Reconceptualizing Major Policy Change in the Advocacy Coalition Framework: A Discourse Network Analysis of German Pension Politics Philip Leifeld How does major policy change come about? This article identifies and rectifies weaknesses in the conceptualization of innovative policy change in the Advocacy Coalition Framework. In a case study of policy belief change preceding an innovative reform in the German subsystem of old-age security, important new aspects of major policy change are carved out. In particular, the analysis traces a transition from one single hegemonic advocacy coalition to another stable coalition, with a transition phase between the two equilibria. The transition phase is characterized (i) by a bipolarization of policy beliefs in the subsystem and (ii) by state actors with shifting coalition memberships due to policy learning across coalitions or due to executive turnover. Apparently, there are subsystems with specific characteristics (presumably redistributive rather than regulative subsystems) in which one hegemonic coalition is the default, or the “normal state.” In these subsystems, polarization and shifting coalition memberships seem to interact to produce coalition turnover and major policy change. The case study is based on discourse network analysis, a combination of qualitative content analysis and social network analysis, which provides an intertemporal measurement of advocacy coalition realignment at the level of policy beliefs in a subsystem. KEY WORDS: Advocacy Coalition Framework, discourse network analysis, policy change, polarization, pension politics, old-age security, demographic change, Germany, policy networks, policy debates, political discourse Introduction How does major policy change come about? Existing evidence in line with the Advocacy Coalition Framework (ACF) suggests that policy subsystems are structured around competing advocacy coalitions (Sabatier, 1998). They are stable for long time periods, often much more than a decade (Jenkins-Smith, St. Clair, & Woods, 1991; Zafonte & Sabatier, 2004). This equilibrium guarantees policy stability and is only interrupted when external perturbations cause coalition members to refine their internal belief systems significantly (Sabatier & Weible, 2007, p. 193). When this happens, major policy change becomes likely. Yet this perspective leaves important questions unanswered: What exactly happens when coalition members adjust their belief systems—do they leave their bs_bs_banner The Policy Studies Journal, Vol. 41, No. 1, 2013 169 0190-292X © 2013 Policy Studies Organization Published by Wiley Periodicals, Inc., 350 Main Street, Malden, MA 02148, USA, and 9600 Garsington Road, Oxford, OX4 2DQ. coalition and join the political opponent? How does the structure of a subsystem change when belief change occurs? Is there a transition phase, and what does it look like? Does the competition between two or more stable coalitions constitute the “normal state” of policymaking irrespective of institutional context across political systems? Or could this be a peculiarity of pluralist or other institutional contexts, while there are in fact subsystems where only one hegemonic coalition is the rule? In this article, an empirical case study is presented that sheds light on these open questions. Using a methodological advancement based on a combination of social network analysis and qualitative data, the belief similarity networks of actors in the German policy subsystem of old-age security are mapped over time. In particular, I posit that hegemony of a single coalition may be the rule rather than the exception in some types of policy subsystems. In these cases, a polarization into competing coalitions and the shift back to a single coalition with new members and new beliefs necessarily occurs before major policy change can take place. This conflictual transition phase is guided by two interrelated processes: belief polarization and learning across coalitions. The paper strives to achieve four goals: opening the black box and describing the processes predating major policy change, demonstrating how consensus and polarization may alternate to produce policy stability or change, discussing the relevance of the “discursive layer” of subsystem politics for policymaking, and the introduction of methodological tools that will enable researchers to tackle a host of new research questions centered around these themes. The article is structured as follows: The next section briefly reviews the literature on the ACF and connects the overarching theme of policy change to related approaches in the public policy literature. The following sections also point out that our understanding of policy learning and policy change is still limited and suggest that new insights can be gained by analyzing the temporal pattern of subsystem change at the discursive level. To meet this challenge, a methodology called “discourse network analysis” is described in the subsequent section. It draws on social network analysis and is capable of measuring belief change in subsystems over time. An original data set on German pension politics is presented, which was compiled using the software Discourse Network Analyzer, and background information on the case study is provided. The next section presents the results of the empirical analysis, and the subsequent section lays out some observable mechanisms and reconnects these findings to the ACF. Finally, the conclusion proposes pathways for future research and recapitulates on the discourse network approach as a means to tackle these open questions. Advocacy Coalitions and Major Policy Change As we know from the ACF, political actors in a policy subsystem can be classified into coalitions of competing policy beliefs (Sabatier, 1998). They have complex belief systems at several layers of intensity and alterability (cf. Henry, Lubell, & McCoy, 2011) and coordinate within but not across coalitions (Ingold, 2011; Weible, 2005). Advocacy coalitions are usually stable over time (for a review, see Zafonte & Sabatier, 170 Policy Studies Journal, 41:1 2004), and they are polarized, particularly in conflictual subsystems (Jenkins-Smith et al., 1991). Administrative agencies have more moderate positions than interest groups and thus often act as policy brokers or intermediaries between coalitions (Sabatier, 1998). Scientific evidence is frequently employed in order to back one’s own policy positions (Sabatier, 1987). New information and exogenous shocks have been identified as the main drivers of policy learning within and across coalitions, and policy learning has been found to cause policy change (Sabatier, 1998). In this perspective, the actual processes of policy learning and policy change largely remain a black box (cf. Mintrom & Vergari, 1996; Nohrstedt, 2010). Especially the very transition from one stable advocacy coalition structure to a new stable advocacy coalition structure has not been sufficiently explored within the ACF. Does one coalition simply discard previously held beliefs instantly upon receipt of new information and join the political opponent? Is the existence of two or more stable coalitions really the “normal state” of policymaking, or is the emergence of polarized coalitions merely a temporally confined piece in the puzzle of policy change? Other scholars have pointed out that subsystems may be structured around a single hegemonic coalition instead of two or more competing coalitions. Baumgartner and Jones (1991), for example, argue that the “normal state” of politics is rather nonconflictual because one hegemonic coalition can clearly determine the course of political action. This centralized policy network structure is stable until previous “policy losers” are able to change the policy image and shift the venue of policymaking, leading to feedback loops and eventually culminating in a punctuation of the policy equilibrium. According to this theory, policy change is rare and, if it occurs, strong (cf. Jones & Baumgartner, 2005). Similarly, Hall (1993) argues that dominant policy paradigms structure subsystems for long periods of time. When actors realize that various core aspects and more peripheral aspects of a policy are no longer credible, the policy paradigm is replaced by a new paradigm. This contrast between the ACF and related theoretical frameworks discloses important questions: may there be two alternative types of equilibria in policy subsystems—one of them characterized by multiple competing coalitions and the other one characterized by transitions from one hegemonic coalition through a rewiring phase to another hegemonic coalition? Should this hold true, we must ask: What institutional, temporal, or cultural factors can explain whether competition between coalitions is a cross-sectional or a temporal pattern? A vague hint is provided by Sabatier and Weible (2007, pp. 199ff.), who allow for the possibility that coalitions may operate in different ways if one compares corporatist consensus democracies with majoritarian-pluralist polities. They concede that “the higher the degree of consensus required, the more incentive coalitions have to be inclusive (rather than exclusive), to seek compromise and share information with opponents, and generally to minimize devil shift” (Sabatier & Weible, 2007, p. 200). However, the implications for subsystem structure are in principle uncertain. Sabatier & Weible (2007, p. 200) suggest that “advocacy coalitions will tend to have fewer actors, and the norms of compromise will create incentives for moderates to broker deals across coalitions.” The analysis below sheds light on this question and Leifeld: Reconceptualizing Major Policy Change in the ACF 171 adds a temporal perspective on subsystem change in a corporatist setting before major policy change takes place. The Discursive Layer of Subsystem Politics Advocacy coalitions are composed of two distinct “layers” that can be measured empirically: beliefs and coordination. The original version of the ACF focuses largely on the belief systems of political actors and how they structure policy subsystems (Sabatier, 1987). Accordingly, early analyses of advocacy coalitions examined beliefs of actors, rather than coordination among them, over long time periods by means of content analysis (e.g., Jenkins-Smith et al., 1991). Following the proposition of Sabatier (1987, p. 664), “it seems preferable to allow the actors to indicate their belief systems (via questionnaires and content analysis of documents) and then empirically examine the extent to which these change over time.” Only after subsequent modifications of the ACF was coordination between actors in coalitions established as the second layer of structures that can be measured empirically in policy subsystems: actors “both (a) share a set of normative and causal beliefs and (b) engage in a non-trivial degree of co-ordinated activity over time” (Sabatier, 1998, p. 103). More recently, coordination has become a central interest of advocacy coalition scholars, and the policy network approach (Pappi & Henning, 1998; Schneider, 1992) and social network analysis are now frequently applied in order to delineate coalitions in terms of information exchange and other relations between actors (Ingold, 2011; Lubell, Scholz, Berardo, & Robins, 2012). Belief systems, however, are still the primary theoretical factor that structures coalition membership and subsystems, and emphasis on them distinguishes the ACF from the vast literature on policy networks that has evolved since the early 1970s. Coordination is conditioned and structured by belief systems of actors (Sabatier, 1998), and more recent analyses could confirm that both are indeed closely associated (Ingold, 2011, and Weible, 2010; but see Leifeld & Schneider, 2012). Moreover, although coordination may be an interesting feature of coalitions, questionnaires with retrospective questions about coalition structure would fail to generate any meaningful results due to recall errors, hindsight bias, and similar problems (Finney, 1981; Geweke & Martin, 2002; Janson, 1990; van der Vaart, van der Zouwen, & Dijkstra, 1995), especially when actors are asked to reconstruct historical relations that may have existed more than a decade ago. Unless repeated questionnaires are employed, content analysis still seems to be the only viable way of measuring advocacy coalitions over periods of a decade or more. For these reasons, and in line with Jenkins-Smith et al. (1991), I propose an operationalization of the belief-related components of the ACF based on content analysis of newspaper articles.1 More specifically, I measure what Sabatier (1998, pp. 116ff.) calls “policy core policy preferences” in his qualification of the ACF—the second most specific and most alterable normative type of policy beliefs (out of four types: deep core beliefs, policy core beliefs, policy core policy preferences, and secondary aspects). They “are broad in scope (affecting virtually all members of the 172 Policy Studies Journal, 41:1 subsystem), involve very salient beliefs, and have been the source of long-term conflict” (Sabatier, 1998, p. 117). These policy preferences are geared toward moving future policymaking in a subsystem in a general normative direction. Most importantly, however, they “constitute the principal ‘glue’ holding a coalition together” (Sabatier, 1998, p. 117) and can thus directly serve to operationalize the most crucial aspect of advocacy coalitions: normative belief similarity regarding policy instruments. The articulation of policy core policy preferences is a complex, relational phenomenon. Actors reveal their preferences in the media or other arenas, and thus other actors feel encouraged to support them or reveal their opposition. As such, this articulation of normative beliefs can be subsumed under the more general notion of “discourse” (cf. Schmidt, 2010) and can thus be understood as a “discursive layer” of subsystem politics. In order to measure coalitions based on these data, some transformations are required. The following section briefly outlines the methodology of discourse network analysis, an approach that combines qualitative content analysis with social network analysis in order to visualize the development of coalitions over time. Social network analysis seems like a natural choice for modeling policy debates because political discourse is an inherently relational phenomenon. Discourse network analysis has been employed to study a political conflict about software patents in the European Union (Leifeld & Haunss, 2012) and the formation of consensus around climate policymaking in the U.S. Congress (Fisher, Leifeld, & Iwaki, 2013; Fisher, Waggle, & Leifeld, 2012). The Methodology of Discourse Network Analysis With the advent of digital technology, full-text archives of newspapers, parliamentary testimony, or other venues are readily available as a source of information. They fill a gap where elite interviews fail, as is the case in analyses of policy debates. Unfortunately, raw text data are unstructured and thus require an elaborate methodology to draw useful conclusions from them. For precisely this purpose, I have created a free-to-use Java-based software called Discourse Network Analyzer in order to facilitate the qualitative coding process and the conversion of actors’ statements into network data (Leifeld, 2013; see http://www.philipleifeld.de). In this software, text data can be imported, statements of actors can be manually encoded, and the resulting actor or concept map can be exported as one out of several network types. Affiliation Networks The following descriptive model of political discourse is adopted: There are political actors who make statements in the media (or whatever text source is used). A statement is a text portion where an actor utters his or her policy preferences in a positive or in a negative way. For example, an actor can either support or reject a policy instrument. For reasons of generality, policy instruments that are proposed by Leifeld: Reconceptualizing Major Policy Change in the ACF 173 actors are called “concepts” in the following framework. A statement is thus a text portion containing (i) an actor, (ii) a concept, and (iii) the binary information about support or opposition. More formally, let A = {a1, a2, . . . am} be the set of actors in the data set, and let C = {c1, c2, . . . cn} denote the set of concepts in the data set. The coding procedure furthermore involves a dummy variable for agreement or disagreement of an actor with a concept. This set of relations can be defined as R = {r1, r2, . . . rl} with l = 2 (for the two relations: agreement and disagreement).2 As a particular emphasis is placed on the longitudinal analysis of discourse, the date of a statement is another critical aspect. Time is actually continuous, but for the sake of simplicity, it will be modeled as being discrete in this context. Thus, T = {t1, t2, . . . tk} denotes the set of discrete time steps, for example the set of years in which statements are made. The level of analysis is the statement. Whenever a statement occurs, a relation between an actor and a concept is inferred from this statement. This relation is modeled as an edge e a c Er t r t, ,,aff aff ( ) ∈ in a bipartite graph Gr t, aff , where actors and concepts are modeled as vertices: G A C Er t r t, ,, ,aff aff = ( ) (1) The aff superscript indicates that this is an affiliation network. There is one such bipartite graph for each agreement relation. It is possible to collapse the positive and the negative affiliation graphs into a single multiplex network. One such graph can be constructed for each time slice t. As the graph is bipartite, it exhibits the property that only edges between actors and concepts are allowed, not within the set of actors or within the set of concepts: a a E c c Er t r t, ,, ,′{ } ∉ ∧ ′{ } ∉aff aff (2) In this condition, a denotes an actor and a′ another actor; similarly, c denotes a concept and c′ denotes an arbitrary second concept. Congruence Networks Unfortunately, it is quite difficult to establish whether two actors actually exhibit high or low degrees of belief overlap, given the highly complex graphical representation of the affiliation network. One might not only be interested in how actors relate to concepts but also in how far coalitions emerge from this structure. The basic idea is that the more concepts two actors agree (or both disagree) on, the more similar they are in terms of preferences or concepts in the discourse. Therefore, it is straightforward to move from a bipartite affiliation graph to an adjacency graph where actors are connected to other actors and where the edge weight between these actors represents the number of common concepts. The overall topology of the resulting congruence network can be used as a map of the discourse where clusters of actors represent advocacy coalitions. This is true because these 174 Policy Studies Journal, 41:1 preferences constitute the “stickiest glue” between coalitions (Sabatier & Weible, 2007). The congruence network provides an intuitive way of conceptualizing and measuring coalitions at the ideational level (of course ignoring material aspects like information exchange relationships as analyzed by Leifeld & Schneider, 2012). Actor congruence networks are created as follows. Let Gt a be an adjacency graph where the vertex set A represents actors: G A Et t aa = ( ), (3) with edges e E Gt t∈ ( )a . Edges have a weight attached to them, such that a denotes the source vertex of an edge, a′ denotes the target vertex, and wt denotes the weight of the edge between source and target. Actors do not have a subscript t because the model assumes they are present in all time periods. Only the presence or absence of statements (or edges) may vary over time. ∀ = ′{ }e e a a wt t t: , , (4) Wt is the set of weights, and wt (a, a′) ∈ Wt denotes the edge weight between a and a′. Edge weights are computed as follows: In the affiliation graph of equation (1), a neighbor is an adjacent vertex of another vertex. Neighbors of concepts must be in the set of actors and vice versa, as required by equation (2). The set of neighbors of vertex a in the affiliation network is denoted as N aGr t, aff ( ). It contains all concepts actor a refers to in the affiliation matrix. Hence, it is defined as the set of concepts that are incident with an edge containing a as a source or target vertex. Er,t (a) denotes the set of edges incident with a. N a C E aG r t r t, : ,aff aff ( ) = ∈ ( ) (5) An edge weight is computed by considering neighbors in the affiliation network: w a a N a N at G G r l r t r t , , , ′( ) = ( )∩ ′( ) = ∑ aff aff 1 (6) In equation (6), the edge weight between a and a′ is determined by computing the intersection of their sets of neighbors and counting the elements of this intersection. This is done for both relations (agreement and disagreement), and both counts are summed up. In other words, the edge weight between two actors is the number of concepts they both refer to in the same (i.e., positive or negative) way. The interpretation is straightforward: The edge weight can be interpreted as a measure of similarity in the discourse. The more similar the policy preferences of two actors, the higher their edge weight. Accordingly, cohesive subgroups in the graph can be interpreted as coalitions, whereas sparse connections between these clusters reflect policy belief divergence. Leifeld: Reconceptualizing Major Policy Change in the ACF 175 Threshold Values In a visual inspection of the resulting network diagrams, threshold values can be imposed: In order to avoid wrong inference due to coding errors or random behavior/noise of actors concerning their statements, the lowest edge weights can be ignored during the analysis by imposing a threshold value on the edge weight. The cutoff value can be increased in a stepwise fashion until the structure of the discourse network becomes visible. There is essentially a trade-off between allowing too much noise (and therefore drowning in too much artificial complexity) and filtering out too much relevant information by setting the threshold value too high. The optimal threshold value is usually determined in an explorative way because the degree of noise critically depends on the size of the time slice, the number of concepts, and other factors that vary between empirical applications. Such a threshold value, however, is only required for the visual inspection of the network but not for subgroup analyses based on structural similarity, which are also presented below. The Normalization of Edge Weights Quite obviously, actors who make more statements than other actors are likely to be central in the resulting congruence network. This affects particularly governmental actors who are officially in charge of dealing with a problem, for example the relevant governmental agency. One way to correct for this potential bias is to employ a normalization (for more details and a discussion, see Leifeld, 2011). The normalization of an edge weight, F(wt), is the edge weight divided by the average number of concepts both actors refer to in the affiliation network, either in a positive or in a negative way (hence the union of the two sets of neighbors for the distinct relations): Φ w a a w a a N a N a N t t G G Gr t r t r t , , , , , ′( )( ) = ′( ) ( )∪ ( ) + = = = 1 2 1 2 1 aff aff afff aff′( )∪ ′( )( )= a N aGr t2, (7) Additional Specifications and Matrix Notation Analogous methods can be employed to create concept congruence networks, conflict networks, and dynamic discourse networks. As these network types are not required for the specific analysis presented in this article, the reader is referred to the detailed discussion in Leifeld (2011). There are two mathematical foundations of social network analysis: graph theory and matrix algebra. The basic model described here is presented using graph theory, but the same logic can be expressed in matrix notation. For the sake of clarity, the basic model is described in matrix notation in Appendix S1. 176 Policy Studies Journal, 41:1 The Data Set A case study about German pension politics is presented below. Using the software Discourse Network Analyzer, 7,249 statements of political actors between January 1993 and May 2001 were encoded. This time period roughly covers the decade before the Riester reform, an instance of major policy change in this subsystem. The law was passed in May 2001. The Coding Procedure The data set was created in three steps. First, the source was selected. Three newspapers were available as digital full-text archives. Two of them are known to be politically moderate. Both newspapers correspond to the “quality press” criterion (Barranco & Wisler, 1999; Koopmans, 1996; Kriesi, 1995): They have a wide circulation and are politically moderate and reputable. In order to avoid potential problems with double coverage of events, only one of these newspapers was eventually selected: Frankfurter Allgemeine Zeitung. Media bias may be a minor issue for a cross-sectional analysis. Unless the newspaper changes its political orientation over time, however, the potential bias should be constant and longitudinal changes in the discursive structure should still be observable. Second, the population of articles had to be defined. Only the “politics” and “business” sections of the newspaper were considered; feuilleton pages and other sections were excluded because their journalistic style was more normative and arguments were often implied rather than made explicit. The search term “*rente*” (the German word for “pension” surrounded by wildcards) was used to identify 1,879 potentially relevant articles. Third, all articles were read, and their contents were manually encoded. Whenever a political actor revealed his policy preferences about a policy instrument related to the pension system, this was coded as a statement (according to the definition given above).3 Individuals and organizations were considered simultaneously. In the final analysis, only statements made by organizational actors were retained, because important persons without an organizational affiliation were not present. If an actor or a concept was not already in the data set, it was subsequently added to the list. Although the coding was mainly inductive (with a certain number of deductively preidentified solution concepts from the theoretical literature), a multipass coding strategy was employed; that is, the coder had to navigate back and forth between the statements in order to ensure a consistent way of coding. A single researcher encoded the articles, and a second individual checked the codes of the other researcher but did not code any data independently. This coding procedure (i) increased reliability compared with a single-coder strategy and (ii) was less labor- and hence cost-intensive than independent coding of the same articles by two separate individuals. Although intercoder reliability could not be explicitly checked with this coding procedure, other measures were taken to ensure a highquality data set; as mentioned above, all codes were reviewed by a second researcher, and in cases of disagreement, codes were discussed and a consensual Leifeld: Reconceptualizing Major Policy Change in the ACF 177 solution was found. Moreover, an algorithm was implemented in the software that can identify self-contradictions of actors over time (i.e., an actor refers to a concept in a positive way somewhere and in a negative way somewhere else). This information was used to detect and fix inconsistencies. In most cases, however, statements were made in an unambiguous way. Finally, a full-text search based on regular expressions was employed to find statements that had been previously overlooked. All of these measures indicated that the coding was very consistent. The final data set contains 7,249 statements of 246 organizations and/or 461 persons about 68 concepts from 1,879 articles between 1993 and 2001.4 Classification of Actors Actor congruence networks were exported from this data set as described in the previous section. Visualization of the networks was done using the software visone (Brandes & Wagner, 2004). Actors in the data set were classified into seven categories: social actors like trade unions, senior citizens’ interest groups, employees’ party organizations or other social interest groups (red in the following figures); liberal actors like industry or employers’ associations, managers’ interest groups, and think tanks with a market-liberal mission statement (yellow); decision makers like governmental actors, political parties, and state agencies (gray); young people’s interest groups and party organizations (magenta); financial actors like banks, insurance companies and their interest groups, and think tanks (blue); scientific organizations like universities; and “other” organizations that could not be classified into any of the previous categories (black). As Sabatier (1987) argues, scientific evidence is usually employed by advocacy coalitions to back up and defend their claims. Scientific organizations would thus be scattered across all coalitions. However, one important aim of the analysis is to understand which type of actor belongs to which coalition. Mapping scientific organizations along with the other actors in a network diagram would rather make the subsystem structure more complex and would render this task more difficult. For this reason, they are omitted in the network visualizations that are part of the following analysis. However, they are included as green nodes in the cluster analyses presented below. Case Study Background Demographic change poses serious challenges to established pension systems around the globe. In coordinated market economies and beyond, an increasing number of senior citizens must be sustained by a shrinking population of young people who pay contributions into the pension system. Characteristics of the Policy Subsystem In Germany, the old-age dependency ratio, which measures the number of citizens aged 65 and over divided by those aged 15–64, is likely to rise until it reaches 178 Policy Studies Journal, 41:1 its peak around the year 2035 (cf. Berkel, Börsch-Supan, Ludwig, & Winter, 2004). Taking no action would automatically increase the contribution rate, part of the non-wage labor costs in Germany, which are jointly financed by employers and employees. Some argue that this strong additional burden may be so extreme that consumption is jeopardized, leading to an eventual “collapse” of the social security system (Birg, 2002; Graf von der Schulenburg & Wähling, 1997). Against this background, there is pressure for reform to make pension systems more sustainable. There are numerous alternatives and propositions of political actors and economists as to how this can be achieved, but there is no consensus between these actors as to what may be the most appropriate solution. The subsystem of pension politics can thus be characterized as an institutionalized subsystem, with demographic change as a relatively stable parameter that provides reform incentives to actors. There is no consensus, however, as to what kind of reform would be appropriate. The 2001 Riester Reform as a Case of Major Policy Change In the German case, a pathbreaking reform was passed in May 2001: the Riester reform (named after then-minister Riester). It replaced the public pay-as-you-go (PAYG) pension system by a multipillar system with private capital-funded elements (for a rough description, see Börsch-Supan & Wilke, 2003). There is scholarly consensus that—despite minor reforms throughout the last three decades—this was the only case of major policy change (Lamping & Rüb, 2004; Schmähl, 2000; Trampusch, 2008; Wehlau, 2009) because it introduced new elements at all levels of the inherent belief system of the policy, from deep core to secondary aspects (“third-order change” according to Hall, 1993). The reform was a “direction-setting law,” which introduced only minor changes at first glance but “puts pension policy on an irreversible track that will constrain all future governments and thus determine all future pensions laws” (Lamping & Rüb, 2004). Competing Reform Options and Policy Preferences Although the reform might seem at first glance like a logical next step that could effectively counter the threat of population aging, the situation was and still is in fact considerably less clear. The easiest but least appropriate explanation stems from a functionalist view: Privatization and capital cover elements had to be introduced because there was the imminent threat of demographic change. This explanation is flawed because many alternative measures were discussed, whether they would be able to solve the problem or not. There are four arguments as to why privatization was not necessary: (i) capital-cover elements might have been introduced within the public pension system instead of privatizing the pension system, (ii) the shift to a (partial) capital-cover system implies severe transaction costs and intergenerational inequalities (Breyer, 2000), (iii) it is not clear to what extent population aging as a dynamic phenomenon would have self-regulated the problem after several decades, and (iv) alternative pathways were equally feasible. Leifeld: Reconceptualizing Major Policy Change in the ACF 179 In the light of this complexity, politicians and scientists argued in multiple directions. For the time period between 1993 and 2001, 68 distinct solution concepts addressing the pension gap could be identified in the political debate.5 Besides privatizing the system in order to yield higher returns or partly decoupling contributors from annuitants by introducing a capital-cover system, the following reform options or policy instruments ranged among the more popular solution concepts: fertility incentives in order to decrease the old-age dependency ratio (like parenting periods or tying the contribution or pension level to the number of children someone has “produced”); immigration; capital-cover elements within the public pension system; flat-rate pensions; more “gender equality” (that is, lowering the old-age dependency ratio by having more female employees and thus contributors); simply increasing the level of contributions; cutting the pension level; tying the pension equation to demographic or economic development; raising the retirement age; including civil servants, self-employed people, low-income earners, and other groups in the pension system; increasing subsidies from the general tax budget or replacing contributions completely; and removing intragenerative redistribution as noninsurance elements from the PAYG system. In other words, there was a large set of feasible policy instruments, two of which survived the selection process of policymakers. Why, then, was the pension system partly privatized, and why did this happen in 2001? Moreover, how were the competing advocacy coalitions around these policy preferences structured, and how would they change over time? Uncertainty, Complexity, and Why Policy Beliefs Mattered There has been considerable scientific uncertainty about demographic trends (Goldstein, Sobotka, & Jasilioniene, 2009; Lesthaeghe & Willems, 1999; Sobotka, 2004; Sobotka, Skirbekk, & Philipov, 2011) and their underlying mechanisms. The literature presents at least 10 different fertility theories, ranging from economic modernization, culture, social networks, or neoclassic economic theory to the rise of contraceptive technology, intergenerational wealth flows, decreasing sperm quality at the population level, or evolutionary biology. Similarly, there is considerable scientific disagreement about future trends of mortality, with some scholars arguing that there is an upper bound to life expectancy and others arguing that life expectancy may continue to increase linearly by up to 2.5 years per decade (Ney, 2000; Oeppen & Vaupel, 2002; Scherbov & Sanderson, 2010). This technical complexity rendered clear policy advice nearly impossible. In addition, there are feedback loops that render the system potentially unlearnable. Demographic change is a dynamic phenomenon. It gets worse until approximately 2035 and may improve afterward. This may be because population aging is jointly caused by low mortality and low fertility. Once the baby-boomers die out, they are replaced by much smaller cohort sizes, which is likely to affect the old-age dependency ratio in a positive way. If it is possible to survive the peak in 2035 by implementing some of the other proposed policy instruments, their proponents argue, demography will self-regulate the system, and the remaining rise in the 180 Policy Studies Journal, 41:1 contribution rate is so low that it can be compensated for by tax subsidies, by getting rid of noninsurance elements, or by increasing the number of contributors. Similar arguments apply to some of the other solution concepts that have been put forth: Fertility incentives may increase the number of additional contributors in the medium run but may also increase the number of pensioners in the long run, once these children become senior citizens themselves. In light of this uncertainty, complexity, and presence of feedback loops, the choice of the appropriate course of action largely depended on policy beliefs (Sabatier, 1998) rather than objective measurement, and political discourse became the main arena for determining what actions to take and what policy beliefs to adopt (cf. Heclo, 1978; Sabatier, 1987). Belief Change as a Driving Factor in the Subsystem Observers note that pension policymaking until the mid-1990s was determined by the so-called “pension consensus,” a hegemonic group of governmental organizations, political parties, and trade and industry associations whose dominant policy beliefs (Sabatier, 1998) and instrument choices were not challenged in the political sphere. This pension consensus eroded in the mid-1990s (Wehlau, 2009, p. 93) because the number of divergent, competing scientific conclusions on the pension problem increased substantially (Wehlau, 2009, p. 260). As a result, “there no longer is one pension truth, but a choice of several approaches to understanding the pension issue: what one chooses to believe now depends on where one stands” (Ney, 2001, p. 34). Wehlau (2009, pp. 259ff.) considers the increasing activities of the financial sector in the public discourse as the cause of this development: banks, insurance companies, and their associations (co)founded think tanks and research institutes like DIA and MEA as well as internal research departments like Deutsche Bank Research, and they made contracts with a number of previously independent researchers. This is in line with the hypothesis of Sabatier (1987) that competing advocacy coalitions use policy analyses and scientific expertise in order to grant credibility to their claims in the public sphere. The result was a newly emerging diversity of views on the future of the pension system and, eventually, a diffusion of the multipillar idea from the financial sector, science, and pseudoscience to voters and decision makers. Explanations for the increasing involvement of financial actors and the changing discourse range from electoral change (Lamping & Rüb, 2004) to within-party politics (Trampusch, 2008; Wehlau, 2009) or changing responsibilities of government departments (Wehlau, 2009) to the substitution of executives in agencies or advisory committees. Many observers note the important role that ideas, frameshifts, and discursive turnover played in this process (Hinrichs, 2004; Ney, 2001; Schulze & Jochem, 2007) or in German welfare state politics in general (Schmidt, 2002). They attribute the policy change in 2001 to changes in advocacy coalitions and dominant beliefs and to discursive contagion. Yet their accounts are rarely based on systematic empirical evidence and can be better described as instances of theory-building. What they have in common is that they hypothesize (i) an erosion of the previously dominant Leifeld: Reconceptualizing Major Policy Change in the ACF 181 advocacy coalition somewhere in the mid- or late 1990s; (ii) the introduction of new ideas or solution concepts into the political discourse; and (iii) an increased participation of actors from the financial sector in the debate, as the drivers of the policy change that can be observed in 2001. The analysis below will therefore fill this gap and (i) provide this systematic empirical evidence; (ii) quantify precisely when and how the pension consensus eroded; and (iii) show what kind of advocacy coalition structure emerged in the aftermath of this erosion, what it looks like, and why it was conducive to policy change. The Transition of the Coalition Structure As set out in the description of the case study background, the pension reform literature makes the following three-step prediction: In the first stage, there is a powerful and closed advocacy coalition with a large constituency until the mid- 1990s. Their views are hardly challenged. In the second stage, after 1996, the coalition slowly erodes due to contradictory evidence and new actors from the financial sector, who make claims about the lack of sustainability in the statutory pension system. Consequently, the proponents of a paradigm shift gain a larger constituency. The political discourse becomes bipolar, with more and more actors leaving the previously dominant advocacy coalition and joining the proponents of change. In the third stage, after the 1998 election, the old coalition vanishes completely. The insurgent advocacy coalition has successfully installed a new policy belief system, and the discourse becomes unipolar or centralized again, with the pro-privatization advocacy coalition becoming the new hegemonic coalition. This gives leeway for a pension reform introducing a paradigm shift, as intended by the financial sector. Three Stages: Hegemony, Polarization, and Erosion In order to test whether these claims are justified, a cluster analysis of aggregated affiliation networks (see methodology section) is conducted for the three critical time periods separately. Figure 1 shows the dendrogram of the first time period. There are two clusters, but it can be concluded from the agglomeration height that the separation between the clusters is not particularly strong. The group on the left contains most important actors that are classified as members of the pension consensus by the literature. The subgroup on the right contains some other members of the pension consensus like the peak trade association DGB, some industry associations (BDI, ZDH, BDS, ULA, and DIHT), and some financial organizations (DVAG, DB, and VLVU). The fact that DGB is among the second group supports the claim that the separation between the two clusters is not very strong. In general, the pension consensus advocacy coalition is clearly dominant. The second time period is depicted in Figure 2. Indeed, the coalition of system change proponents grows as large as the previously hegemonic advocacy coalition. A variety of financial organizations (DB, BVI, GDV, AGV, Dresdner Bank, etc.) challenges the traditional policy paradigm. The subsystem is extremely bipolar. There are some details that can be observed beyond the predictions of the literature: 182 Policy Studies Journal, 41:1 Numerous social actors start to support the pension consensus in order to avert the imminent threat of privatization, among them VdK, SoVD, the churches, and several trade unions. Furthermore, and against the background of German corporatism, most major industry associations support the status quo-oriented coalition (BDA, DIHT, and ZDH). In this stage of the political process, the two advocacy coalitions show the highest internal congruence and the smallest overlap between the two coalitions. In line with the conjectures, the pro-system-change advocacy coalition supersedes the previously hegemonic status quo-oriented coalition in the third stage (Figure 3). It grows much larger than the traditional advocacy coalition, has a clearly defined and congruent core (the actors between Ludwig-Erhard-Stiftung and BMF), and its constituency now includes the subgroup of industry associations previously supporting the PAYG coalition (BDA, DIHT, etc.). What is more, two critical governmental actors, BMF and BMWi, have left the PAYG coalition and joined the capitalcover proponents. Likewise, the Social Advisory Council has, due to personnel turnover, joined this coalition. The new structure of the discourse after the 1998 election essentially entails a hegemonic pro-system-change coalition composed of financial interests, industry interests, and parts of the government (BMF and BMWi) against a shrinking advocacy coalition of social interests, members of the large parties, and parts of the government (BK and BMAS). The 2001 Riester reform is thus no longer surprising, given the changes at the belief layer of the subsystem that were already initiated in the mid-1990s by introducing divergent views on optimal policy design into the pension discourse. There is yet one puzzle to solve. How can a reform be passed if the relevant veto players (Tsebelis, 1995) are still members of the shrinking, but still existing, status 0.00.51.01.52.0 ClusterAgglomerationHeight BMAS CDU FDP BMWi SPD BDA SB VDR BfA−AN Buba BGA DAG ABV BfA BK CDA ZDH BDI BDS BfA−AG BMF−WBR JuLi SPD−AGS CSU ULA DB CDU−MIT DIHT DGB DVAG VLVU Figure 1. First Stage, January 1, 1993–December 31, 1995. Notes: agglomerative hierarchical cluster analysis of the aggregated affiliation network; Ward’s optimization; Jaccard distances; only actors with more than two statements are preserved. Node colors and shapes are as follows: red triangles denote social actors; yellow circles denote liberal actors; blue circles denote actors from the financial market; magenta diamonds denote young people’s organizations; green diamonds denote scientific organizations; gray rectangles denote governmental actors and parties; and black rectangles denote other actors. Leifeld: Reconceptualizing Major Policy Change in the ACF 183 3 Cluster Agglomeration Height CDU−FU CDU−SU BfA−AG DIW Berlin CDU−MIT DIHT ZDH BKU CDU−JU BK BDA CDU−WR SVR BDI ZDB BdSt CAWM SPD−Jusos IW IfW Ifo Uni Bremen SPD BMAS CDU VDR CSU FDP SPD−60p CDU−JG VdK BfA SB PDS DGB Grüne CDA DAG BMF BfA−AN WB Uni Erlangen−Nürnberg Universität Hannover Continentale Versicherungs−Gruppe Europa−Versicherungen Uni Köln LZB Thüringen und Sachsen Universität Tübingen BMWi Ludwig−Erhard−Stiftung BVdB Dresdner Bank ZEW BMG Buba OECD IWG Uni Konstanz BVI Pensions Institute ABV BMWi−WBR DVfVW JDW Universtity of Chicago WJD JuLi Kronberger Kreis Uni Mannheim ASU Colonia Nordstern Lebensversicherungen BMFSFJ KDFB KFD GDV ABA AK−BPF AGV Initiative für Deutschland IG BAU IG BCE IGM 0 1 2 4 Figure2.SecondStage,January1,1996–December31,1998. Notes:SameasinFigure1. 184 Policy Studies Journal, 41:1 4 Cluster Agglomeration Height SPD−AfA Verdi IG BAU PDS SoVD BfA−AN DAG VdK DeuBiKo EKD Uni Bielefeld Uni Frankfurt DGB IGM BMAS Grüne SPD CDU CSU CDU−MIT FDP BK VDR CDA Uni Mannheim AG−GesM ARGE BDI IW CDU−JU HWWA IWH ASU ÖTV FAZ BdSt IfW SB DStGB Ifo AGV SVR Awo OECD DVAG DIA Uni Köln IWG ZdK LZB H, MV, SH Uni Konstanz Uni Freiburg Buba MIT BMWi BMWi−WBR DIW Berlin IG BCE DGZ−Deka−Bank, Frankfurt DB Research DB Metzler Allianz GDV Morgan Stanley DIS Ludwig−Erhard−Stiftung Uni Bamberg BVerfG CDH BGA BfA−AG BfA CDU−WR HDE Cardiff University Columbia University BDA DIHT ZDH BVI BdB AGP VW ABA BMF 0 1 2 3 Figure3.ThirdStage,January1,1999–May21,2001. Notes:SameasinFigure1. Leifeld: Reconceptualizing Major Policy Change in the ACF 185 quo-oriented coalition? In fact, the major parties are partisan veto players: the socialdemocratic party SPD and the Green Party as members of the government coalition, and the Christian-democratic parties CDU and CSU as partisan veto players in the Bundesrat, the second parliamentary chamber. Moreover, the ministry in charge of pensions (BMAS) cannot be easily superseded. I argue that it is necessary to scale down to smaller time units in order to make the relevant changes visible (in the remainder of this section). Figures 4–7 show annual time slices of the normalized actor congruence network between 1997 and 2001. The visualization of the year 1999 is skipped because it looks similar to the diagrams of the surrounding years 1998 and 2000. Threshold values are set individually so as to maximize the clarity of the network structure. In the network visualizations, the coordinates of vertices and the spatial distance between nodes cannot be interpreted in a meaningful way. The conclusions are solely drawn on the basis of the interconnectedness of the nodes. As described in the methodology section, the interpretation is straightforward: The strength of a tie between two actors reflects Figure 4. Normalized Actor Congruence Network in 1997 (F(w) Ն 0.31). Notes: Edge width visualizes the strength of association. The graph layout is based on a stress minimization (MDS) of graph-theoretic distances (Brandes & Pich, 2009) as implemented in the “quick layout” in visone (Brandes & Wagner, 2004). 186 Policy Studies Journal, 41:1 their normalized belief congruence. Clusters of interconnected actors can be interpreted as advocacy coalitions because the latter are made up of actors with overlapping policy core policy preferences (Sabatier, 1998, p. 117). The Status Quo in 1997 In 1997 (Figure 4), the extended status quo-oriented coalition aligns with social interests, whereas the system-change advocacy coalition does not exist yet. There is already a substantial number of financial (blue) actors, but they emphasize different concepts rather than standing united in promoting system change and privatization. They are virtually scattering all around the dominant advocacy coalition. In this early stage, the Federal Ministry for the Economy (BMWi) aligns with liberal actors and industry interests and does not show any overlap with the pension consensus. The broad consensus about the future directions of pension policy is clearly visible. In line with Sabatier (1998), however, there are two wings within this large advocacy coalition that follow the classic corporatist labor–capital cleavage line Figure 5. Normalized Actor Congruence Network in 1998 (F(w) Ն 0.29). Notes: Same as in Figure 4. Leifeld: Reconceptualizing Major Policy Change in the ACF 187 (denoted by the yellow nodes clustering southwest of the majority of state actors, and the red nodes, which are located predominantly northeast of them) and that have somewhat fuzzy borders and considerable overlap with each other. According to Sabatier (1998), this may be a typical feature of subsystems in corporatist regimes. He also notes that in these kinds of subsystems, governmental actors assume strong intermediary roles as policy brokers. The conjecture can be confirmed here because governmental actors are predominantly located between the two camps. Polarization Between 1998 and 2000 In 1998 (Figure 5), the year of the election, the financial actors are suddenly very united in their claims. The bipolar structure with the pension consensus on one side and the financial sector on the other side emerges. The BMWi is now positioned within the financial bloc along with a number of liberal actors. The parties and governmental actors align with the social actors, as before. However, a distinction Figure 6. Normalized Actor Congruence Network in 2000 (F(w) Ն 0.27). Notes: Same as in Figure 4. 188 Policy Studies Journal, 41:1 between the two subcoalitions is slightly visible, with social actors consistently being located south of the governmental actors and parties. In the year 2000, polarization reaches its peak. There are numerous ties within each advocacy coalition, and between-block density is very low. BMF, BMWi, and SB have joined the system-change coalition. The government is thus divided over the pension question. Some other actors previously known as being rather social also join the new advocacy coalition. Among them are DAG, a major trade union, and the employees’ wing of the BfA. The hegemony of the status quo-defending advocacy coalition fades away, and some early adopters switch from one coalition to the other in 2000. These observations indicate that transitions between subsystem equilibria are not only accompanied by a belief polarization but also by early adopters who leave their coalition and adopt the beliefs of the former opponent. This development leads to an erosion of the pension consensus in late 2000 and early 2001. Figure 7. Normalized Actor Congruence Network between January and May 2001 (F(w) Ն 0.23). Notes: Same as in Figure 4. Leifeld: Reconceptualizing Major Policy Change in the ACF 189 Dissolution of the Formerly Hegemonic Coalition and Institutionalization of the New Advocacy Coalition Figure 7 shows the structure of the discourse between January and May 2001. The status quo-oriented coalition has broken apart and is now situated at the margin of the new dominant privatization coalition, in some cases even bridging the housing and the insurance wing of the system-change coalition. The chancellor (BK) has left his original coalition completely and joins the insurance cluster. Similarly, the association of the German statutory pension insurance scheme (VDR) joins the financial coalition and abandons its discursive ties to other governmental actors almost completely. Surprisingly, even the social actors are now dispersed all around the new dominant coalition. At the lower end, a small clique of social actors connects both to the chancellor and to the financial sector. Other social actors reside at various locations in the discourse (CDA, DAG, and IG BAU); they are largely disconnected from the governmental actors with whom they used to share many basic premises on how the pension system should be designed. Significance for the Pension Reform Literature How do these observations fit into previous accounts of German pension politics? Besides providing further evidence for the dominance of the newly established coalition right before the Riester reform was adopted, the main conclusion from these observations is that core decision makers and veto players like the chancellor, the major parties, and the relevant federal ministries switched from their old coalition to the newly established coalition and thus gave leeway to the reform. A clear pattern of structural change at the level of policy preferences could be identified prior to the reform in 2001: a single hegemonic advocacy coalition until 1997, the emergence of a second advocacy coalition from 1998 onwards, a strong bipolarization of the discourse with an increasing number of critical political actors leaving their old coalition due to the credibility problems of the old paradigm, and a complete erosion of the old coalition and attachment of their members to the new hegemonic advocacy coalition. This constitutes a shift from one normal state of policymaking until 1997 to a new normal state of policymaking after 2000, with a polarization phase in the meantime. Only after this process was finished was the reform adopted. This lends new credibility to the argument that changes in political discourse led to the reform and specifies clearly how and when these changes came about. Reconnecting the Findings to the ACF A clear transition pattern between a single hegemonic advocacy coalition until 1997 and another hegemonic advocacy coalition from 2001 on can be identified in the case study. Between these equilibria, there is a transition phase in which both coalitions coexist and the subsystem becomes more and more polarized. 190 Policy Studies Journal, 41:1 Early Adopters and Learning Across Coalitions Once polarization has taken off, the erosion of the old coalition starts with some early adopters who leave their old coalition and join the political opponent. These are usually agencies or decision makers rather than vested interest groups. This process resembles a bandwagon effect (Nadeau, Cloutier, & Guay, 1993). The reasons for this behavior may be manifold: in some cases outlined above, the directors or heads of an organization were replaced indirectly by members of the new coalition (SB and BMF); in other cases, policy learning across coalitions due to the discursive activity of the financial sector coalition may explain this shift (BfA-AN and DAG). In any case, these changing coalition memberships lent more credibility to the claims of the newly established coalition and presumably contributed to the erosion of the pension consensus coalition. Both processes—polarization and learning—interacted and had a disintegrating effect on the belief system inherent in the status quo-oriented coalition. These results have implications for the ACF. A Single Hegemonic Coalition Normal policymaking in the case study under scrutiny seems to be determined by a single hegemonic advocacy coalition rather than a competition between two or more coalitions. Such a competition can only be found in the relatively short transition phase between two subsystem equilibria or “normal states” of policymaking. How can this finding be explained? One possibility—as vaguely set out by Sabatier and Weible (2007, p. 199)—is that the ACF was previously too pluralism-centric, and corporatist systems work differently. Nonetheless, although the typical corporatist patterns of fuzzy coalitions with brokers in between (Sabatier & Weible, 2007, p. 200) are observable in 1997 and, to a lesser extent, within coalitions in the other years, other studies in corporatist political systems have found a prevalence of competing coalitions (for an overview of studies and their geographic setting, see Sabatier, 1998, p. 100), which indicates that more fine-grained institutional differences between subsystems than the simple corporatism–pluralism dimension are likely to account for this variation. In this perspective, the variation could be related to differences between subsystems or policy sectors rather than polities at large (cf. Lowi, 1972). Old-age security is a typical redistributive policy sector, in which the state collects taxes and redistributes them to other individuals. In other words, state authorities have a prevalent role in this kind of subsystem. In contrast, regulative policy sectors like telecommunication or environmental policy are characterized by the surveillance of market or private actors by the state. Regulatory interventions are only made if the provision of infrastructures or public goods is inefficient. Regulative policy subsystems may thus be more prone to competition by interest groups than redistributive subsystems. Hence, in redistributive subsystems like old-age security, policy change may be characterized by a transition between stable hegemonic coalitions, with polarization and learning across coalitions occurring in the transition phase, whereas regulative subsystems may be characterized by the competition of advocacy Leifeld: Reconceptualizing Major Policy Change in the ACF 191 coalitions as confirmed by numerous studies. In fact, most ACF applications were conducted in policy sectors with a highly regulatory character (for an early overview, see Sabatier, 1998, p. 100), which is why most studies could confirm the original predictions. The ACF allows for this possibility—albeit with a different predicted pattern—but does not pursue it any further: “subsystem dynamics may vary by policy type [. . .]. For example, one might expect regulatory and redistributive subsystems to be characterized by multiple coalitions, while distributive policies may usually have a single (pork-barrel) coalition except during periods when cost-bearers (e.g., taxpayers or environmentalists) are activated” (Sabatier, 1988, p. 159). Future research may shed more light on these open questions, in particular on why some subsystems are characterized by competition and others by hegemony and whether redistribution versus regulation can explain this difference. Transitions and Major Policy Change Furthermore, the case study presented above suggests that a transition between two normal states or subsystem equilibria may be required for major policy change to occur. In the case of a single hegemonic coalition, the transition phase features two interrelated processes: polarization and learning across coalitions (where learning is a result of the polarization that has already begun). This leaves several interesting questions to be explored by future research: Is the transition observed here a general pattern in subsystems with a hegemonic coalition, or is this an idiosyncratic case? Is there a similar transition phase in subsystems with two or more competing coalitions? And what does such a realignment in pluralist subsystems look like at the discursive level? Moreover, the reasons why a transition is initiated in the first place must be disentangled. The ACF allows for external perturbations to initiate learning processes across coalitions, hence leading to major policy change. As it seems, in subsystems with a single hegemonic coalition, polarization is a necessary additional mechanism that must take place before learning occurs. What are the mechanisms that trigger polarization? In the pension subsystem analyzed above, the literature suggests several institutional forces ranging from the national election in 1998 to party politics to substitution of agency executives (see the case study background section). Conclusion This article presents two key findings. First, it shows how major policy change comes about. In the case study of German pension politics, preference polarization and shifting coalition memberships of early adopters have been pinpointed at the level of policy beliefs (the “discursive” level) as necessary conditions for third-order policy change to happen. The Riester reform in 2001 was predated by a shift from one hegemonic advocacy coalition to a bipolarization and finally to the replacement of the former by a new dominant advocacy coalition. In this process, some key actors 192 Policy Studies Journal, 41:1 (“early adopters”) switched their affiliation over time, initiating a diffusion process and culminating in an erosion of the pension consensus. Second, discourse network analysis is presented as a viable measurement instrument for the analysis of policy debates over time. The approach is able to graph relational changes at the level of policy core policy preferences and hence the belief component of advocacy coalitions and subsystems. The results presented here also make a genuinely new contribution to the analysis of German pension politics in the public policy literature. For the first time, the often-hypothesized ideational changes among actors were operationalized in a systematic way. However, more importantly, the results may have implications for other policy subsystems and other polities. Is policy change in subsystems always predated by a discursive polarization that looks like the one identified here? Or might this pattern of polarization covary with redistributive versus regulative policy subsystems or other factors like technical complexity, moral tension, institutionalization of the policy sector, the existence of a discursive forum like a widely read newspaper, or other variables related to the subsystem under scrutiny? Under what conditions is “normal” (that is, stable) policymaking accompanied by the presence of only one hegemonic coalition, as witnessed here, and under what circumstances is politics over a decade or more multipolar and conflictual, as suggested by the ACF (Sabatier, 1998)? Do governmental actors usually act as bridges, or “brokers” (Sabatier, 1998), between advocacy coalitions when a normal-state discourse is multipolar, or is this pattern more prevalent within dominant coalitions in corporatist settings, as the results in 1997 imply (see also Sabatier & Weible, 2007, p. 200)? And finally, what rational, boundedly rational, and cognitive mechanisms can explain why actors contribute certain solution concepts to the public debate at certain points in time? The toolbox of social network analysis, and in particular the approach of discourse network analysis, can help to answer questions like these. It facilitates the operationalization of the apparently ill-defined phenomenon of political discourse and opens up a new and previously inaccessible research agenda. Appendix The Discourse Network Model in Matrix Notation The descriptive discourse network model was presented in graph-theoretic notation. For the sake of clarity, the model is presented in matrix notation in this appendix. The information encoded in a collection of articles can be represented by a four-dimensional array of actors, concepts, agreement relations, and time points: X m n l k× × × . This array can be broken down into a set of affiliation matrices for each time point and each relation separately: Xr t m n , × . In such an affiliation matrix, actors occupy the row labels and concepts the column labels. A cell entry of xij = 1 denotes that actor Leifeld: Reconceptualizing Major Policy Change in the ACF 193 i refers to concept j in a certain way (relation r) during time period t. A cell entry of xij = 0 denotes that actor i does not refer to concept j in the specified way during t. An actor congruence network can be computed by multiplying the affiliation matrix by its transpose: Y X Xr t r t r t T , , ,:a = (8) This yields an m ¥ m square co-occurrence matrix with the edge weights as the cell entries for each of the two agreement relations separately. Next, the matrices for the different agreement relations must be combined into a single matrix Yt a . This can be simply done by adding up the two matrices: the actor congruence matrix can be obtained by computing Y X Xt r t r t T r l a : , ,= ( ) = ∑ 1 (9) In order to normalize the edge weights stored in Yt a , one first has to generate an aggregated affiliation matrix by adding up the two separate agreement relations. The resulting matrix does not distinguish between positive and negative referral anymore: X Xt r t r l = = ∑ , 1 (10) This matrix must be dichotomized; that is, nonzero elements must be recoded as l: ∀ = > = ⎧ ⎨ ⎩ x x x x ij ij ij ij : dich if if 1 0 0 0 (11) In the dichotomized, aggregated affiliation matrix Xt dich , let xi• dich denote the row sum of actor i (with j Յ n being the index for the concepts): x xi ij j n • = = ∑dich dich 1 (12) A weighted edge yij in the congruence network Yt a , as defined in equation (9), can then be normalized by dividing it by the average row sum (in the affiliation matrix) for row actor i and column actor j in the congruence matrix, which is equivalent to equation (7): ∀ ( ) = +• • y y y x x ij ij ij i j : Φ 2 dich dich (13) Philip Leifeld is a postdoctoral researcher at the Swiss Federal Institute of Aquatic Science and Technology (Eawag), and at the Institute of Political Science, University of Bern, Switzerland. 194 Policy Studies Journal, 41:1 Notes The author wishes to thank Swiss Federal Institute of Aquatic Science and Technology (Eawag), Dübendorf, Switzerland, and University of Bern, Institute of Political Science. The author also wishes to thank Frank Kaiser, Volker Schneider, Christoph Engel, Karin Ingold, members of the workshop series “Networks and Time” at Columbia University, and four anonymous reviewers for helpful comments on earlier drafts, and the Max Planck International Research Network on Aging (MaxNetAging), the Max Planck Institute for Demographic Research, and the Max Planck Institute for Research on Collective Goods for financial and scientific support. 1. Other kinds of archival data could have been used alternatively. For example, Fisher et al. (2013) extract issue stances of actors from testimonies of legislators and interest groups in the U.S. Congress. News media data presumably capture a wider variety of political actors, whereas congressional testimonies may be more confined to actors involved in the legislative process. On the other hand, media data may be more selective in favor of mediagenic actors. More research is required on how these different political arenas overlap in terms of their sets of actors. 2. The l index is needed later in equation (6) to sum over the different relations. For this reason, agreement and disagreement are not merely hardcoded as R = {r1, r2}. 3. To understand how statements were encoded, consider the following fictional example: “The number of immigrants does not affect the old-age ratio. We would have to invite 175 million people to compensate for demographic change. Increasing women’s share in the labor market to generate additional contributions should be our primary goal.” In this case, beside the name of the person who makes the statement and his or her organizational affiliation, the following codes would be attached to the text portion: “immigration”–“no,” and “increase female labor participation”–“yes.” 4. A list of all normative concepts as well as the list of actors and their abbreviations can be found in Appendix S1. 5. A list of these concepts is provided in Appendix S1. References Barranco, José, and Dominique Wisler. 1999. “Validity and Systematicity of Newspaper Data in Event Analysis.” European Sociological Review 15 (3): 301–22. Baumgartner, Frank R., and Bryan D. Jones. 1991. “Agenda Dynamics and Policy Subsystems.” The Journal of Politics 53 (4): 1044–74. Berkel, Barbara, Axel Börsch-Supan, Alexander Ludwig, and Joachim Winter. 2004. “Sind Die Probleme Der Bevölkerungsalterung durch eine höhere Geburtenrate lösbar?” Perspektiven der Wirtschaftspolitik 5 (1): 71–90. Birg, Herwig. 2002. “Demographic Ageing and Population Decline in Twenty-First-Century Germany: Consequences for the Systems of Social Insurance.” Population Bulletin of the United Nations 44–45: 103–34. Börsch-Supan, Axel, and Christina Benita Wilke. 2003. “The German Public Pension System: How it Was, How it Will Be.” Discussion Paper 34-2003. Ann Arbor: Michigan Retirement Research Center (MRRC). Brandes, Ulrich, and Christian Pich. 2009. “An Experimental Study on Distance-Based Graph Drawing.” In Proceedings of the 16th International Symposium on Graph Drawing, 218–229, Berlin: Springer. Brandes, Ulrich, and Dorothea Wagner. 2004. “Visone—Analysis and Visualization of Social Networks.” In Graph Drawing Software, ed. M. Jünger, and P. Mutzel. Berlin/Heidelberg: Springer, 321–40. Breyer, Friedrich. 2000. “Kapitaldeckungs- Versus Umlageverfahren.” Perspektiven der Wirtschaftspolitik 1 (4): 383–405. Finney, Henry C. 1981. “Improving the Reliability of Retrospective Survey Measures.” Evaluation Review 5 (2): 207–29. Fisher, Dana R., Philip Leifeld, and Yoko Iwaki. 2013. “Mapping the Ideological Networks of American Climate Politics.” Climatic Change 116 (3): 523–45. Leifeld: Reconceptualizing Major Policy Change in the ACF 195 Fisher, Dana R., Joseph Waggle, and Philip Leifeld. 2012. “Where Does Political Polarization Come From? Locating Polarization Within the U.S. Climate Change Debate.” American Behavioral Scientist 57 (1): 70–92. Geweke, John, and Donald L. Martin. 2002. “Pitfalls in Drawing Policy Conclusions from Retrospective Survey Data: The Case of Advertising and Underage Smoking.” Journal of Risk and Uncertainty 25: 111–31. Goldstein, Joshua R., Tomáš Sobotka, and Aiva Jasilioniene. 2009. “The End of ‘Lowest-Low’ Fertility?” Population and Development Review 35 (4): 663–99. Graf von der Schulenburg, J.-Matthias, and Susanne Wähling. 1997. “Das Elend der Alterssicherung in Deutschland.” In Rentenkrise. Und wie wir sie meistern können, ed. G. S. Becker, G. Dahlmanns, S. Homburg, M. Neumann, J.-M. Graf von der Schulenburg, and S. Wähling. Bad Homburg: Frankfurter Institut—Stiftung Marktwirtschaft und Politik, 27–59. Hall, Peter A. 1993. “Policy Paradigms, Social Learning, and the State: The Case of Economic Policymaking in Britain.” Comparative Politics 25 (3): 275–96. Heclo, Hugh. 1978. “Issue Networks and the Executive Establishment.” In The New American Political System, ed. A. King. Washington, DC: American Enterprise Institute, 87–124. Henry, Adam Douglas, Mark Lubell, and Michael McCoy. 2011. “Belief Systems and Social Capital as Drivers of Policy Network Structure: The Case of California Regional Planning.” Journal of Public Administration Research and Theory 21 (3): 419–44. Hinrichs, Karl. 2004. “Alterssicherungspolitik in Deutschland: Zwischen Kontinuität und Paradigmenwechsel.” In Gesellschaft mit beschränkter Hoffnung. Reformfähigkeit und die Möglichkeit rationaler Politik, ed. P. Stykow, and J. Beyer. Wiesbaden: VS Verlag für Sozialwissenschaften, 266–86. Ingold, Karin Mirjam. 2011. “Network Structures Within Policy Processes: Coalitions, Power, and Brokerage in Swiss Climate Policy.” Policy Studies Journal 39 (3): 435–59. Janson, Carl Gunnar. 1990. “Retrospective Data, Undesirable Behavior, and the Longitudinal Perspective.” In Data Quality in Longitudinal Research, ed. D. Magnusson, and L. R. Bergman. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press, 100–121. Jenkins-Smith, Hank C., Gilbert K. St. Clair, and Brian Woods. 1991. “Explaining Change in Policy Subsystems: Analysis of Coalition Stability and Defection Over Time.” American Journal of Political Science 35 (4): 851–80. Jones, Bryan D., and Frank R. Baumgartner. 2005. “A Model of Choice for Public Policy.” Journal of Public Administration Research and Theory 15 (3): 325–51. Koopmans, Ruud. 1996. “New Social Movements and Changes in Political Participation in Western Europe.” West European Politics 19 (1): 28–50. Kriesi, Hanspeter. 1995. New Social Movements in Western Europe: A Comparative Analysis. Minneapolis, MN: University of Minnesota Press. Lamping, Wolfram, and Friedbert W. Rüb. 2004. “From the Conservative Welfare State to an ‘Uncertain Something Else’: German Pension Politics in Comparative Perspective.” Policy & Politics 32 (2): 169–91. Leifeld, Philip. 2011. Discourse Networks and German Pension Politics. PhD diss., University of Konstanz. ———. 2013. Discourse Network Analyzer Manual. Swiss Federal Institute of Aquatic Science and Technology (Eawag), Dübendorf, Switzerland [Online]. http://www.philipleifeld.de. Accessed January 16, 2013. Leifeld, Philip, and Sebastien Haunss. 2012. “Political Discourse Networks and the Conflict over Software Patents in Europe.” European Journal of Political Research 51 (3): 382–409. Leifeld, Philip, and Volker Schneider. 2012. “Information Exchange in Policy Networks.” American Journal of Political Science 53 (3): 731–44. Lesthaeghe, Ron, and Paul Willems. 1999. “Is Low Fertility a Temporary Phenomenon in the European Union?” Population and Development Review 25 (2): 211–28. Lowi, Theodore J. 1972. “Four Systems of Policy, Politics, and Choice.” Public Administration Review 32 (4): 298–310. 196 Policy Studies Journal, 41:1 Lubell, Mark N., John T. Scholz, Ramiro Berardo, and Garry Robins. 2012. “Testing Policy Theory With Statistical Models of Networks.” Policy Studies Journal 40 (3): 351–74. Mintrom, Michael, and Sandra Vergari. 1996. “Advocacy Coalitions, Policy Entrepreneurs, and Policy Change.” Policy Studies Journal 24 (3): 420–34. Nadeau, Richard, Edouar Cloutier, and J.-H. Guay. 1993. “New Evidence About the Existence of a Bandwagon Effect in the Opinion Formation Process.” International Political Science Review 14 (2): 203–13. Ney, Steven. 2000. “Are You Sitting Comfortably . . . Then We’ll Begin: Three Gripping Policy Stories About Pension Reform.” Innovation: The European Journal of Social Science Research 13 (4): 341–71. ———. 2001. Pension Reform in Germany. Public Participation and the Pension Policy Process: The Citizen and Pension Reform (PEN-REF Project). Deliverable D2. Vienna: The Interdisciplinary Centre for Comparative Research in the Social Sciences (ICCR) [Online]. http://www.iccrinternational.org/pen-ref/docs/penref-d2-de.pdf. Accessed January 16, 2013. Nohrstedt, Daniel. 2010. “Do Advocacy Coalitions Matter? Crisis and Change in Swedish Nuclear Energy Policy.” Journal of Public Administration Research and Theory 20 (2): 309–33. Oeppen, James, and James W. Vaupel. 2002. “Broken Limits to Life Expectancy.” Science 296 (5570): 1029–31. Pappi, Franz Urban, and Christian H. C. A. Henning. 1998. “Policy Networks: More Than a Metaphor?” Journal of Theoretical Politics 10 (4): 553–75. Sabatier, Paul A. 1987. “Knowledge, Policy-Oriented Learning, and Policy Change: An Advocacy Coalition Framework.” Science Communication 8 (4): 649–92. ———. 1988. “An Advocacy Coalition Framework of Policy Change and the Role of Policy-Oriented Learning Therein.” Policy Sciences 21 (2): 129–68. ———. 1998. “The Advocacy Coalition Framework: Revisions and Relevance for Europe.” Journal of European Public Policy 5 (1): 98–130. Sabatier, Paul A., and Christopher M. Weible. 2007. “The Advocacy Coalition Framework.” In Theories of the Policy Process, ed. P. A. Sabatier. Boulder, CO: Westview Press, 189–220. Scherbov, Sergei, and Warren C. Sanderson. 2010. “Negative Folgen der Alterung bislang überbewertet. Neue Maßzahlen für aktuelle Bevölkerungsentwicklung.” Demografische Forschung Aus Erster Hand 7 (4): 1–2. Schmähl, Winfried. 2000. “Perspektiven Der Alterssicherungspolitik in Deutschland—Über Konzeptionen, Vorschläge Und Einen Angestrebten Paradigmenwechsel.” Perspektiven der Wirtschaftspolitik 1 (4): 407–30. Schmidt, Vivien A. 2002. “Does Discourse Matter in the Politics of Welfare State Adjustment?” Comparative Political Studies 35 (2): 168–93. ———. 2010. “Taking Ideas and Discourse Seriously: Explaining Change through Discursive Institutionalism as the Fourth ‘New Institutionalism’.” European Political Science Review 2 (1): 1–25. Schneider, Volker. 1992. “The Structure of Policy Networks.” European Journal of Political Research 21 (1–2): 109–29. Schulze, Isabelle, and Sven Jochem. 2007. “Germany: Beyond Policy Gridlock.” In Handbook of West European Pension Politics, ed. E. Immergut, K. M. Anderson, and I. Schulze. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 660–710. Sobotka, Tomáš. 2004. “Is Lowest-Low Fertility in Europe Explained by the Postponement of Childbearing?” Population and Development Review 30 (2): 195–220. Sobotka, Tomáš, Vegard Skirbekk, and Dimiter Philipov. 2011. “Economic Recession and Fertility in the Developed World.” Population and Development Review 37 (2): 267–306. Trampusch, Christine. 2008. “Sequenzorientierte Policy-Analyse. Warum die Rentenreform von Walter Riester nicht an Reformblockaden scheiterte.” In Die Zukunft der Policy-Forschung. Theorien, Methoden, Anwendungen, ed. F. Janning, and K. Toens. Wiesbaden, Germany: VS Verlag für Sozialwissenschaften, 259–78. Tsebelis, George. 1995. “Decision Making in Political Systems: Veto Players in Presidentialism, Parliamentarism, Multicameralism and Multipartyism.” British Journal of Political Science 25: 289–325. Leifeld: Reconceptualizing Major Policy Change in the ACF 197 van der Vaart, Wander, Johan van der Zouwen, and Wil Dijkstra. 1995. “Retrospective Questions: Data Quality, Task Difficulty, and the Use of a Checklist.” Quality & Quantity 29: 299–315. Wehlau, Diana. 2009. Lobbyismus Und Rentenreform. Der Einfluss Der Finanzdienstleistungsbranche Auf Die Teil-Privatisierung Der Alterssicherung. Wiesbaden, Germany: VS Verlag für Sozialwissenschaften. Weible, Christopher M. 2005. “Beliefs and Perceived Influence in A Natural Resource Conflict: An Advocacy Coalition Approach to Policy Networks.” Political Research Quarterly 58 (3): 461–75. ———. 2010. “Collaborative Institutions, Functional Areas, and Beliefs: What Are Their Roles in Policy Networks?” Self-Organizing Federalism: Collaborative Mechanisms to Mitigate Institutional Collective Action Dilemmas, ed. Richard C. Feiock, and John T. Scholz. New York: Cambridge University Press, 179–203. Zafonte, Matthew, and Paul Sabatier. 2004. “Short-Term Versus Long-Term Coalitions in the Policy Process: Automotive Pollution Control, 1963–1989.” The Policy Studies Journal 32 (1): 75–107. Supporting Information Additional Supporting Information may be found in the online version of this article at the publisher’s web-site: Appendix 1. List of concepts in the dataset. 2. List of actors in the dataset. 198 Policy Studies Journal, 41:1