://www.jstor.org/stable/3488799 JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org. Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at https://about.jstor.org/terms Oxford University Press is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to Oxford Economic Papers This content downloaded from 147.251.110.131 on Tue, 22 Mar 2022 12:08:37 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms ( Oxford University Press 2004 Oxford Economic Papers 56 (2004), 563-595 563 All rights reserved doi:10.1093/oep/gpf064 Greed and grievance in civil By Paul Collier* and Anke Hoefflert *Centre for the Study of African Economies, Unive tCentre for the Study of African Economies, Unive Road, Oxford OX2 6NA; e-mail: anke.hoeffler@econ We investigate the causes of civil war, using a new data se Rebellion may be explained by atypically severe grievance a lack of political rights, or ethnic and religious divisions it might be explained by atypical opportunities for build While it is difficult to find proxies for grievances and op political and social variables that are most obviously relate explanatory power. By contrast, economic variables, which ances but are perhaps more obviously related to the viabi considerably more explanatory power. 1. Introduction Civil war is now far more common than international conflict: all of the 15 major armed conflicts listed by the Stockholm International Peace Research Institute for 2001 were internal (SIPRI, 2002). In this paper we develop an econometric model which predicts the outbreak of civil conflict. Analogous to the classic principles of murder detection, rebellion needs both motive and opportunity. The political science literature explains conflict in terms of motive: the circumstances in which people want to rebel are viewed as sufficiently rare to constitute the explanation. In Section 2 we contrast this with economic accounts which explain rebellion in terms of opportunity: it is the circumstances in which people are able to rebel that are rare. We discuss measurable variables which might enable us to test between the two accounts and present descriptive data on the 79 large civil conflicts that occurred between 1960 and 1999. In Section 3 we use econometric tests to discriminate between rival explanations and develop an integrated model which provides a synthesis. Section 4 presents a range of robustness checks and Section 5 discusses the results. This analysis considerably extends and revises our earlier work (Collier and Hoeffler, 1998). In our previous theory, we assumed that rebel movements incurred net costs during conflict, so that post-conflict pay-offs would be decisive. The core of the paper was the derivation and testing of the implication that high post-conflict pay-offs would tend to justify long civil wars. We now recognize that This content downloaded from 147.251.110.131 on Tue, 22 Mar 2022 12:08:37 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms 564 P. COLLIER AND A. HOEFFLER this assumption is untenable: rebel groups often more than co the conflict. Here we propose a more general theory which tunities for rebellion against the constraints. Our previo conflated the initiation and the duration of rebellion. We now This paper focuses on the initiation of rebellion.' Our sampl cross-section analysis of 98 countries during the period 196 sive coverage of 750 five-year episodes over the period 1960 analyse double the number of war starts. Further, we expand variables to a more extensive coverage of potential determinan ness to select a preferred specification. 2. Rebellion: approaches and measures 2.1 Preferences, perceptions, and opportunities Political science offers an account of conflict in terms of motive: rebellion occurs when grievances are sufficiently acute that people want to engage in violent protest. In marked contrast, a small economic theory literature, typified by Grossman (1991, 1999), models rebellion as an industry that generates profits from looting, so that 'the insurgents are indistinguishable from bandits or pirates' (Grossman, 1999, p.269). Such rebellions are motivated by greed, which is presumably sufficiently common that profitable opportunities for rebellion will not be passed up.2 Hence, the incidence of rebellion is not explained by motive, but by the atypical circumstances that generate profitable opportunities. Thus, the political science and economic approaches to rebellion have assumed both different rebel motivationgrievance versus greed-and different explanations-atypical grievances versus atypical opportunities. Hirshleifer (1995, 2001) provides an important refinement on the motiveopportunity dichotomy. He classifies the possible causes of conflict into preferences, opportunities, and perceptions. The introduction of perceptions allows for the possibility that both opportunities and grievances might be wrongly perceived. If the perceived opportunity for rebellion is illusory-analogous to the 'winners' curse'-unprofitability will cause collapse, perhaps before reaching our threshold for civil war. By contrast, when exaggerated grievances trigger rebellion, fighting does not dispel the misperception and indeed may generate genuine grievances. Misperceptions of grievances may be very common: all societies may have groups with exaggerated grievances. In this case, as with greed-rebellion, motive would not explain the incidence of rebellion. Societies that experienced civil war would be distinguished by the atypical viability of rebellion. In such societies rebellions .......................................................................................................................................................................... 1 On the analysis of th 2 By the 'Machiavelli T to exploit someone els This content downloaded from 147.251.110.131 on Tue, 22 Mar 2022 12:08:37 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms GREED AND GRIEVANCE 565 would be conducted by viable not-for-profit organizations, pur agendas by violent means. Greed and misperceived grievance have important simil of rebellion. They provide a common explanation-'opportu describe the common conditions sufficient for profit-seekin rebel organizations to exist. On our evidence they are observa since we cannot observe motives. They can jointly be contraste account of conflict in which the grievances that both motivate are assumed to be well-grounded in objective circumstanc high inequality, or unusually weak political rights. We now t for opportunities and objective grievances. 2.2 Proxies for opportunity The first step in an empirical investigation of conflict is a cl definition of the phenomenon. We define civil war as an inter least 1,000 combat-related deaths per year. In order to dis massacres, both government forces and an identifiable rebel suffer at least 5% of these fatalities. This definition has becom the seminal data collection of Small and Singer (1982) and Sin We use an expanded and updated version of their data set that over the period 1960-99 and identifies 79 civil wars, listed in T explain the initiation of civil war using these data.3 We now consider quantitative indicators of opportunity, start ties for financing rebellion. We consider three common sources resources, donations from diasporas, and subventions from h Klare (2001) provides a good discussion of natural resource e diamonds in West Africa, timber in Cambodia, and cocaine in C we proxy natural resources by the ratio of primary commodity each of the 161 countries. As with our other variables, we m five years, starting in 1960 and ending in 1995. We then con five years as an 'episode' and compare those in which a civil w flict episodes') with those that were conflict-free ('peace episod statistics give little support to the opportunity thesis: the conf average slightly less dependent upon primary commodity exp episodes. However, there is a substantial difference in the dis episodes tended to have either markedly below-average or mar dependence, while the conflict episodes were grouped around t 3 Later in the paper (Table 6) we examine whether our results are sensitive to th Sambanis (2002) comes to a similar conclusion. 4 We list the data sources and definitions in the Appendix. 5 The standard deviation of primary commodity exports is 0.11 for the conflict peace episodes. This content downloaded from 147.251.110.131 on Tue, 22 Mar 2022 12:08:37 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms 566 P. COLLIER AND A. HOEFFLER Table 1 Outbreaks of war Country Start of End of Previous war Gdp Secondary the war the war sample schooling sample Afghanistan 04/78 02/92 Afghanistan 05/92 Ongoing Algeria 07/62 12/62 Algeria 05/91 Ongoing Angola 02/61 11/75 Angola 11/75 05/91 Angola 09/92 Ongoing * Azerbaijan 04/91 10/94 Bosnia 03/92 11/95 Burma/Myanmar 68 10/80 Burma/Myanmar 02/83 07/95 Burundi 04/72 12/73 Burundi 08/88 08/88 * Burundi 11/91 ongoing Cambodia 03/70 10/91 Chad 03/80 08/88 China 01/67 09/68 Columbia 04/84 ongoing Congo 97 10/97 Cyprus 07/74 08/74 Dominican Rep. 04/65 09/65 * El Salvador 10/79 01/92 Ethiopia 07/74 05/91 Georgia 06/91 12/93 Guatemala 07/66 07/72 Guatemala 03/78 03/84 Guinea-Bissau 12/62 12/74 India 08/65 08/65 * India 84 94 * Indonesia 06/75 09/82 * Iran 03/74 03/75 Iran 09/78 12/79 * Iran 06/81 05/82 * Iraq 09/61 11/63 Iraq 07/74 03/75 Iraq 01/85 12/92 Jordan 09/70 09/70 Laos 07/60 02/73 Lebanon 05/75 09/92 Liberia 12/89 11/91 Liberia 10/92 11/96 Morocco 10/75 11/89 Mozambique 10/64 11/75 Mozambique 07/76 10/92 Nicaragua 10/78 07/79 Nicaragua 03/82 04/90 Nigeria 01/66 01/70 (continu This content downloaded from 147.251.110.131 on Tue, 22 Mar 2022 12:08:37 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms GREED AND GRIEVANCE 567 Table 1 Continued Country Start of End of Previous war Gdp Secondary the war the war sample schooling sample Nigeria 12/80 08/84 * * Pakistan 03/71 12/71 * * Pakistan 01/73 07/77 Peru 03/82 12/96 * * Philippines 09/72 12/96 * * * Romania 12/89 12/89 * * Russia 12/94 08/96 Russia 09/99 Ongoing * Rwanda 11/63 02/64 Rwanda 10/90 07/94 * * * Sierra Leone 03/91 11/96 * * Sierra Leone 05/97 07/99 * * Somalia 04/82 05/88 * * Somalia 05/88 12/92 * * Sri Lanka 04/71 05/71 * * Sri Lanka 07/83 ongoing * * * Sudan 10/63 02/72 Sudan 07/83 ongoing * * * Tajikistan 04/92 12/94 Turkey 07/91 ongoing * Uganda 05/66 06/66 * * Uganda 10/80 04/88 * * * Vietnam 01/60 04/75 * Yemen 05/90 10/94 Yemen, Arab Rep. 11/62 09/69 * Yemen, People's Rep. 01/86 01/86 Yugoslavia 04/90 01/92 Yugoslavia 10/98 04/99 * Zaire/Dem. Rep. of Congo 07/60 09/65 Zaire/Dem. Rep. of Congo 09/91 12/96 * * * Zaire/Dem. Rep. of Congo 09/97 09/99 * * * Zimbabwe 12/72 12/79 * * Note: Previous wars include war start natural resources are sufficien be so well-financed that rebel make the net effect of natu may also reflect differences Section 3). Further, primary that may cause civil war, suc economic mismanagement (Sa conflict risk may be due to r financial opportunities. 6 Collier (2000) provides an illustrati This content downloaded from 147.251.110.131 on Tue, 22 Mar 2022 12:08:37 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms 568 P. COLLIER AND A. HOEFFLER Table 2 Descriptive statistics Sample No civil war Civil war (n = 1167) (n = 1089) (n 78) War starts 0.067 0 1 Primary commodity exports/GDP 0.168 0.169 0.149 GDP per capita (const. US$) 4061 4219 1645 Diaspora (relative to population of 0.017 0.018 0.004 country of origin) Male secondary schooling (% in school) 43.42 44.39 30.3 GDP per capita growth (average for 1.62 1.74 -0.23 previous 5 years) Previous war (% with war since 1945) 20.8 18.5 53.8 Peace duration (months since last conflict) 327 334 221 Forest cover (%) 31.11 31.33 27.81 Mountainous terrain (%) 15.82 15.17 24.93 Geographic concentration of the 0.571 0.569 0.603 population (Gini) Population density (inhabitants per 150 156 62 square km) Population in urban areas (%) 45.11 46.00 32.7 Ethnic fractionalization (index, 0-100) 39.57 38.64 52.63 Religious fractionalization (index, 0-100) 36.09 35.98 37.70 Polarization a= 1.6 (index, 0-0.165) 0.077 0.077 0.076 Democracy (index, 0-10) 3.91 4.07 1.821 Ethnic dominance (% with main ethnic 0.465 0.465 0.452 group 45-90%) Income inequality (Gini) 0.406 0.406 0.410 Land inequality (Gini) 0.641 0.641 0.631 Note: We examine 78-rather than the 79-war starts a two outbreaks of war during 1970-74. We only include o A second source of rebel finance is from (1996) review the evidence, an example bein Tamils in north America. We proxy the size o living in the US, as given in US Census data. in other countries, it ensures uniformity in same legal, organizational, and economic env population as a proportion of the population analysis we decompose the diaspora into tha which is exogenous to conflict, but here we These do not support the opportunity thesis the conflict episodes. A third source of rebel finance is from the government of Southern Rhodesia pu Mozambique. Our proxy for the willingness military opposition to the incumbent gover Cold War each great power supported rebelli This content downloaded from 147.251.110.131 on Tue, 22 Mar 2022 12:08:37 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms GREED AND GRIEVANCE 569 power. There is some support for the opportunity thesis: only broke out during the 1990s. We next consider opportunities arising from atypically low c be paid, and their cost may be related to the income forgone b Rebellions may occur when foregone income is unusually low mists regard this as fanciful we give the example of the Russia Whites, both rebel armies, had four million desertions (the ob ment problem). The desertion rate was ten times higher in sum the recruits being peasants, income foregone were much high (Figes, 1996). We try three proxies for foregone income: mea male secondary schooling, and the growth rate of the economy. the conflict episodes started from less than half the mean in episodes. However, so many characteristics are correlated wit that, depending upon what other variables are included, the pr interpretations. Our second proxy, male secondary school advantage of being focused on young males-the group fro recruited. The conflict episodes indeed started from lower but this is again open to alternative interpretation: education m of conflict through changing attitudes. Our third measure, th economy in the preceding period, is intended to proxy new in Conflict episodes were preceded by lower growth rates. This evidence that the lower is the rate of growth, the higher is unconstitutional political change (Alesina et al., 1996).7 Althoug are all consistent with atypically low forgone income as an opp could also be interpreted as an objective economic grievance. The opportunity for rebellion may be that conflict-spec military equipment) is unusually cheap. We proxy the cost of time since the most recent previous conflict: the legacy of weap organizational capital will gradually depreciate. Empirically preceded by far longer periods of peace than conflict episode this supports the opportunity thesis, it could also be interpret gradual decay of conflict-induced grievances. Another dimension of opportunity is an atypically weak go capability. An unambiguous indicator is if the terrain is favora and mountains provide rebels with a safe haven. We measure country's terrain that is forested, using FAO data. We could fin 7 The economic growth literature concentrates on the analysis of political insta economic growth (see for example Barro 1991, 1997). Alesina et al. (1996) equation system of economic growth and political instability. They present su that political instability reduces growth. Lower growth does not seem to c defined as the number of government changes. However, when they define p narrowly as unconstitutional government changes they find that lower growth political instability. This content downloaded from 147.251.110.131 on Tue, 22 Mar 2022 12:08:37 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms 570 P. COLLIER AND A. HOEFFLER on mountainous terrain: proxies such as altitude tend to misc and rugged uplands. We therefore commissioned a new index John Gerrard. The descriptive statistics (Table 2) suggest that t conflict episodes 25% of the terrain is mountainous, versu episodes, although there is no difference in forest cover. Geog the population may also inhibit government capability: Herbst Zaire is prone to rebellion because its population lives arou country. We measure dispersion by calculating a Gini coeffic dispersion.8 In fact, the concentration of the population is slig peace episodes (0.57) than prior to war episodes (0.6). Simil density and low urbanization may inhibit government capabilit to war episodes both population density and urbanization are A final source of rebel military opportunity may be social c religious diversity within organizations tends to reduce their (Easterly and Levine, 1997, Alesina et al., 1999, Collier, 2001). A army may be in particular need of social cohesion, constrain single ethnic or religious group. A diverse society might in t opportunity for rebellion by limiting the recruitment pool. T measure of ethnic diversity is the index of ethno-linguistic fr measures the probability that two randomly drawn people wil ethnic groups. We could find no measure of religious fractio constructed one equivalent to that of ethnic fractionalization Barrett (1982). If ethnic and religious divisions are cross-cuttin lization is multiplicative rather than additive. We could f religious and ethnic divisions and so we construct a proxy tha mum potential social fractionalization.9 The thesis that social opportunity is not supported by the descriptive statistics: co atypically high fractionalization. This seems more consiste interpretation, to which we now turn. 2.3 Proxying objective grievances We consider four objective measures of grievance: ethnic or re tical repression, political exclusion, and economic inequality. 8 For the calculation of the Gini coefficient we used the population data per the income Gini coefficient, the Gini coefficient of population dispersion will concentrated in a relatively small area of the country. 9 If there were e equally sized ethnic groups and r equally sized religious gr social fractionalization would be measured simply by the product er. Since both ethnic and religious fractionalization range on the scale 0-100, their product religious or ethnic homogeneity whereas there is social homogeneity only if therefore measure social fractionalization as the product of the underlying ind is the greater. This content downloaded from 147.251.110.131 on Tue, 22 Mar 2022 12:08:37 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms GREED AND GRIEVANCE 571 Ethnic and religious hatreds are widely perceived as a cause Although such hatreds cannot be quantified, they can evid societies that are multi-ethnic or multi-religious and so ou various dimensions of diversity. Our previously discussed meas zation are pertinent: inter-group hatreds must be greater in fractionalized than in those which are homogenous. Howe source of inter-group tension is not diversity but polarization allowable class of measures of polarization is quite limited. measure due to Esteban and Ray (1994) P= K 7l+crjd (1) i=1 j=l where 7i denotes the percentage of people that belong to group i in the t population, i= 1,... , n. This measure of polarization depends on the parameters K and a. K does not change the order, but is used for population normalization Esteban and Ray show that ac is bounded between zero and 1.6. We calcul the polarization measure for three different values of a, 0, 0.8 and 1.6, us primary data on ethnic composition."1 In addition we investigate the variant o the Esteban-Ray measure proposed by Reynal-Querol. These measures indeed d tinguish polarization from fractionalization: their correlation coefficient rang between 0.39 (a= 1.6) and 1.0 (a = 0).12 The descriptive data does not sugge that polarization is important: conflict and peace episodes have very similar m values (Table 2). We measure political repression using the Polity III data set (see Jaggers and Gurr, 1995). This measure of political rights ranges 0-10 on an ascending ordin scale. Political rights differ considerably between conflict and peace episodes. also investigate the Polity III measure of autocracy, and a measure of polit openness published by Freedom House (the 'Gastil Index'). The quantitative poli tical science literature has already applied these measures to conflict risk. Heg et al. (2001) find that repression increases conflict except when it is severe. Even in democracies a small group may fear permanent exclusion. A potential important instance is if political allegiance is based on ethnicity and one ethn group has a majority. The incentive to exploit the minority increases the larger the minority, since there is more to extract (Collier, 2001). Hence, a minority l?The link from polarization to conflict is proposed by Esteban and Ray (1999) and Reynal-Qu (2000) and is common in the popular literature. l Our data source was Atlas Narodov Mira, USSR (1964). The Esteban-Ray measure includes a coe cient d that denotes the degree of antagonism between two different ethnic groups. Obviously, in la samples such as we are using this is not observed. Following Reynal-Querol (2000) we assume that distance between any two ethnic groups is unity whereas that within the group is zero, so that d ha properties: d = 1 if i f j and d = 0 if i =j. 12 For a = 0 the polarization measure is equal to the Gini coefficient. This content downloaded from 147.251.110.131 on Tue, 22 Mar 2022 12:08:37 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms 572 P. COLLIER AND A. HOEFFLER may be most vulnerable if the largest ethnic group constitutes term this ethnic dominance. In Table 2 we define it as occurring group constitutes 45-90% of the population. On this definitio important: it is as common in peace episodes as in conflict ep The opening page of Sen's On Economic Inequality (Sen, 197 relation between inequality and rebellion is indeed a close one'. to induce redistribution, and rich regions may mount secession empt redistribution.l3 We measure income inequality by the by the ratio of the top-to-bottom quintiles of income. We me by the Gini coefficient of land ownership. The data are from (1996, 1998). Inequality is slightly higher prior to the conflict 2.4 Scale effects Our measures of opportunity, such as primary commodity exports, income, and school enrolment, are scaled by measures of country size. For given values of these variables, opportunities should be approximately proportional to size. Grievance might also increase with size: public choices diverge more from the preferences of the average individual as heterogeneity increases.'4 We are, however, able to control for three aspects of heterogeneity: ethnic, religious and income diversity. Empirically, the conflict episodes had markedly larger populations than the peace episodes. 3. Regression analysis As set out above, the proxies for opportunity and objective grievances are largely distinct and so can be compared as two non-nested econometric models. There is, however, no reason for the accounts to be exclusive and the aim of our econometric tests is to arrive at an integrated model which gives an account of conflict risk in terms of all those opportunities and grievances that are significant. We now attempt to predict the risk that a civil war will start during a five-year episode, through a logit regression. Our dependent variable, civil war start, takes a value of one if a civil war started during a five year episode (1965-69,..., 1994-99). Episodes that were peaceful from the beginning until the end are coded zero. Ongoing wars are coded as missing observations as to not conflate the analysis of civil war initiation and duration.15 If a war ended and another one started in the same period we coded these events as one. Some of our explanatory variables are 13 This is analogous to the theory of tax exit proposed by Buchanan and Faith (1987). 14 Mounting diversity is the offset to scale economies in the provision of public goods in the model of optimal county size proposed by Alesina and Spolaore (1997). 15 This approach contrasts with our initial work (Collier and Hoeffler, 1998) in which we used a tobit procedure to study the duration of civil war (on a much inferior data set) and argued that the same factors that determined duration would determine the risk of initiation. Collier et al. (2004) establishes that this is wrong: initiation and duration are radically different processes. This content downloaded from 147.251.110.131 on Tue, 22 Mar 2022 12:08:37 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms GREED AND GRIEVANCE 573 time invariant. Those that are not are measured either for th period (e.g. 1965) or during the preceding five years (e.g. gro in order to avoid endogeneity problems. Our results rest on h experienced an outbreak of war differed from those that sust We start with the opportunity model (see Table 3). The first r excludes per capita income and diasporas. Because per capita inc Table 3 Opportunity model 1 2 3 4 5 Primary comm exports/GDP (Primary com exports/GDP)2 Post-coldwar Male secondary schooling Ln GDP per capita GDP growth Peace duration Previous war Mountainous terrain Geographic dispersion Social fractionalization Ln population Diaspora/peace 18.149 (6.006)*** -27.445 (11.996)*** -0.326 (0.469) -0.025 (0.010)** -0.117 (0.044)*** -0.003 (0.002) p=0.128 0.464 (0.547) p= 0.396 0.013 (0.009) p=0.164 -2.211 (1.038)** -0.0002 (0.0001) p= 0.109 0.669 (0.163)*** 18.900 (5.948)*** -29.123 (11.905)*** -0.207 (0.450) -0.024 (0.010)** -0.118 (0.044)*** -0.004*** (0.001) 16.476 (5.207)*** -23.017 (9.972)** -0.454 (0.416) -0.837 (0.253)*** -0.105 (0.042)*** -0.004 (0.001)*** 17.567 (6.744)*** -28.815 (15.351)* 17.404 (6.750)*** -28.456 (15.366)* -1.237 -1.243 (0.283)*** (0.284)*** -0.002 -0.002 (0.001) (0.001) 0.014 0.008 (0.009) (0.008) -2.129 (1.032)** -0.0002 (0.0001) p=0.122 0.686 (0.162)*** -0.865 (0.948) -0.0002 (0.0001)** 0.493 0.295 (0.129)*** (0.141)** 700.931 (363.29)** Diaspora corrected/peace (Diaspora-diaspora corrected)/peace N No of wars Pseudo R2 Log likelihood 688 46 0.24 -128.49 688 46 0.24 -128.85 750 52 0.22 -146.86 595 29 0.25 -93.27 0.296 (0.141)** 741.155 (387.636)* 823.941 (556.024) 595 29 0.25 -93.23 Notes: All regressions include a constant. Standard errors in parentheses. ***, *, * indicate s the 1, 5, and 10% level, respectively. This content downloaded from 147.251.110.131 on Tue, 22 Mar 2022 12:08:37 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms 574 P. COLLIER AND A. HOEFFLER in secondary schooling are highly correlated, they canno regression (p = 0.8). Our diaspora measure is available only and so we explore it as an addendum. The variables included i permit a sample of 688 episodes (from 123 countries), includ Primary commodity exports are highly significant. Althoug linear, the risk of conflict peaks when they constitute around is a high level of dependence. The other proxy for finance, th has the expected sign but is insignificant. The foregone ear both significant with the expected sign: secondary schoolin reduce conflict risk. Our proxy for the cost of conflictnumber of months since any previous conflict (back to between this interpretation and the danger that the proxy fixed effects, we add a dummy variable that is unity if there post-1945. Our proxy has the expected sign and is on the bord while the dummy variable is completely insignificant. When t dropped (column 2) the proxy becomes highly significant and changed. The proxies for military advantage also have the e marginally significant: mountainous terrain, population dispe tionalization. Finally, the coefficient on population is positive The third column replaces secondary schooling with per permits a larger sample-750 episodes (from 125 countrie Per capita income is highly significant with the expected n the change of variable and the expansion of sample have littl results-social fractionalization becomes significant and p loses significance. There is little to chose between these model-secondary schooling gives a slightly better fit, but p mits a slightly larger sample. In the last two columns of Table 3 we introduce our dia many observations are missing, the number of war episodes w radically reduced. In order to preserve sample size we therefo parsimonious version of the model. We drop four sample-co explanatory variables: social fractionalization, population dis terrain, and the rate of growth in the previous episode. The variables are thus per capita GDP, primary commodity export number of months since the previous conflict. Even with t deletions, the sample size is reduced to 29 war episodes (a However, all the included explanatory variables remain signif diaspora is not directly significant in the initiation of conflic it is significant when interacted with the number of month ous conflict. 'Diaspora/peace' divides the size of the diaspora .......................................................................................................................................................................... 16 We differentiate the proba the risk is at its maximum This content downloaded from 147.251.110.131 on Tue, 22 Mar 2022 12:08:37 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms GREED AND GRIEVANCE 575 previous conflict. The variable is positive and significant: a la erably increases the risk of repeat conflict. While this result may indicate that diasporas increase the risk their finance of rebel organizations, it is also open to a more a tion. Diasporas are endogenous to the intensity of conflict: wh people emigrate to the USA. Hence, the size of the diaspora mi intensity of conflict. The result may therefore be spurious: in have a higher risk of repetition. To test for this we decompos into a component which is exogenous to the intensity of con endogenous component. For this decomposition we estimated reported in Appendix 1. The size of the diaspora in a census ye a function of its size in the previous census, time, per capita in of origin, and whether there was a war in the intervening predicts the size of the diaspora with reasonable accuracy. Fo to a conflict we replace the actual data on the size of the diasp from this regression. Thus, all post-conflict observations of d which are purged of any effect of the intensity of conflict. Th actual and estimated figures is then used as an additional varia part of the diaspora which is potentially endogenous to the i Both of these measures are then introduced into the regressi previous single measure of the diaspora. The results are r column of Table 3. The purged measure of the diaspora remai the size of the coefficient is only slightly altered (it is not signific that on the endogenous diaspora measure). This suggests th substantial causal effect of the diaspora on the risk of conflict also guides our interpretation of why the risk of conflict repet is maintained. Recall that in principle this could be either beca fade, or because 'rebellion-specific capital' gradually depreciat sporas slow these processes? Diasporas preserve their own hatr finance rebellion. However, it is unlikely that the diaspora's influence attitudes among the much larger population in the By contrast, the finance provided by the diaspora can offset rebellion-specific capital, thereby sustaining conflict risk. In Table 4 we turn to objective grievance as the explanation ping all the economic measures of opportunity.17 We retain th since a previous conflict, since (subject to our discussion abov preted as proxying fading hatreds. In the first column we also measures due to considerations of sample size. This enables a 850 episodes and 59 civil wars. 1 We retain the two geographic measures, population dispersion and mount their exclusion does not affect the results, non-economists often find the pro opportunity affects conflict plausible and inoffensive, while contesting the role We retain population size as a scale variable. This content downloaded from 147.251.110.131 on Tue, 22 Mar 2022 12:08:37 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms 576 P. COLLIER AND A. HOEFFLER Table 4 Grievance model 1 2 3 Ethnic fractionalization 0.010 0.011 0.012 (0.006)* (0.007)* (0.008) Religious fractionalization -0.003 -0.006 -0.004 (0.007) (0.008) (0.009) Polarization a = 1.6 -3.067 -4.682 -6.536 (7.021) (8.267) (8.579) Ethnic dominance (45-90%) 0.414 0.575 1.084 (0.496) (0.586) (0.629)* Democracy -0.109 -0.083 -0.121 (0.044)*** (0.051)* (0.053)** Peace duration -0.004 -0.003 -0.004 (0.001)*** (0.001)*** (0.001)*** Mountainous terrain 0.011 0.007 -0.0001 (0.007) (0.009) (0.009) Geographic dispersion -0.509 -0.763 -1.293 (0.856) (1.053) (0.102) Ln population 0.221 0.246 0.300 (0.096)** (0.119)** (1.133)** Income inequality 0.015 (0.018) Land inequality 0.461 (1.305) N 850 604 603 No of wars 59 41 38 Pseudo R2 0.13 0.11 0.17 Log likelihood -185.57 -133.46 -117.12 Notes: All regressions include a constant. Standard er the 1, 5 and 10% level, respectively. Column 1: the two measures of fractionalization and The four proxies for ethnic and religious view of the attention that the phenomen significant at 10% with the expected sign tion are insignificant with the wrong sign Nor are the three measures jointly signif with the expected sign-repression incr previous conflict is again highly signific more likely to be proxying rebellion-s second and third columns we introduce respectively. Although the sample size is 18 At this stage we measure polarization with a = 1.6 largest ethnic group constitutes 45-90% of the popu where we investigate robustness to alternative defini This content downloaded from 147.251.110.131 on Tue, 22 Mar 2022 12:08:37 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms GREED AND GRIEVANCE 577 episodes of which 41 (income) and 38 (land) are wars. Neither significance.19 All three grievance models have very low expla pseudo R2 of 0.17 or lower. We now turn to the question of which model, opportunity or a better explanation of the risk of civil war. Since the two mo i.e. one model is not a special case of the other, we use the J Davidson and MacKinnon (1981). As shown in the first two colu find that we cannot reject one model in favor of the other.20 T while the opportunity model is superior, some elements of the likely to add to its explanatory power. We therefore investigat the two models as presented in column 3 of Table 5. Since this combined model includes income inequality a our sample size is much reduced (479 observations). In column ity (which is consistently insignificant). Omitting inequality size to 665. In this combined model neither democracy, e fractionalization nor the post-Cold War dummy are significa are statistically significant or close to significance and th sonable (pseudo R2 of 0.26). Since both the grievance and o are nested in the combined model, we can use a likelihood rat mine whether the combined model is superior. We can re the restrictions proposed by the grievance model, but not by model.21 Although the combined model is superior to the opportunity and grievance models, several variables are completely insignificant and we drop them sequentially. First we exclude the post-Cold War dummy, then religious fractionalization, .......................................................................................................................................................................... 19We also tried the r insignificant. 20 The J-test is based on in terms of the two di (1) p = f(opportunity) (2) p = f(grievance) Based on these logit re popportunity and fgriev (1) p = f(opportunity, p (2) p = f(grievance, p?PP According to the J-tes between the two diffe opportunity model in f we reject the grievance Table 5, grievance is sig model. 21Using the same sample as for the combined model (n=665) we obtain the following results: Opportunity model versus combined model, 5 degrees of freedom, Likelihood Ratio Test (LRT) statistic 7.85 (p = 0.165); grievance model versus combined model, 6 degrees of freedom, LRT statistic 29.64 (p = 0.000). This content downloaded from 147.251.110.131 on Tue, 22 Mar 2022 12:08:37 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms Table 5 Combined opportunity and grievance model 1 2 3 4 Primary com exports/GDP (Primary commodity exports/GDP)2 Post-coldwar Male secondary schooling Ln GDP per capita (GDP growth) t-1 Peace duration Mountainous terrain Geographic dispersion Ln population Social fractionalization 19.107 (5.996)*** -30.262 (12.008)*** -0.208 (0.457) -0.021 (0.011)** -0.108 (0.044)*** -0.0003 (0.002) 0.005 (0.010) -1.976 (1.049)* 0.489 (0.193)** -0.0002 (0.0001)*** Ethnic fractionalization Religious fractionalization Polarization 0.0005 (0.0014) 0.001 (0.008) 0.053 (1.101) -0.022 (0.136) 0.008 (0.007) -0.005 (0.008) -9.338 37.072 (10.293)*** -69.270 (21.697)*** -0.873 (0.644) -0.029 (0.013)** -0.045 (0.062) -0.0003 (0.0015) 0.005 (0.012) -4.032 (1.490)*** 0.927 (0.250)*** -0.0008 (0.0003)** 0.041 (0.019)** 0.015 (0.020) -25.276 23.385 (6.692)** -36.335 (12.998) -0.281 (0.459) -0.022 (0.011) -0.108 (0.045)* -0.003 (0.001)* 0.015 (0.009) p=O.11 -1.962 (1.149) 0.697 (0.181)** -0.0005 (0.0003) p=0.11 0.023 (0.015) 0.014 (0.019) -15.992 This content downloaded from 147.251.110.131 on Tue, 22 Mar 2022 12:08:37 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms (8.734) (13.390)* (10.518) Ethnic dominance (45-90%) 1.210 2.020 1.5 (0.648)* (0.915)** (0.746 Democracy -0.036 -0.018 -0.042 (0.054) (0.062) (0.054) Income inequality 0.025 (0.024) Grievance predicted value 0.765 (0.413)* Opportunity predicted value 1.044 (0.21 1)*** Primary commodity exports oil dummy (9. (Primary commodity exports/ oil dummy (38 N 665 665 479 665 68 No of wars 46 46 32 4 Pseudo R2 0.24 0.25 0.24 0.26 Log likelihood -126.69 -125.29 -89.55 -124.60 Notes: All regressions include a constant. Sta This content downloaded from 147.251.110.131 on Tue, 22 Mar 2022 12:08:37 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms 580 P. COLLIER AND A. HOEFFLER then democracy,22 then polarization, then ethnic fraction mountainous terrain, yielding the baseline model of colum with per capita income replacing secondary enrolment in colu reduction in the model is accepted, and no additions of variab previous models are accepted. The baseline model and its varian results although the variant has less explanatory power an significance (ethnic dominance and geographic dispersion). Our baseline model allows us to calculate the change in the starts for different values of the explanatory variables. We prese in Appendix Table A2. At the mean of all variables the risk of 11.5%. Our model predicts that a hypothetical country with teristics found in our sample would have a near-certain risk of all the best characteristics would have a negligible risk. We no variable affects the risk of civil war (keeping all other variab values). The effect of primary commodity exports on conflict risk is both highly significant and considerable. At peak danger (primary commodity exports being 33% of GDP), the risk of civil war is about 22%, while a country with no such exports has a risk of only 1%. The effect is sufficiently important to warrant disaggregation into different types of commodities. We categorized primary commodity exports according to which type of product was dominant: food, non-food agriculture, oil, other raw materials, and a residual category of 'mixed'.23 Of the many potential disaggregations of primary commodity exports permitted by this data, only one was significant when introduced into our baseline regression, namely oil versus non-oil. The results are reported in column 7. We add variables that interact the primary commodity export share and its square with a dummy variable that takes the value of unity if the exports are predominantly oil. Both variables are significant: oil exports have a distinct effect on the risk of conflict. However, the effect is modest: at the average value of primary commodity exports oil has the same effect as other commodities. Low levels of oil dependence are somewhat less risky than other commodities and high levels of dependence are somewhat more risky. The disaggregation slightly reduces the sample size, does not change the significance of any of the other variables, and substantially improves the overall fit of the model.24 Recall that the other proxies for financial opportunities, the Cold War and diasporas, are not included in this baseline. The end of the Cold War does not 22 We tried different specifications to test for the effect of political repression by investigating non-linear effects, by including the autocracy score instead of the democracy score, and by using the difference between the two variables as suggested by Londregan and Poole (1996). We also tried the Freedom House measure of political freedom, but neither of these alternative political repression measures were found to be significant. 23 We would like to thank Jan Dehn for providing us with the data that enabled this disaggregation. 24 Furthermore, using data from Dehn (2000) we investigated whether contemporaneous export price changes altered the risk of conflict. We could not find any evidence to support this hypothesis. This content downloaded from 147.251.110.131 on Tue, 22 Mar 2022 12:08:37 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms GREED AND GRIEVANCE 581 appear to have had a significant effect. Diasporas are excluded purely for considerations of sample size. In the parsimonious v are included, their effect on the risk of repeat conflict is substan of peace, switching the size of the diaspora from the smallest to post-conflict episodes increases the risk of conflict six-fold. The proxies for earnings foregone have substantial effects. If for secondary schooling is ten percentage points higher than th war is reduced by about three percentage points (a decline in t to 8.6%). An additional percentage point on the growth rate red by about one percentage point (a decline from 11.5% to 10.4% for the cost of rebellion is also highly significant and substant civil war there is a high probability of a re-start, the risk being declines over time at around one percentage point per year. The only measures of rebel military advantage that survive i population dispersion and social fractionalization. Consis hypothesis, countries with a highly concentrated population h of conflict, whereas those with a highly dispersed population h (about 37%). Consistent with the hypothesis that cohesion is i effectiveness, social fractionalization makes a society substan mally fractionalized society has a conflict risk only one quart genous society. Only one of the proxies for grievance survives into the bas namely ethnic dominance. If a country is characterized by et risk of conflict is nearly doubled. Thus, the net effect of increase the sum of its effect on social fractionalization and its effect on ethnic dominance. Starting from homogeneity, as diversity increases the society is likely to become characterized by ethnic dominance, although this will be reversed by further increases in diversity. The risk of conflict would first rise and then fall. Note that while these measures in combination are superficially similar to the hypothesized effect of polarization, our measure of polarization itself is insignificant. Finally, the coefficient on the scale variable, population, is highly significant and close to unity: risk is approximately proportional to size. We have suggested that proportionality is more likely if conflict is generated by opportunities than by grievances. 4. Robustness checks We now test these baseline results for robustness. We consider the sensitivity bot to data and to method. With respect to data, we investigate the effect of outlying observations, and of different definitions of the dependent and independent vari ables. With respect to method, we investigate random effects, fixed effects and ra events bias. We investigate outlying observations using two different methods. First, we inspect the characteristics of the 46 conflict episodes used in the baseline regressio This content downloaded from 147.251.110.131 on Tue, 22 Mar 2022 12:08:37 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms 582 P. COLLIER AND A. HOEFFLER and second, we use a systematic analysis of influential data po is unbalanced as between events and non-events, the potential arises predominantly among the 46 conflict episodes. Of these were first-time conflicts and 22 were repeat conflicts. First, the classification of events in Romania in 1989, and in and 1981 as civil wars is in various respects questionable. They highly atypical of conflict episodes. Both had secondary scho higher than the other conflict episodes, and Iran also had primary commodity export share. In Table 6 column 1 we dr observations. No results are overturned, but the performanc improves and all variables are now significant at the 1% or 5 There are four observations of highly negative growth: Ang (now the Democratic Republic of the Congo) in 1990-95, Iran in 1980-84. All of these growth collapses appear to be genuin different countries. We now check whether the result that the conflict risk is dependent upon these four observations, deleti Iran and Romania (Table 6, column 2). Growth remains signific cient is only slightly reduced. Hence, we can conclude that th conflict due to slow growth is not confined to episodes of gro more continuous relationship. We next analyse whether our regression results are sensitive influential data points. Based on the methods developed by P examined which observations may be influential and investigat these observations from our baseline model changed our resu influential observations: Congo 1995-99, Iran 1970-74, an However, when we omitted these three observations from our all fit of the regressions improved (from previously R2 = 0.24 of the coefficients remain statistically significant. (Table 6, co We now investigate the possibility that a few countries with export ratio account for the non-monotonic relationship to c might imply that the reduction in conflict risk only occurre of commodity dependence. Four peaceful countries have part of primary dependence: Saudi Arabia, Guyana, Oman, and Tri In Table 6 column 4 we present our baseline model exclud primary commodity exporters. The non-monotonic relationsh commodity exports and the risk of conflict remains signific results. We next turn to questions of variable definition. The most contentious aspect of the dependent variable is distinguishing between whether a country has a single long war or multiple shorter wars interrupted by periods of peace. In the above analysis we have been guided by the judgement of the political scientists who built .........(1997) pp.98-101 provides a discussion of influence in limited dependent variable models. 25 Long (1997) pp.98-101 provides a discussion of influence in limited dependent variable models. This content downloaded from 147.251.110.131 on Tue, 22 Mar 2022 12:08:37 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms GREED AND GRIEVANCE 583 the original data sets. Some peace periods are, however, quite s better to conceptualize these as interludes in a single war. We f those wars that were separated by peace periods of less than tinuous wars (Table 6, column 5). The baseline results are redefinition. We then reclassified those wars separated by less tinuous wars (Table 6, column 6). The only result to be affected rate becomes marginally insignificant (p = 0.12), although its changed.26 We investigated how robust our results are to the definition of ethnic dominance and social fractionalization. In the baseline we define ethnic dominance as the largest ethnic group constituting 45-90% of the population. We investigate other definitions that either vary the range of the population or use the share of the largest group regardless of its size. As the range is changed from 45-90% th significance level and the coefficient are both reduced, while if the definition is changed more radically to being the population share of the largest group it is completely insignificant. We also find that 'social fractionalization', our measure o cross-cutting cleavages, dominates the other possible aggregation procedures for ethnic and religious diversity. When this measure of fractionalization is included with the ethnic and religious diversity indices either together or individually, it i significant whereas the underlying indices are not significant. In the baseline we use only the most extreme measure of polarization over the range proposed by Esteban and Ray (1994). However, if this measure is replaced by either the lower bound (a =0), or the central measure (a =0.8) the results are unaffected: polarization remains insignificant and the other variables remain sig nificant. We also experimented with the alternative measure proposed by ReynalQuerol (2002), and with the number of ethnic groups, but with the same result.27 In Table 7 we investigate a number of different estimation issues. We concentrat on the analysis of random effects, fixed effects, time effects, and a correction for rare events. We re-estimated our models using random effects. For the baseline model we find that the panel data estimator is not different from the pooled estimator, i.e. we accept the hypothesis that we can pool across the observations.28 The estimation of fixed effects logits was only possible on a very small sub-sample of the observations. The countries for which the dependent variable does not vary over time (the majority of countries experienced only peace) cannot be included in 26 We also examined the effect of time since the previous conflict in more detail by including the natura logarithm of the peace variable or its square, however, a linear decay term provides a better fit. Note tha the measure of peace since the end of the civil war is somewhat imprecise since we only measure it from the end of the war to the initial year of each sub-period. A duration model of post-war peace would allow a more detailed analysis of this peace effect, however, the duration model results in Collier et al. (2004 support the results presented in this paper. 27All of these robustness checks are presented in Collier and Hoeffler (2002). 28 A LRT provides a x2 statistic of 0 (p = 0.998). Thus, we cannot reject the null-hypothesis that the pane data and pooled estimator provide the same results. This content downloaded from 147.251.110.131 on Tue, 22 Mar 2022 12:08:37 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms Table 6 Robustness checks 1 2 3 Excluding Excluding Excluding Exclud Iran and Iran and Romania influential high pri Romania and growth data points commo collapses exporters Primary commodity exports/GDP (Prim. com. exports/GDP)2 Male secondary schooling (GDP growth) t- 1 Peace duration Geographic dispersion 19.696 (6.608)*** -34.090 (14.356)** -0.035 (0.01 1)*** -0.140 (0.047)*** -0.004 (0.001)*** -2.114 (1.080)** 19.029 (6.671)*** -33.250 (14.609)** -0.037 (0.011)*** -0.100 (0.052)** -0.003 (0.001)*** -2.272 (1.090)** 28.745 (7.862)*** -59.818 (17.781)*** -0.041 (0.011)*** -0.137 (0.046)*** -0.004 (0.0011) -2.890 (1.136)*** 18 (6.0 -2 (12 -0 (0. -0 (0. -0 (0.0 -2 (1 This content downloaded from 147.251.110.131 on Tue, 22 Mar 2022 12:08:37 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms Social fractionalization Ethnic dominance Ln population N No. of wars Pseudo R2 Log likelihood -0.0002 (0.0001)** 0.727 (0.368)** 0.747 (0.174)*** 674 42 0.25 -118.40 -0.0002 (0.0001)** 0.732 (0.370)** 0.743 (0.175)*** 671 39 0.22 -116.17 -0.0003 (0.0001)*** 0.655 (0.372)* 0.899 (0.195)*** 685 43 0.29 -114.04 -0.0 (0.0 0.6 (0.3 0.7 (0.1 6 4 0. -12 Notes: All regressions include a constant. Standard errors in parentheses. ***, **, * ind Column 2: We exclude the following three growth collapses: Angola 1970-74, Iraq 198 Column 3: We exclude the following three influential data points: Iran 1970-74, Rom Column 4: We exclude the countries with the highest primary commodity export to G average primary commodity export to GDP ratio is 0.504 (sample average 0.158). Column 5: We exclude the following war starts: Angola 1975 and Somalia 1988. Column 6: We exclude the following war starts: Angola 1975, Mozambique 1976, Sierr This content downloaded from 147.251.110.131 on Tue, 22 Mar 2022 12:08:37 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms 586 P. COLLIER AND A. HOEFFLER Table 7 Estimation issues 1 2 3 4 Random effects time dummies Primary commodity exports/GDP (Primary commodity exportslGDP)2 Male secondary schooling (GDP growth) t-1 Peace duration Geographic dispersion Social fractionalization Ethnic dominance (45-90%) Ln population T70-74 T75-79 T80-84 T85-89 190-94 195-99 N No of wars Pseudo R2 Log likelihood 18.937 (5.865)*** -29.443 (1 1.782)*** -0.032 (0.010)*** -0.115 (0.043)*** -0.004 (0.001)*** -2.487 (1.005)*** -0.0002 (0.0001)** 0.670 (0.354)* 0.768 (0.166)*** 688 46 -128.21 35.850 (14.436)*** -65.967 (26.964)*** 0.007 (0.033) -0.045 (0.072) 0.011 (0.002)*** 115.363 (74.562) -0.007 (0.006) 0.010 (1.410) 145 44 -38.18 18.895 (5.988)*** -29.815 (12.098)*** -0.031 (0.010)*** -0.129 (0.047)*** -0.004 (0.001)*** -2.447 (1.018)** -0.0002 (0.0001 )** 0.682 (0.359)* 0.762 (0.170)*** 0.725 (0.602) 0.578 (0.608) 1.137 (0.602)* -0.013 (0.757) 0.802 (0.677) -0.492 (0.921) 688 46 0.26 -124.30 17.161 (6.535)*** -25.594 (14.355)* -0.029 (0.010)*** -0.110 (0.040)*** -0.004 (0.001)*** -2.394 (1.085)** -0.0002 (0.0001)** 0.644 (0.336)* 0.726 (0.151)*** 688 46 Notes: All regressions include a constant. Standard errors in parentheses. , , * indicate significance at the 1, 5, and 100 level, respectively the analysis. Although the fixed effects test is very severe, the non-monotonic effect of primary commodity exports remains significant. Were the effect of primary commodity exports dependent only upon cross-section data, it might suggest that the variable was proxying some other characteristic such as geography. This content downloaded from 147.251.110.131 on Tue, 22 Mar 2022 12:08:37 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms GREED AND GRIEVANCE 587 However, the fixed effects regression uses only changes in prim dependence, and so reduces the scope for alternative interpretati We analysed whether time effects matter by including time d model. Based on a log likelihood ratio test we cannot reject the the time dummies are zero.30 Finally, in the last column of Table 7 we use a recently develo method for rare events data (King and Zeng, 2001). The event w occurs in only about 7% of our observations. King and Zeng sho logit estimation tends to underestimate the probability of rare ev used their correction procedure. The differences between the sta and the rare events corrected results are negligible with all varia the same levels. The mean of the predicted probabilities obtaine events logit regression is 0.072. Thus, we find that the correcte similar to the logit results. We examined a number of different model specifications. We fo the following geographic and demographic characteristics were s coverage, population density and the proportion of young men ag also investigated the potential endogeneity of income to civil war we are measuring income prior to war the endogeneity only arise more than one war. Since the first war will have reduced incom wars the correlation between income and war could in principle re causation. To control for this we re-estimated excluding repeat variable remained highly significant. 5. Interpretation and conclusion Using a comprehensive data set of civil wars over the period 1960 regressions to predict the risk of the outbreak of war in each fiv find that a model that focuses on the opportunities for rebellio 29 We also investigated the effect of commodity prices. Since prices are exogenou contemporaneous with the episode being predicted, whereas our value-based prox experimented with both the level of export prices and with the change in pri period. However, in either form when added to the baseline regression the variable fact that lagged values of exports are significant even in the fixed effects regression respond to changes in values, but the response is evidently not so rapid as to giv price response. Potentially, the effect on conflict risk captures the 'voracity effect Tornell (1999) whereby an increase in the price of a natural resource export would increment in value to be devoted to conflict. Our results suggest that there may be su it is lagged. 30 The LRT statistic is 7.83, 6 restrictions (p = 0.251). 31 The proportion of the population living in urban areas was statistically significant when we excluded the geographic concentration of the population. However, when we included both proxies for the concentration of the population, the geographic concentration measure remained statistically significant while the proportion of the population living in urban areas was marginally insignificant (p = 0.11). This content downloaded from 147.251.110.131 on Tue, 22 Mar 2022 12:08:37 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms 588 P. COLLIER AND A. HOEFFLER whereas objective indicators of grievance add little explanatory robust to a range of tests for outliers, redefinitions, and alter One factor influencing the opportunity for rebellion is the av We have shown that primary commodity exports substantial risk. We have interpreted this as being due to the opportuniti provide for extortion, making rebellion feasible and perhaps alternative explanation would be that primary commodity de governance and so generates stronger grievances. However, we economic performance-the level, growth, and distribution political rights (which appear not to affect the risk of conflict wish to discount the possibility of an effect working through we cannot control), there is plenty of case study evidence supp interpretation. Another source of finance for which ther evidence is diasporas. We have found that diasporas substa risk of conflict renewal, and it is hard to find an alternative result. A second factor influencing opportunity is the cost of rebellion. Male secondary education enrollment, per capita income, and the growth rate all have statistically significant and substantial effects that reduce conflict risk. We have interpreted them as proxying earnings foregone in rebellion: low foregone earnings facilitate conflict. Even if this is correct, low earnings might matter because they are a source of grievance rather than because they make rebellion cheap. However, if rebellion were a protest against low income, we might expect inequality to have strong effects, which we do not find. A third aspect of opportunity is military advantage. We have found that a dispersed population increases the risk of conflict, and there is weaker evidence that mountainous terrain might also advantage rebels. It remains possible that these are correlated with unmeasured grievances. Most proxies for grievance were insignificant: inequality, political rights, ethnic polarization, and religious fractionalization. Only 'ethnic dominance'-one ethnic group being a majority-had adverse effects. Even this has to be considered in combination with the benign effects of social fractionalization: societies characterized by ethnic and religious diversity are safer than homogenous societies as long as they avoid dominance. We have suggested that diversity makes rebellion harder because it makes rebel cohesion more costly. It would be difficult to argue that diversity reduced grievance. Finally, the risk of conflict is proportional to a country's population. We have suggested that both opportunities and grievances increase with population. Thus, the result is compatible with both the opportunity and grievance accounts. However, grievances increase with population due to rising heterogeneity. Yet those aspects of heterogeneity that we are able to measure are not associated with an increased risk of conflict. Hence, a grievance account of the effect of population would need to explain why unobserved, but not observed, heterogeneity increases conflict risk. This content downloaded from 147.251.110.131 on Tue, 22 Mar 2022 12:08:37 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms GREED AND GRIEVANCE 589 One variable, the time since a previous conflict, has substa heals. Potentially, this can be interpreted either as opportun may reflect the gradual depreciation of rebellion-specific ca increasing cost of rebellion, or the gradual erosion of hatred found that a large diaspora slows the 'healing' process. The k diasporas to finance rebel groups offsets the depreciation of capital, and so would be predicted to delay 'healing'. The lends support to the opportunity interpretation. Opportunity as an explanation of conflict risk is consisten interpretation of rebellion as greed-motivated. However, it is grievance motivation as long as perceived grievances are suf to be common across societies and time. Opportunity can acco of either for-profit, or not-for-profit, rebel organizations. not therefore imply that rebels are necessarily criminals. But motivate rebels may be substantially disconnected from the of inequality, political rights, and ethnic or religious identity Acknowledgements We would like to thank Todd Sandler and two anonymous ref comments. Anke Hoeffler gratefully acknowledges funding from Norway (NFR). References Alesina, A., Baqir, R., and Easterly, W. (1999). 'Public goods and ethnic divisions', Quarterly Journal of Economics, 114, 1243-84. Alesina, A., Oetzler, S., Roubini, N., and Swagel, P. (1996). 'Political instability and economic growth', Journal of Economic Growth, 1, 189-211. Alesina, A. and Spolaore, E. (1997). 'On the number and the size of nations', Quarterly Journal of Economics, 112, 1027-56. Angoustures, A. and Pascal, V. (1996). 'Diasporas et financement des conflits', in F. Jean and J.-C. Rufin (eds), Economie des Guerres Civiles, Hachette, Paris. Barro, R.J. (1991). 'Economic growth in a cross section of countries', The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 106, 407-43. Barro, R.J. (ed.) (1997). Determinants of Economic Growth, MIT Press, Cambridge, MA. Barrett, D.B. (ed.) (1982). World Christian Encyclopedia, Oxford University Press, Oxford. Buchanan, J.M. and Faith, R.L. (1987). 'Secession and the limits of taxation: towards a theory of internal exit', American Economic Review, 77, 1023-31. Collier, P. (2000). 'Rebellion as a quasi-criminal activity', Journal of Conflict Resolution, 44, 839-53. Collier, P. (2001). 'Ethnic diversity: an economic analysis of its implications', Econ Policy, 32, 129-66. Collier, P. and Hoeffler, A. (1998). 'On the economic causes of civil war', Oxford Eco Papers, 50, 563-73. This content downloaded from 147.251.110.131 on Tue, 22 Mar 2022 12:08:37 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms 590 P. COLLIER AND A. HOEFFLER Collier, P. and Hoeffler, A. (2002). 'Greed and grievance in civil war', WPS 2002-01, Oxford University. http://www.economics.ox.ac.uk/CSAEadmin/workingpapers/pdfs/200 Collier, P., Hoeffler, A., and Soderbom, M. (2004). 'On the duration of Peace Research, 41, 253-73. Davidson R. and MacKinnon, J.G. (1981). 'Several tests for mode presence of alternative hypotheses', Econometrica, 49, 781-93. Dehn, J. (2000). 'Commodity price uncertainty, investment and sh economic growth', D.Phil. thesis, University of Oxford. Deininger, K. and Squire, L. (1996). 'A new data set measuring inco Bank Economic Review, 10, 565-91. Deininger, K. and Squire, L. (1998). 'New ways of looking at old growth', Journal of Development Economics, 57, 249-87. Easterly, W. and Levine, R. (1997). 'Africa's growth tragedy: policie Quarterly Journal of Economics, 113, 203-49. Esteban, J.-M. and Ray, D. (1994). 'On the measurement of polarizat 819-51. Esteban, J.-M. and Ray, D. (1999). 'Conflict and distribution', Journal of Economic The 87, 379-415. Figes, 0. (1996). A People's Tragedy: The Russian Revolution 1891-1924, Pimlico, Lon Fearon, J. (2004) 'Why do some civil wars last so much longer than others?' Journal of Research, 41, 275-301. Gerrard, A.J.W. (2000). 'What is a mountain?', mimeo, DECRG, World Bank, Washington, DC. Grossman, H.I. (1991). 'A general equilibrium model of insurrections', American Economic Review, 81, 912-21. Grossman, H.I. (1999). 'Kleptocracy and revolutions', Oxford Economic Papers, 51, 267-83. Hegre, H., Ellingsen, T., Gates, S., and Gleditsch, N.-P. (2001). 'Toward a democratic civil peace? Democracy, political change, and civil war, 1816-1992', American Political Science Review, 95, 33-48. Herbst, J. (2000). States and Power in Africa, Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ. Hirshleifer, J. (1995). 'Theorizing about conflict', in K. Hartley and T. Sandler (eds), Handbook of Defense Economics, Vol. 1, Elsevier Science, Amsterdam, 165-89. Hirshleifer, J. (2001). The Dark Side of the Force: Economic Foundations of Conflict Theory, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge. Jaggers, K. and Gurr, T.R. (1995). 'Tracking democracy's third wave with the Polity III data', Journal of Peace Research, 32, 469-82. King, G. and Zeng, L. (2001). 'Logistic regression in rare events data', Political Analysis, 9, 137-63. Klare, M.T. (2001). Natural Resource Wars: The New Landscape of Global Confli Metropolitan Books, New York. Lane A. and Tornell, P.R. (1999). 'The voracity effect', American Economic Review, 22-46. This content downloaded from 147.251.110.131 on Tue, 22 Mar 2022 12:08:37 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms GREED AND GRIEVANCE 591 Londregan, J.B. and Poole, K.T. (1996) 'Does high income promot Politics, 49, 1-30. Long, J.S. (1997). Regression Models for Categorical and Limited Sage Publications, London. Mauro, P. (1995). 'Corruption and growth', The Quarterly Journ 681-712. Pregibon, D. (1981). 'Logistic regression diagnostics', The Annals of Statistics, 9, Reynal-Querol, M. (2000). 'Religious conflict and growth: theory and evidence'. Ph.D London School of Economics and Political Science. Reynal-Querol, M. (2002). 'Ethnicity, political systems and civil war', Journal of Confl Resolution, 46, 29-54. Sachs, J. and Warner, A.M. (2000). 'Natural resource abundance and economic growt in G.M. Meier and J.E. Rauch (eds), Leading Issues in Economic Development, 7th ed., Oxfo University Press, Oxford. Sambanis, N. (2002). 'What is a civil war? Conceptual and empirical complexities of operational definition', mimeo, Yale University. Sen, A. (1973). On Economic Inequality, Clarendon Press, Oxford. Singer, D.J. and Small, M. (1994). 'Correlates of war project: international and civil war da 1816-1992', data file, Inter-University Consortium for Political and Social Research, An Arbor, MI. Small, M. and Singer, J.D. (1982). Resort to Arms: International and Civil War, 1816-1980, Sage, Beverly Hills, CA. The Stockholm International Peace Research Institute (2002). Yearbook of World Armaments and Disarmaments, Oxford University Press, Oxford. Summers, R. and Heston, A. (1991). 'The Penn World Table (Mark 5): an expanded set of international comparisons, 1950-1988', The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 99, 327-68. USSR (1964). Atlas Narodov Mira, Department of Geodesy and Cartography of the Geological Committee of the USSR. Moscow. World Bank (2000). World Development Indicators, Washington DC, data file. Appendix 1 1. A simple migration model Our estimation of migration is based on the following model diasit =1.163 diasit - 0.0002 lnGDPi,t_l + 0.003 wari,t_ + 0.003. T80 + 0.005 T90+ 0.013 (0.045)*** (0.001)** (0.03) (0.002) (0.002) (0.008) Where dias denotes diaspora which is measured as the ratio of emigra total population of the country of origin. The variable war is a wa t - 1 it takes a value of one if the country experienced a civil war The method of estimation is OLS. The data is measured at the beg This content downloaded from 147.251.110.131 on Tue, 22 Mar 2022 12:08:37 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms 592 P. COLLIER AND A. HOEFFLER i.e. 1960, 1970, 1980, and 1990. The regression includes time dumm significant. Based on this simple migration model we estimated the size of the diaspora at time t. diasit = xit '* For countries which experienced a previous civil war we used these estimated values to correct for a possible endogeneity problem. We replaced a total of 64 observations. For countries which did not experience a civil war we use the actual diaspora data. In order to obtain values for 1965 we took the averages of this corrected diaspora data measured in 1960 and 1970, and analogously for the values for 1975 and 1985. For 1995 we use the observations measured in 1990. Appendix 2 1. Calculating the marginal probabilities In our regressions we estimate the probability of a war breaking out during a five-year period, and the model can be written in the following general form Yit = a + bXit + cMi, t_ + dZi + uit (A2.1) where t and i are time and country indicators. The dependent variable is a dumm indicating whether a war broke out during the five-year period, so that Yit is the war. The explanatory variables are either measured at the beginning of the p example, income per capita, primary commodity exports/GDP, population), or previous five-year period (for instance, per capita income growth, or are time in changing slowly over time (for example, social fractionalization). The expected probability Pit of a war breaking out can be calculated by using th coefficients obtained from equation (Al.1): a + bXit + cMi t- + dZi = it (A2.2) ewit pit = 100 (A2.3) (l+ eit) Appendix 3 1. Data sources Democracy The degree of openness of democratic institutions is measured on a sc zero (low) to ten (high). Source: http://www.cidcm.umd.edu/polity/index.html. The d described in Jaggers and Gurr (1995). This content downloaded from 147.251.110.131 on Tue, 22 Mar 2022 12:08:37 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms Table A2 Marginal probabilities Variable Coefficient Mean (1) (2) (3) ( of X At the Worst Best primary 10% mean commodity/ men in gr GDP = 0. Primary commodity 18.937 exports/GDP (Primary commodity -29.443 exports/GDP)2 Male secondary schooling -0.032 (GDP growth),_ -0.115 Peace duration -0.004 Geographic dispersion -2.487 Social fractionalization -0.0002 Ethnic dominance 0.670 (45-90%) Ln population 0.768 Constant -13.073 p 0.158 2.992 6.060 -0.735 -3.015 0 6.060 0 -3.015 44.489 -1.406 -0.032 -4.645 -1.406 1.618 -0.186 1.508 -1.660 -0.186 347.5 -1.286 -0.004 -2.19 -1.286 0.602 -1.497 0.000 -2.415 -1.497 1790 -0.376 -0.004 -1.465 -0.376 0.439 0.294 0.670 0 0.294 30,500,000 13.230 16.049 9.136 -13.073 -13.073 -13.073 -2.043 8.160 -16.312 0.115 1.000 0.000 13.230 13.073 - - - - - -1 -1.255 -2 0.222 0 This content downloaded from 147.251.110.131 on Tue, 22 Mar 2022 12:08:37 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms 594 P. COLLIER AND A. HOEFFLER Diaspora We used the data on the foreign born population from the Census and divided these numbers by the total population in http://www.census.gov/population/ Ethnic dominance Using the ethno-linguistic data from the origin 1964) we calculated an indicator of ethnic dominance. This variable if one single ethno-linguistic group makes up 45 to 90% of the tot otherwise. We would like to thank Tomila Lankina for the translat source. Forest coverage We used the FAO measure of the proportion of a is covered in woods and forest. Source: http://www.fao.org/forestr GDP per capita We measure income as real PPP adjusted GDP p data set is the Penn World Tables 5.6 (Summers and Heston, 1991 available from 1960-92 we used the growth rates of real PPP adj from the World Bank's World Development Indicators 1998 in or for the 1990s. These GDP per cpaita data were used to calculate th rate over the previous five years. Geographic dispersion of the population We constructed a population on a country by country basis. Based on population d generated a Gini coefficient of population dispersion for each count that the population is evenly distributed across the country and a va total population is concentrated in one area. Data is available for prior to 1990 we used the 1990 data. We would like to thank Uwe Bank's Geographic Information System Unit for generating this da data sources: Center for International Earth Science Informa Columbia University; International Food Policy Research Inst Resources Institute (WRI). 2000. Gridded Population of the W Palisades, NY: IESIN, Columbia University. Available at http://sedac Inequality Inequality was either measured as income inquality Squire, 1996) or as inequality in land ownership (source: Deini lished). Both inequality measures are provided as a Gini coefficien Male secondary school enrolment rates We measure male seco rates as gross enrolment ratios, i.e. the ratio of total enrollment, r population of the age group that officially corresponds to the l Secondary education completes the provision of basic education t level, and aims at laying the foundations for lifelong learning by offering more subject- or skill-oriented instruction using m Source: World Bank Development Indicators, 1998. Mountainous terrain The proportion of a country's terrain w measured by John Gerrard, a physical geographer specialized in measure is based not just on altitude but takes into account plate The data are presented in Gerrard (2000). This content downloaded from 147.251.110.131 on Tue, 22 Mar 2022 12:08:37 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms GREED AND GRIEVANCE 595 Peace duration This variable measures the length of the peace peri the end of the previous civil war. For countries which never expe measure the peace period since the end of World War II. Population Population measures the total population, the data sour World Development Indicators 1998. Primary commodity exports/GDP The ratio of primary comm proxies the abundance of natural resources. The data on primary co GDP were obtained from the World Bank. Export and GDP data ar US dollars. Social, ethnolinguistic, and religious fractionalization We proxy social fractionalization in a combined measure of ethnic and religious fractionalization. Ethnic fractionalization is measured by the ethno-linguistic fractionalization index. It measures the probability that two randomly drawn individuals from a given country do not speak the same language. Data are only available for 1960. In the economics literature this measure was first used by Mauro (1995). Using data from Barrett (1982) on religious affiliations we constructed an analogous religious fractionalization index. Following Barro (1997) we aggregated the various religious affiliations into nine categories: Catholic, Protestant, Muslim, Jew, Hindu, Buddhist, Eastern Religions (other than Buddhist), Indigenous Religions, and no religious affiliation. The fractionalization indices range from zero to 100. A value of zero indicates that the society is completely homogenous whereas a value of 100 would characterize a completely heterogeneous society. We calculated our social fractionalization index as the product of the ethno-linguistic fractionalization and the religious fractionalization index plus the ethno-linguistic or the religious fractionalization index, whichever is the greater. By adding either index we avoid classifying a country as homogenous (a value of zero) if the country is ethnically homogenous but religiously divers, or vice versa. War data A civil war is defined as an internal conflict in which at least 1,000 battle related deaths (civilian and military) occurred per year. We use mainly the data collected by Small and Singer (1992) and according to their definitions (Singer and Small, 1984) we updated their data set for 1992-99. This content downloaded from 147.251.110.131 on Tue, 22 Mar 2022 12:08:37 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms