EUROPEAN CENTRAL BANK EUROSYSTEM Working Paper Series Mariachiaracavaiieri, Alice Eiiet, Concentration, market power and Peter McAdam, Filippos Petroulakis, Anasoares, Isabel vansteenkiste dynamism in the euro area Discussion Papers Disclaimer: This paper should not be reported as representing the views of the European Central Bank (ECB). The views expressed are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect those of the ECB. Discussion papers Discussion papers are research-based papers on policy relevant topics. They are singled out from standard Working Papers in that they offer a broader and more balanced perspective. While being partly based on original research, they place the analysis in the wider context of the literature on the topic. They also consider explicitly the policy perspective, with a view to develop a number of key policy messages. Their format offers the advantage that alternative analyses and perspectives can be combined, including theoretical and empirical work. Discussion papers are written in a style that is more broadly accessible compared to standard Working Papers. They are light on formulas and regression tables, at least in the main text. The selection and distribution of discussion papers are subject to the approval of the Director General of the Directorate General Research. ECB Working Paper Series No 2253 / March 2019 1 Abstract We examine the degree of market power in the big four countries of the euro area using macro and firm micro data. We focus on three main indicators of market power in and across countries: namely, the concentration ratios, the markup and the degree of economic dynamism. For the macro database we use the sectoral data of KLEMs and for the micro data we use a combination of Orbis and iBACH (dating from 2006 onwards). We find that, in contrast to the situation in the US, market power metrics have been relatively stable over recent years and - in terms of the markup specifically - marginally trending down since the late 1990s, driven largely by Manufacturing. In terms of the debate as to the merits of market concentration, we find (relying on results for Manufacturing) that firms in sectors which exhibit high concentration, but are categorized as 'high tech users, generally have higher TFP growth rates. By contrast, markups tend to display a bi-modal distribution when looked at through the lens of high concentration and high tech usage. These results would tend to confirm that the rise in market power documented for other economies is not obviously a euro area phenomenon and that welfare and policy analysis of market concentration is inevitably complex. Keywords: Market Power, Euro Area, micro-macro data. JEL Classifiction: D2, D4, Nl, 03. ECB Working Paper Series No 2253 / March 2019 2 Non-technical summary There is an increasing public policy debate as to whether market power of firms in the economy has become "too big". By market power we mean, (i) in terms of the market share taken by a few companies (relative to historical trends) and (ii) the extent to which firms can price above their (marginal) costs. A number of recent studies have documented that in particular in the United States, but also potentially at the global level, firm concentration ratios appear to be on the rise while the degree of imperfect competition (as proxied by the markup, i.e. the price marginal cost ratio) is rising. We have, however, far less information about the degree and evolution of market power and competitive intensity in the euro area. This Discussion Paper aims to contribute to our understanding by means of a comprehensive approach which considers the evolution of macro and micro data based firm markups, firm concentration and economic dynamics in the four largest euro area countries. Our findings are the following: 1. Concentration ratios in the euro area have remained broadly flat in the last ten years or so, albeit with some differences across sectors and countries. The top 4 firms in our measure of the total euro area economy account for between 10% -20% of aggregate sales. Manufacturing has relatively higher concentration levels (around 16 - 30%). 2. The aggregate euro area markup has been fairly stable, varying around a value of 10-15% and has even declined marginally since late 1990s/early 2000s, driven largely by developments in Manufacturing, and potentially the impact of trade and monetary integration in the euro area. There are industries and firms that have high (and rising) markups but such firms are not those with particularly high market shares; thus they do not impart a trend in the aggregate markup. 3. As regards economic dynamism (the creation of new firms and jobs), there has been no obvious change in the trend in the euro area. This contrasts with the United States, where dynamism - although in absolute terms above that of the euro area - has witnessed some considerable decreases over time reflecting recent shifts in market structure (especially in labour markets). 4. Industries within the Manufacturing Sector which exhibit high concentration, but which are categorized as 'high tech users, generally are associated with higher TFP growth rates. By contrast, markups tend to display a bi-modal distribution when looked at through the lens of high concentration and high tech usage - namely a tail of firms with above-average markups and below average markups. 5. There remains considerable scope to improve Research and Development (R&D), hi-tech activity and diffusion of best practices, and reduce barriers to new entrants ECB Working Paper Series No 2253 / March 2019 3 in the euro area. Structural reforms in product markets and further progress on the Service Directive (of 2006) therefore remains a potent policy message. In that respect, a relatively strong anti-trust framework at the aggregate euro area level looks to be a positive aspect. 6. Notwithstanding, the increasing degree of global firms and often complex ownership structures across certain firms and industries, allied to the associated measurement issues, provides a challenge to fully understand concentration and market power outcomes and to assess policy responses. ECB Working Paper Series No 2253 / March 2019 4 1 Introduction There is an increasing public policy debate as to whether market power (i.e., markups, sales concentration) of firms in the economy has become "too big". By this we typically mean (i) in terms of the market share taken by a few companies (relative to historical trends) and (ii) the extent to which these firms can price above their (marginal) costs. A number of recent studies have documented that in particular in the United States, but also potentially at the global level, firm concentration ratios are on the rise while the degree of imperfect competition (as proxied by the markup, i.e. the price marginal cost ratio) is rising.1 The conventional view is that (in a static sense at least) market power is welfare reducing (leaving aside some special cases like natural monopolies) since it results in firms charging too high prices and producing too little output relative to the competitive benchmark (Tirole 1988). Alongside this, firms, with a dominant market position may under invest (relative to a more competitive environment) and may (implicitly or otherwise) erect barriers to new potentially more innovative firms (OECD 2005). It was on the basis of these views that the foundations for the modern day anti-trust laws were laid, and which continue to guide much of economic policy discussions (see Crampton 2003).2 The link between firm market power and welfare and economic performance, however, is far from straightforward. Indeed, market power can also be viewed in a positive light; in some endogenous growth models (e.g., Aghion & Howitt 1997), the prospect of enjoying some market power (and profits) is the main incentive for firms to invest and innovate. If firms were not able to appropriate the results of their investments - whether they are research and development (R&D) expenditures or others - they may not do so at all. This may deprive consumers of higher quality goods and/or new product varieties (see Motta 2003). Moreover, a key (if arguably under-appreciated) challenge in such debates is to identify what are the sources of market dominance. If a firm has a dominant market position it may be that it has a superior selling or production technology. Over time, as existing technologies proliferate and diffuse, that technological advantage will be eroded. Alternatively, a monopolistic outcome may reflect rent seeking by a firm as it looks to win legal or protected status or engineers its activities in such a way as to discourage new entrants. Bringing these two opposing views together, Aghion et al. (2005) demonstrate, using a panel of UK firms, that there in fact exists an inverted U-shaped relationship between 1 See for instance, among others, De Loecker & Eeckhout (2017, 2018), Diez et al. (2018), Dottling et al. (2017a) and Autor et al. (2017a). 2 Baqaee & Farhi (2018) suggest that elimination of markups would raise TFP by about 20% in the US (for the years 2014-15). ECB Working Paper Series No 2253 / March 2019 5 market power and innovation: At low levels of competition the "escape competition" outcome tends to dominate the "Schumpeterian" effect.3 By contrast, when competition is high, the Schumpeterian effect is likely to dominate because a larger fraction of sectors in equilibrium have innovation being performed by laggard firms with low initial profits. Finally, for moderate levels of competition, both types of firms have rather strong incentive to innovate. These findings would suggest that there exists an optimal (non-zero) level of market power in the economy. However, determining the degree of market power - let alone whether it is optimal -is fraught with difficulties. In theory, the definition of market power is straightforward, it is measured by the ability of firms to maintain prices above marginal cost. Empirically, however, markups are not directly observable and therefore need to be estimated in some form. As a result, researchers have in practice relied on a variety of approaches to assess the market power of firms, which we essentially can group into three principal methods. The first of these approaches is to derive firm markups from demand data (see for instance Berry et al. 2004). This is considered a well-tested and reliable way to estimate markups (De Loecker & Eeckhout 2018). However, the approach is complicated by the demanding data requirements and the assumptions on how and in which market firms compete. As a result, this approach can only be used for a short period of time and for few selected industries that can comply with the data requirements. The approach is therefore not well suited if one wants to study economy-wide developments. In view of these limitations, researchers and competition authorities have often resorted to a second approach to proxy market power, by measuring the degree of firm concentration. However, such proxies are at best imperfect. Indeed, the (positive) correlation between market concentration and market power only holds under very specific market structures, such as Cournot quantity competition (e.g., Tirole (1988)). When relaxing some of the assumptions in the Cournot quantity competition model, such as assuming that products are differentiated, there is no longer necessarily a relation between market concentration and market power. More recently, and with the aim of overcoming the drawbacks of the aforementioned methodologies, a cost based approach to measuring markups was developed. Hall (1988) initiated this approach for aggregate data and more recently De Loecker & Warzynski (2012) adapted it for applications to micro data. This approach relies on significantly less data and assumptions than the demand approach and therefore allows for the calculations of firm markups over a long time period and for a large range of firms. 3 Schumpetarian models predict that competition fosters innovation in neck-and-neck sectors where firms operate at the same technological level. In such sectors, increased product market competition reduces pre-innovation rents, increasing the incremental profits from innovating and becoming a leader. This is the "escape-competition effect". The models also predict a negative "Schumpeterian effect": increased competition reduces the post-innovation rents of laggard firms and thus their incentive to catch up with the leader. ECB Working Paper Series No 2253 / March 2019 6 Notwithstanding, this third approach also has drawbacks, such as the requirement to appropriately define what constitutes variable costs to a firm (see Traina (2018) for a detailed discussion).4 As a result, any conclusion on firm market power would require an assessment based on a range of indicators. For economy-wide developments both the second and third approach can be applied and further complemented by, for instance, indicators on firm dynamics (such as entry and exit). Moreover, for the United States, recently a number of studies have concluded that market power is on the rise. This conclusion is corroborated by considering a number of trends: a rise in firm markups based on a variety of approaches, a rise in market concentration and a decline in a variety of measure of economic dynamism. Some authors (e.g. De Loecker & Eeckhout (2017)) have concluded that such trends have an explanatory role in outcomes such as the decline productivity, the rise in inequality and fall in the labour share of income. However, some have argued that market concentration and rising markups are a natural side effect of the rise of global technology giants (and their increased global reach) and that such developments are beneficial for growth, as they could spur investment and innovation. While there is already a well developed debate in the United States we have, however, far less information about the degree and evolution of market power and competitive intensity in the euro area.5 This Discussion Paper aims to contribute to our understanding by means of a comprehensive approach which considers trends in macro and micro data based firm markups, firm concentration and economic dynamics in the four largest euro area countries. In this context, moreover, it is important to note that shifts in market structure matter to the central-banking community (as opposed to being solely a matter for competition authorities). For example, the degree of imperfect competition can affect the pass-through of costs to prices (Goldberg & Hellerstein 2013); the recent literature on the 'flattening' of the Phillips curve could be rationalized in this manner. On the real side, market power can impact (note, leaving aside precise statements of causality) key output variables: investment, TFP potential growth and output gaps, labour share6 (see the discussions in Aghion et al. (2005), De Loecker & Eeckhout (2017), Baqaee & Farhi (2018), Gutierrez & Philippon (2018), Hall (2018)). Market structure can also impact (again, leaving aside causality statements) the propagation of shocks, and thus economic volatility. For example in most developed countries, firm size distribution is highly skewed and fat-tailed. Given this, shocks to large (or deeply 'networked') firms have the potential to account for a large share of aggre- 4 Strictly speaking, it not necessarily required to identify variables costs as such but at least one factor free of adjustment costs. 5 Although see Gutierrez & Philippon (2017), Weche&Wambach (2018), Deutsche Bundesbank (2017). 6 Under some parametric assumptions (primarily Cobb Douglas) the markup is the inverse of the labour share, see e.g. Gali & Gertler (1999), McAdam & Willman (2004). ECB Working Paper Series No 2253 / March 2019 7 gate volatility (Gabaix 2011, Acemoglu et al. 2012). If one were to model the economy as being captured by a single representative firm, these dynamics would be obscured. Moreover, in terms of monetary policy instruments per se, some authors have argued that (historically) low nominal and real rates may potentially raise/reinforce market concentration trends and, in turn, may have reduced creative destruction (i.e., new innovative firms displacing laggards) among firms and widened inequality (Liu et al. 2018). These issues are far from settled. Accordingly, it is no surprise that issue of shifts in market structure has been the dominant topic in recent central bank fora - for example, the 2018 ECB Forum on Central Banking in Sintra (see Hartmann & McAdam (2018)), as well as the 2018 Jackson Hole symposium.7 Overall our analysis shows that in (a perhaps surprising) contrast to trends reported in the US, competition intensity has been reasonably stable in the aggregate euro area (as gauged by that of its largest four economies: Germany, France, Italy and Spain8). This is a feature of both macro and micro data. On the former (which extends back to 1980) the aggregate euro area markup (or more correctly, the price-cost margin) seems to have varied around a value of 15% but has declined marginally since the late 1990s/early 2000s. This has been driven largely by developments in Manufacturing, and potentially the impact of deeper trade and monetary integration in the euro area. The micro firm data (which albeit covers the shorter sample (of 2006-2015) largely confirms this picture. Markups tends to be lower and somewhat more volatile in the Manufacturing sector (this is also confirmed at the individual country level). This is not to say that there are not industries and firms within the euro area that have high (and rising) markups but only that such firms are not those with particularly high market shares. Thus the De Loecker & Eeckhout (2017) explanation - that it has been a change within industry and the increase of markup of the firms with the highest markups already - appears not to hold in the euro area. In terms of concentration ratios (for which we can naturally only have recourse to micro data), we find that, in the euro area, it has remained broadly flat in recent years, both at the aggregate and national level. Moreover, we find that concentration is higher at the country level than at the single market aggregate level (Italy appears to be least concentrated, while Germany the most) .9 The Manufacturing sector is on average some- 7 On both these symposia, see, respectively, https://www.ecb.europa.eu/pub/conferences/hta and https://www.kansascityfed.org/publications/research/escp/symposiums/escp-2018. 8 In our analysis of business dynamism later we draw some comparisons for other European countries given the availability of the data. 9 This statement must be taken with some caution though, since levels comparisons across countries is sensitive to differences in data availability, quality and coverage. ECB Working Paper Series No 2253 / March 2019 8 what more concentrated (relative to the Total or Overall Economy).10 Over time, concentration has been broadly flat in most countries, albeit declining slightly in Germany and increasing slightly in Spain. Our final dimension of market power is economic dynamism (i.e., the birth and death rate of new establishments and jobs). In this respect, we found it fruitful to make a detailed comparison with the US. The US economy has traditionally been measured as more dynamic than the euro area (and indeed remains so over our sample) but recently changing market structures have led to drops in dynamism (mostly so in the labour market), drops not witnessed in the euro area. A possible explanation for such declines appears to lie in the high tech sectors. Accordingly, we examine the implication for high tech usage in euro area Manufacturing, and its relation to concentration and markups. The paper is organized as follows. After reviewing some simple definitions of variables and concepts used in our analysis, Section 3 presents the relationship of our themes to the general literature. Section 4 then discusses the concept of 'relevant market' (with some relevant technical details introduced). This is the geographical unit over which we judge the boundaries of market competition. We define two concepts in that regard: the aggregation of sectors to a euro area level within and across countries (dubbed, respectively, the Country Aggregate and the Single Market). Section 5 discusses the data used, encompassing both macro and micro sources. Section 6 is our main empirical section, and covers the calculation of concentration and markup measures in the euro area. Section 7 looks specifically at economic dynamism and draws some comparisons with the US. The next section considers the macroeconomic and policy implications of our empirical findings, with special emphasis on the interaction between concentration and markups conditional on uptake of high technology practices. Section 9 summarizes the findings and, finally, Section 10 raises some discussion points around our analysis. 2 Market Power: Some Basic Definitions To understand the evolution of market power in euro area firms we focus in our analysis on three dimensions: market concentration, markups and economic dynamics. To obtain a comprehensive picture, we rely on micro firm level as well as macro sectoral data. Limitations to the data quality and availability (in particular for the micro data) imply that we focus our analysis on the four largest euro area countries, namely Germany (DE), France (FR), Italy (IT) and Spain (ES). This nevertheless should allow us to obtain a rather comprehensive picture, since these four countries combined represent almost 80% of euro area GDP. A detailed description of the data sources and transformations to the data are explained in Appendix A. 10Note, differences in the levels across countries may be driven by data coverage, so they should be interpreted cautiously Analysis based on trends is more robust. ECB Working Paper Series No 2253 / March 2019 9 2.1 Measuring market concentration Market concentration measures the extent to which market shares are captured by a reduced set of firms. As noted above it is often taken as a proxy for competitive intensity. There exists a number of approaches to measure market concentration. The simplest is to compute the concentration ratio, {CRq), which express the market share {MS) of the qth iargest firms in a market: CR>qit = JTMSlt (1) i=i This metric is bounded in the unit interval, where q is typically set to values such as 4,10 and/or 50. Here we use q = 4, and thus the CRA denotes the combined market shares of the four largest firms. In turn, MSf^ is the market share of firm i, in year t and industry 5: sales?+ MSslt = —s-^— (2) E«=i salestt where Nf is the number of firms in industry/ sector s and year t. Indicator (1) considers exclusively the relevance of the top q firms and disregards the distribution of market shares of a given industry. The concentration ratio captures the ability to collude (as the number of firms in an industry falls, collusion is expected to increase). Note, to meaningfully interpret the CRq measure, one first needs to determine the relevant market, i.e. which firms and products to include when calculating the market shares. We shall discuss these issues further in Section 4. Moreover, concentration ratios such as a CRA inevitably do not distinguish between markets in which there are only five firms and those where there is a long tail of firms with smaller market shares. The Herfindahl-Hirschman index {HHI) solves this problem by calculating the square of the market share of each firm in the market, and summing the resulting numbers: Nl HHIts = J2MSlt2 (3) The HHI index ranges from close to 0 under perfect competition to 10,000 in monopoly (i.e., 100% market share). When there are n equal-sized firms HHI equals 1/n. The empirical literature defines HHI < 1000 as the threshold for low levels of concentration and HHI > 1800 as highly concentrated markets. One advantage of the HHI is that it does not only take into account the equality of market shares across firms but also the number of firms in the industry. Accordingly, we consider both CR4 and HHI measures in our analysis (albeit concentrating on the former in the main body of our text). ECB Working Paper Series No 2253 / March 2019 10 2.2 Markup definition The market power of a firm relates to its ability to sustain prices above marginal costs. The markup ratio measures the gap between the price and the marginal cost and it is defined as follows: where Pijt and MCijt are the price and marginal cost, respectively, for a given firm i in year t. Under perfect competition, it equals one as prices match marginal costs. The degree of market power is increasing in the gap between prices and marginal costs. The markup ratio is closely related to the Lerner index also known as the price-cost margin {PC Mi t). It is defined as follows: PC Mi t = l--^, where the PC Mi t = Pi*-MCi*. The markup at industry level 5 corresponds to a weighted mean of firm-level markups according to the corresponding market shares as follows: where, as before, MSf^ is the market share of firm i, in year t and industry s. We shall discuss aggregation issues in more detail in Section 4. The main problem when computing markups is that prices are generally not available and marginal costs are unobservable. To overcome these shortcomings, the empirical literature has developed a variety of approaches. In line with these, in our analysis we assume constant returns-to-scale, that capital is a fixed cost and, consequently, that average costs are a suitable proxy for marginal costs. What constitutes "marginal costs" for the firm is by no means settled, and can have an impact on the level and dynamics of the markup measures (e.g., Traina 2018). Moreover, data availability and comparability across countries and sectors can make precise calculations difficult.11 2.3 Economic Dynamism Market economies are characterised by a continuous reallocation of resources across firms and sectors. Myriads of jobs are destroyed and created every year, new firms are born, old ones die, and continuing ones grow or downsize, with gross flows of workers, jobs, and firms dwarfing net flows. According to canonical models of firm dynamics (Hopenhayn 1992), such reallocation of resources is critical for productivity growth. Resources (capital and labour) are expected to flow from less to more productive firms. This raises aggregate productivity directly, as resources move to more productive uses, but also indirectly, as the in- 11 Note, given some data constraints on the macro side, and the short time span of the micro data side, we chose not to implement the recent De Loecker & Warzynski (2012) markup methodology. (5) i=l ECB Working Paper Series No 2253 / March 2019 11 creased availability of resources allows these firms to expand further. Reallocation also enhances the productivity contribution from the entry of new firms and the exit of weak incumbents. The contribution of young firms is especially important: young firms enter markets in search of new opportunities, introduce new products and innovations, and are an important source of employment growth (Bartelsman et al. 2000). A host of inefficiencies and rigidities can hinder entry and reallocation. High barriers to entry that protect the rents of incumbents, an unfriendly business environment in the form of large administrative costs, insufficient credit and an absence of specialised finance for new ventures. Rigidities in the exit margin are also important. Weak firms may inefficiently stay in the market through insolvency frameworks that prevent restructuring or resolution, weak banks that want to avoid recognising losses, or political pressure. This congests healthy incumbent firms, and can impair productivity growth (Adalet Mc-Gowan et al. 2018, Andrews & Petroulakis 2017). This economic dynamism is typically captured by the measures of so-called firm 'churn': Entering Firms Birth Rate =—-^—-x 100 (6) Active Firms ^ , „ Exiting Firms , „ Death Rate =—-^—- x 100 (7) Active Firms Churn =Birth Rate + Death Rate (8) In the De Loecker and Eeckhout framework, under certain conditions, rising markups can explain the concurrent decline in the rate of labour reallocation in the US over the same time. Rising concentration and depressed levels of economic dynamism are intuitively related. Barriers to entry mechanically translate into higher market power for incumbents. Conversely, firms with high market power may use it to deter entry, through the threat of a price war or privileged access to partner firms, or lobby for the establishment of occupational licenses. Power in product markets may directly imply power in labour markets (where firms can pay wages below marginal product), which may be further entrenched by the enforcement of non-competing clauses or no-poaching agreements (Ashenfelter & Krueger 2017). As regards job reallocation, relying on the job-finding and employment-separation rates (the unemployment-to-employment and employment-to-unemployment transition rates), we follow the Shimer (2012a) to estimate these from aggregate data. Let the unemployment rate ut evolve as ^ = st{\ - ut) - ftut, (9) at where st is the monthly rate of inflow into unemployment (or the separation rate) and ECB Working Paper Series No 2253 / March 2019 12 ft is the monthly outflow rate from unemployment (or the finding rate). Letting the stock of unemployed be given by Ut, the stock of unemployed for less than 1 month by Uf1, and the probability of exiting from unemployment within 1 month by Ff1, then the change in the stock of unemployed within 1 month is given by: ut+1 -ut = uf+\ - utF{- . (10) Similarly the separation rate can be obtained by solving (9) forward to obtain (using the definition /<* = -ln(l - Ft)) Ut+i = 1-t-;-LJ±1(Ut + Et) + e-^+s^Ut, (11) ft+i + st+i where Et is the stock of the employed. For the euro area, since monthly inflow and outflow rates are too low to be captured by survey data, we use the adaptation of this method by Elsby, Hobijn & §ahin (2013), and optimally combine inflow and outflow rates for 1,3, 6, and 12 months. The finding rate is the hazard rate associated with the probability that an unemployed individual will find a job, and the separation rate is similarly related to the probability that an employed individual will lose her job. These probabilities are not identical to job creation and destruction. A worker may lose her job (increase in the separation rate) without an increase in job destruction if the job is filled immediately. If the job is filled with a worker coming out of unemployment the job finding rate will increase, but not if the new worker switches immediately from another job. There are disagreements as to whether the finding and exit rates or the destruction and creation rates are more important over the business cycle, but it seems rather innocuous to consider the trend behaviour of job-finding and job-exit rates as sufficient statistics for the trend of job reallocation. While it is well-known that the US labour market is much more dynamic than any European labour market, with exit and entry rates in the US dwarfing those in Europe, here we are concerned with the evolution of dynamism over the past two decades rather than its actual level. 3 Relationship to the Literature Understanding the extent of firm market power is of relevance in many branches of economics. Industrial organization economists and competition authorities have a long history of studying firm market power. Traditionally however it attracted far less attention among macroeconomists, who only started studying markup behaviour in the mid-1980s and even then, they were more interested in analyzing the cyclical rather than trend behavior of markups. This ECB Working Paper Series No 2253 / March 2019 13 can in part be explained by the fact that macroeconomic models are generally founded on Kaldor's stylized facts, such as a constant labour share, constant profits and a constant capital-to-output ratio. The models thus implicitly assume no trend changes in firm market power. Only recently, the analysis of trend developments in market power has entered the field of macroeconomics in response to a number of studies which found that there may be a potential sustained rise in market power. The topic was most prominently brought to the fore in recent years by De Loecker & Eeckhout (2017). They suggested that the average markup for US firms has risen sharply over the past three decades. More specifically, they find that the increase occurred across industries but was mostly concentrated within high markup firms (i.e. those firms that had a high markup at the beginning of the sample witnessed the biggest rise in markups).12 De Loecker & Eeckhout (2017) further link these developments to a number of secular macro trends, such as the decrease in labour and capital share, the decline in low skilled wages, the decline in labour flows, labour force participation and migration rates and the slowdown in aggregate output. In addition, Eggertsson, Robbins & Wold (2018) also find that a rise in pure profits or market power could be driving some of the recently observed macroeconomic trends, including the decline in both the capital and labour share and a rise in inequality (Edmond et al. 2018). A further nuance to this debate concerns the rise of common ownership, whereby, through the rise of passive asset management, the largest asset management institutions in the United States (such as BlackRock, Vanguard, State Street) collectively own large shares in natural competitors across a wide range of industries. Taking common ownership into account can vastly increase measures of concentration (Azar et al. 2018) and have important consequences. When shareholders own shares in different competitors, they may be more reluctant to engage in competitive pricing, innovation, investment or any other activity that may reduce the profits of commonly owned competitors. Externalities and spillovers may be sufficiently complex that common ownership raises R&D (Lopez & Vives 2019) and common ownership across many sectors may raise aggregate output (Azar & Vives 2018). Overall, however, under reasonable calibrations, common ownership has an overall negative effect on the economy and has been shown to be able to explain the secular stagnation hypothesis (low output growth, declining labour share) (Azar & Vives 2019). There have been also a number of other studies, using different approaches and methodologies, that point towards a rise in market power of US firms. For instance, Hall (2018) and Nekarda & Ramey (2013) also find, in this case using macro data, support for the conclusion that the markup has risen for US firms in recent decades. Moreover, tak- 12 As De Loecker & Eeckhout (2017) state: "The decomposition shows that since the 1980s, the change in markup is mainly driven by the change within industry There is some change in the composition between industries, but that is relatively minor compared to the within industry change. The change due to reallocation, the joint effect, is mostly small." (pl3). ECB Working Paper Series No 2253 / March 2019 14 ing a different angle, a number of studies also show that concentration ratios have been rising (see overview Table 1) and Barkai (2016) found that the decrease in labour share of value added is not due to an increase in the capital share but rather by an increase in the profit share, which went from 2% of GDP in 1984 to 16% in 2014. However, whereas there is by now broad based agreement that firm markups and concentration ratios have increased in the United States, there is far less agreement on the magnitude. Indeed, markup estimates range widely across studies, with Traina (2018) finding that the increase in markups between 1980-2016 is within historical ranges, while De Loecker & Eeckhout (2017) at the other extreme find that markups have risen from 18% in 1980 to 67% in 2014. There is even less agreement on the drivers of this potential increase in market power. One less benign explanation is that changes to US merger policies have made it easier for firms to build, protect and extend positions of market power through anticompetitive mergers and that this has had a bigger impact on increasing market power than it did in delivering efficiencies (see for instance Peltzman (2014) and Bloningen & Pierce (2016)). Another possibility is that firms have been successful in lobbying and rent-seeking for regulatory protection. For instance, Bessen (2017) finds that regulation and campaign spending are responsible for an increase in markup of 1-2 percent. Zin-gales (2017) stressed that while lobbying and rent seeking have always existed, this has worsened recently through a vicious circle of market concentration and political power. More concretely, as firms have recently gained market power, their capacity to exert political pressure to protect and increase their market power has also risen. However, other authors have found that the documented rise in market power may reflect much more (potentially) 'positive' economic developments as firms earned it thanks to repeated successes in innovating and distinguishing themselves from their rivals and/or cutting costs and improving their productivity. Autor et al. (2017a) describe this as the 'superstar' firm hypothesis. Such a development may result in an increase in markups, profit and concentration that is also accompanied by lower costs, higher product varieties and higher productivity. Digitalization and globalization may have recently facilitated such developments. As a potential confirmation of this view, Calligaris et al. (2018fo) find that markups are higher in digitally intensive sectors. Along similar lines, Crouzet & Eberly (2018) suggest that intangible investment has been an important driver behind the recent rise in markups and firm concentration in some US sectors. While the debate and analysis in the United States is already at a rather advanced stage, our understanding of these trends at the euro area and global level is much more limited. In part, this can be explained by data limitations and cross-country comparability issues. Nevertheless, there is also here a nascent literature developing. An overview of these studies is presented in Table 2. As the table shows, no consistent message arises so far on the evolution of market power at the euro area or global level. While a number ECB Working Paper Series No 2253 / March 2019 15 of studies indicate that at European (and even at global) level we are witnessing similar trend developments as in the US, other studies do not observe such developments (and in some cases, they even document a rise in competition). In this regard, Gutierrez & Philippon (2018) find that while until the 1990s, US markets were more competitive than the European markets, the situation has reversed, with European markets having lower concentration, lower excess profits and lower regulatory barriers to entry. The authors attribute this change, inter alia, to a delegation of anti-trust enforcement to the euro area level. 4 Aggregation and "Relevant Markets" In Section 2, we explained our three main indicators of market power. However, making sense of such indicators requires us to integrate additional issues of geographical coverage and market size. Simply calculating, for instance, an aggregated markup without controlling for the size of the relevant firms or economic size of the interacting markups gives a distorted view. Accordingly, in this section we define some logical and algebraic boundaries to our metrics. Consider a concrete example - say the Tobacco industry (which sells a fairly homogenous internationally-trade product), in one country, say France. If there is only one French tobacco Manufacturer, we might conclude that this firm has a monopoly, warranting an examination by the relevant competition authorities. However citizens in France may also use British or German tobacco products. Indeed, the French Tobacco Manufacturer may - when all such sellers are considered - enjoy a very limited market share. These considerations naturally prompt some discussion of how and where we define the market and how we aggregate sectors and countries. 4.1 Relevant Markets A comprehensive definition of the relevant market takes into account the degree of product substitution, transportation costs and the geographic location of producers and consumers. Given the difficulty in defining relevant markets, we follow much of the empirical literature which relies on an economic activity classification such as the NACE. In this context, we use 2 digit level as a market segmentation criterion. The underlying assumption is that firms sell one good and serve one industry defined at 2 digit in NACE Rev.2. Naturally, the presence of multi-product firms is likely to be a source of bias, especially if a firm sells products that are not close substitutes. Over the years, the European Union has taken several steps to increase economic integration. Notwithstanding, there is evidence that there are still barriers to entry and exit related for instance to institutional frameworks that have prevented a complete in- ECB Working Paper Series No 2253 / March 2019 16 tegration in particular in industries less exposed to international trade. In this context, we consider two operational concepts: 1. Partial Integration: Country Aggregation (CA) In this case, the assumption is that each firm competes with firms that sell goods in the same industry and in the same country. Hence market shares are computed in a given industry and year for a given country in the Single Market. Thus, the aggregation of industries yields a country result for DE, FR, ES and IT. To obtain a country aggregate (as opposed to a Single-Market aggregate discussed below), we need to further aggregate countries into a euro area dimension. It corresponds to a country aggregate (CA) computed as a weighted mean of country level results as follows: lfA = J2wtcx lfM'c (12) s where I™M'c is the indicator of interest {pfM, EElfM and CR^tM) computed at country level in year t as a weighted mean across industries. are country weights based on output using the EU-KLEMS dataset. Since this first scenario maybe a restrictive hypothesis in some industries, we consider an alternative scenario, which we call the Single Market. 2. 'Full' Integration: Single Market (SM) Each firm in this scenario competes with European counterparts in the same industry. At this level, one important challenge is that this set of firms operating in the Single Market is not entirely observed. There are important constraints on data collection which translate into lack of representativeness and comparability on several variables. Here we consider DE, ES, FR and IT as the relevant set of countries. S Oil Recall the definition of market share of firm i, in year t and sector s: MSft = —^—-—, EiJi salest,t where, as before, N* is the number of firms in industry s and year t. Under the first scenario, market shares are country specific and iV/ includes exclusively the set of resident firms. On the Single Market case (SM), N£ includes all European firms (DE, IT, FR and ES) in industry s and year t. Naturally, and by definition, market shares are lower under the SM scenario compared to the aggregation of country results.13 13 Note that imports in a given industry (beyond the European firms) are disregarded and that sales consider not only domestic revenues but also exports. ECB Working Paper Series No 2253 / March 2019 17 4.2 Aggregation Within these two scenarios - the Single Market (case) and the country specific results -We consider several aggregation strategies as follows: 4.2.1 CRq and HHI - Weighted mean To obtain figures for the aggregate economy we consider a weighted mean (WM) as follows: IWM = Y^W°xIst (13) s where // is HHIf or CR%t which are measures computed at industry level 5 and year t. Wts are industry weights based on output using EU-KLEMS. We rely on this last source to ensure representativeness. - Un-weighted mean To ensure that the dynamics is not driven exclusively by changes in weights over time, we consider also the un-weighted mean (unWM). junWM = I* (14) Median In addition, we also consider the median across industries for a given year for the Ci?4 and the HHI as follows: jMedian = Median (15) 4.2.2 Markup - Weighted mean To obtain figures for the aggregate economy, we consider a weighted mean as follows: flWM = J2wtsx^t (16) s where /if is the markup computed at industry level 5 and year t. Wts are industry weights based on output using EU-KLEMS. - Moments. Median and Upper Decile from the firm-level distribution (respectively, the 50th and 90th percentile). In order to discuss the role of the firms in the top of the ECB Working Paper Series No 2253 / March 2019 18 distribution, we consider two moments in the firm-level distribution for a given industry and aggregate these moments using industry weights. ^ = £V/x ^' (17) s s - The mark ups of the largest firms (i.e., specifically those identified in the CR4 index): The top of the markup distribution is, according to recent evidence, driving aggregate markups in the US: sectoral shares remained broadly stable and all variation seems to be within sector particularly by the top of the distribution. While the top of the markup distribution does not necessarily comprise the same set of firms, these are also not necessarily large firms. To discuss this issue we compare the following two indicators: Indicator 1: The Mark up of the 4 largest firms 4 s,L s,SM /, (-, m /V =2_^Vt /4 (19) where i include the four largest firms in a given sector s (included C7?4). As above, sectors are aggregated into a SM result as follows: //f M'L = Y,s K,L x w^'sm, where w*,sm is the weight of a given sector s year t based on EU-KLEMS data (based on the data for the 4 countries) and: Indicator 2: The Markup of the Total Economy jjWm,sm = Yjwtsx (4>SM (20) s where /if is the markup computed at industry level 5 and year t (computed as a weighted mean between market shares in SM and firm-level markups). wts are industry weights based on output using EU-KLEMS (using data for the 4 countries). 5 Data We now briefly overview the data sources and treatment, on the macro and micro side. Appendix A describes the data in greater detail as well as various trade offs among the different data sets and the treatment and 'cleaning' that we applied. ECB Working Paper Series No 2253 / March 2019 19 5.1 Macro Data We use macro data from the EU-KLEMS database (September 2017 Statistical Release), which provides information for DE, FR, IT, ES, a number of other European countries and the United States. For some variables, countries, and sectors, the series are available on a long time span, as early as 1970; however, a valid common sample across the selected countries only covers the period 1995-2015. We will hence focus on this specific period for the cross-country analyses. We examine six macro-sectors defined at the 1-digit level and follow the NACE Rev.2 classification. The macro-sectors considered are: Manufacturing (NACE 2 category C), Water, Electricity and Gas (NACE 2 category D-E), Construction (NACE 2 category F), Wholesale and Retail Trade (NACE 2 category G), Transportation (NACE 2 category H), Non-financial Services (NACE 2 categories I, L, and M-N). 5.2 Firm-Level Micro Data We rely on two sources of data for the analysis at the firm-level: the Orbis database from Bureau Van Dijk; and iBACH data. iBACH is our main source but it only includes information for France (FR) and Italy (IT). Other countries, Germany (DE) and Spain (ES) are collected through Orbis. Regarding Orbis-Europe, we use a customized version requested by the ECB with no attrition bias which is imposed when collecting data through online access. However, some features of the firm such as location, sectoral classification, legal form, year of incorporation (entry), status of the company (active/liquidation/merger-acquisition) and quoted/unquoted indicator are time invariant and relate to the last year. There is information on Orbis at this level (merging vintage data) however this is not currently available at the ECB. There is a 2 year reporting lag, on average, from Orbis and 2015 is the last available year. The iBACH firm-level dataset is gathered through national central banks (NCBs) in the euro area in joint work with ECB Directorate General Statistics. Substantial effort is placed on having variables that are comparable across countries. The source of this data is mainly administrative though not entirely homogeneous across countries. It is an alternative to Orbis since it overcomes their main problems but the only countries available are FR, IT, PT (Portugal), BL (Belgium) and ES (and some other, mainly small, countries such as Slovakia). The financial sector is not part of iBACH dataset and for this reason it is excluded from the analysis. ECB Working Paper Series No 2253 / March 2019 20 6 Evidence of the evolution of market power of euro area firms 6.1 Concentration Measures Figure 1 shows the evolution of the CR4 measure over our micro sample, both for the Total Economy and for the Manufacturing sector. The main reason to isolate Manufacturing is that measurement error is likely to be lower and at the same time integration across tradable goods in the euro area is expected to be higher. Moreover, in our later analysis we isolate margins (such as technological take up) that are only available at the Manufacturing level. Consistent with our earlier discussion, we observe that by definition the Country Aggregate concentration ratio will always strictly exceed that of the Single Market indicator (although this need not hold for the markup measure). We see that the top 4 firms in the Total Economy account for between 10% and 22% of total market shares (depending on whether you use the Single Market or country-aggregate measure). Manufacturing has relatively higher concentration levels (around 14 — 30%). This is hardly surprising since Manufacturing, when comparing to the Total Economy, typically involves higher fixed costs and often more emphasis on scale economies which tends to provide a bound on the number of entrants. Interestingly, as we shall see below, Manufacturing tends to have lower markups than the Total Economy for equivalent reasons (e.g., traded nature of goods produced). Notwithstanding, we find that in both polar cases (i.e., Country Aggregate, and Single Market) the dynamics of concentration are essentially flat over the last 10 years both for the Total Economy and the Manufacturing sector. There was though - after the volatility of the financial crisis - some minor general increases in the concentration ratios, presumably reflecting the exit of some producers and firm amalgamations. Naturally, this could be a rather short time frame to evaluate structural changes, although De Loecker & Eeckhout (2017) found much of the rise of market power for the US economy occurring over a not too dis-similar time frame (albeit for those authors, shift were considered in terms of markups). Overall, thus, the results suggest that market concentration in the euro area has remained broadly flat since 2006, both at the Single Market and national (Country Aggregate) level. As such, these results confirm the conclusions in the existing literature (see Table 2). Looking at the countries separately (see Figures 2 and 3), we find that the Manufacturing sector is on average somewhat more concentrated and also that concentration is higher at the country level than at the single market aggregate level (in line with Gutierrez & Philippon 2018). Across countries meanwhile we find that Italy appears to be least concentrated, while Germany the most. Over time, concentration has been broadly flat in most countries, albeit declining somewhat in Germany and increasing ECB Working Paper Series No 2253 / March 2019 21 slightly in Spain. 6.2 Markup Measures We now turn our attention to another indicator of market power, namely firms' markup. In this respect, unlike the concentration measures for which we can only rely on micro data, we can exploit both long-dated macro data and micro data. This is especially useful since much of the debate over the markup has tended to focus on whether recent decades have seen a change in its trend. Figure 4 shows that average markup for the economy as a whole - based on macro sectoral data - has remained broadly stable over the period 1978-2015 at a mean of around 13% (thus implying the prices are on average 13% above marginal costs). There has been a mild reduction (or perhaps stabilization) of the markup trend from the late 1990s/early 2000s driven potentially by the gains in intra-EU competition which might be expected from the start of the Single Market in Goods and Services in 1993 and the start of the monetary union in 1999. This (downward) trend is also apparent to a greater degree in Manufacturing, with the average markup trending noticeably particularly from the mid to late 1990s with an overall mean of around 5%. This is consistent with our prior that margins in Manufacturing are smaller given the tradeable and sub-stitutable nature of its products and the high costs (including presumably high variable costs) that may be involved in production. Figure 5, moreover, shows that this trend is quite uniform across the constituent countries. These results contrast with US developments. As shown in the figure (and widely documented in the literature, recall Section 3), average markups have been on a upward trend in the US.14 This is observable in both the Manufacturing sector and the Total Economy, but has been most pronounced in the former. Concretely, using sectoral EU-KLEMS data, the average markup in the US is estimated to have increased by 9% and 12% in the Total Economy and Manufacturing, respectively. To pursue these issues more fully, we can shift our attention to our micro data sources. Figure 6 shows the markup in our four euro area countries from 2006 (for both Total Economy and Manufacturing) given the variety of definitions described in Section 4. It is worth noting at the outset that the markup we find on the micro data (from 2006 onwards) is in the ballpark of the macro markup of that period (around 10% for the Total economy, and under 10% for Manufacturing) and follows a similar dynamic.15 Firm level data also allows to consider the full distribution of markups. For the US, 14 Note, that we do not replicate the dramatic evolution of De Loecker & Eeckhout (2017) for the US markups - given that we do not use their (CompuStat) database. We do however replicate qualitatively their path. 15 Although of course given what is known in micro to macro aggregation there is no necessity that the two would necessarily yield a similar picture. ECB Working Paper Series No 2253 / March 2019 22 firm level data have shown that the rise in markups has been most pronounced at the top end of the distribution (see for instance De Loecker & Eeckhout 2017 and Diez et al. 2018). The upper (orange) dashed lines (in both panels) reveal there are firms among our sample who do enjoy relatively high markups (around 20 - 30%) and (at least for the Total Economy) exhibit a marginally rising path. The question remains of who these firms are; are they economically meaningful in size? This is important, since De Loecker & Eeckhout (2017) argued that the rise in the aggregate markup is driven by the increasing sectoral share of firms with a pre-existing 'high markup. In other words, the top of the markup distribution is driving the aggregate markup. Since sectoral shares remained broadly stable, all variation seems to be within sector, particularly at the top of the distribution.16 However, as Figure 7 reveals, this is not so for the euro area. Here we take the previous mean for the markup (the previous blue line in Figure 6) and then restrict our attention to the markups associated to the CRA set of firms (the brown line). As can be seen there is no major difference between them (and no statistical significance). 6.3 Is there a relationship between markups and concentration? So far we have looked at markups and concentration in isolation. Interestingly, the link between them - both empirically and in theory - is by no means clear cut, Tirole (1988). There may be firms with 'high markups but which operate in a sector with many competitors (e.g., both domestic and non domestic). Alternatively there may be firms with limited markups but who are dominant in their industry (as judged by their market shares). This begs the question of why there should be such differences. One explanation may rest of the afore-mentioned Shumpetarian framework and the potential con-testability of markets. Another is firms' technological characteristics. We examine these issues in later sections. Figure 8 combines the evidence on concentration and markup evolution at the NACE rev. 2 level. It shows the evolution of markups in low (blue) versus highly (red) concentrated sectors (as reflected in their CR4 rating).17 If outcomes are unchanged, then the dots (all of them) will be clustered on the diagonal. That they mostly are, confirms that markups (at least by sector) are reasonably stable (although remember that this is a short sample, so we might expect such stability). Moreover, as regards the markup changes in low versus high concentrated sectors, no clear pattern emerges, i.e. markup changes were not concentrated in either the low or high concentrated sectors. That said, there is a clustering of dots around the low markup low concentration region. Furthermore, there are some interesting and illustra- 16 For an overview of sectoral shares in the euro area and the US see Figure B.3 in the appendix. 17 By high and low we mean above and below sample median. ECB Working Paper Series No 2253 / March 2019 23 tive cases to examine. For instance, Air Transport is highly concentrated (as you would expect of an industry with huge fixed costs and operating in a high regulatory environment) but its weighted markups are fairly low. Whereas Telecom (also an industry with high fixed costs and relatively high barriers to entry) is also highly concentrated but enjoys a quite substantial markup. Although note that markup in Telecoms has been going down - reflecting deregulation in the industry and increasing competition from other media platforms. At the other end we have Real Estate and Rental which are not especially concentrated but they do enjoy an above-average markup. This may reflect that firms in this sector compete in non price terms, or, being mostly local services, are not exposed to international competition. Figure 9 repeats the earlier figure but wherein the size of the bubbles represent the respective share of the sectoral turnover over total sales. 6.4 The Case of 'Superstar' firms Autor et al. (2017a) and Autor et al. (2017fo) argue that some firms and industries are increasingly characterized by a winner-takes-all effect - i.e., attaining large market shares from higher productivity and more demanded product ranges but with a relatively small workforce (popular examples being Facebook and Google). They describe this phenomenon as the superstar firm hypothesis. The emergence of such firms could be related to: i) the diffusion of new competitive platforms (e.g., easier price/quality comparisons on the Internet) ii) the proliferation of information-intensive goods that have high fixed and low marginal costs (e.g., software platforms, cloud computing, and online services), iii) rising international integration of product markets.18 Such developments may result in an increase in markups, profit and concentration that is also accompanied by lower costs, higher product varieties and productivity. This dynamic, moreover, may be self reinforcing. Figure 10, taken from Autor et al. (2017fo), plots the average sales- and employment-based CR4 and CR20 measures of concentration across four-digit industries for each of the six major US sectors. We see an upward trend over time - according to all measures, industries have become more concentrated on average, stronger when measuring concentration is measured in sales rather than employment. The precise welfare implications of such 'superstar firms' is far from clear, though. On one hand, their productivity can potentially raise general productivity and release resources for other sectors (and thus for the development on new industries and new products). On the other hand, they may create a polarized labour market (into high and low skill, and 'good' and 'bad' 18 As a potential confirmation of this view, Calligaris et al. (20 f 8b) find that markups are higher in digitally intensive sectors. Along similar lines, Crouzet & Eberly (2018) suggest that intangible investment has been an important driver behind the recent rise in markups and firm concentration in some US sectors. ECB Working Paper Series No 2253 / March 2019 24 jobs) with resulting (likely negative) effects on the overall labour income share.19 For the euro area, however, we find little evidence that such firms are emerging over our sample period, see Figure 11 and Figure 12. Here we tag firms in their Ci?4 forms, then compute the share of employment in the sector and aggregate up using country weights based on employment. We do not observe that the large firms are decoupling their sales and employment trends, except perhaps for 'Other Services'.20 At the same time, our micro data frame may be rather short to look at structural dynamics such as the Superstar phenomenon. 7 Measuring economic dynamism In this section, we examine the evolution of dynamism in the euro area and the US, focusing on job reallocation. The US comparison is particularly revealing since (i) we witness marked differences (in both trend and level) relative to the euro area and (ii) technology uptake seems to be a key underlying reason (which is helpful also to discuss in the European context). As job reallocation data require administrative datasets on the job flows across firms, which are not readily available across the euro area, we consider the job finding and separation rates, the probability of an unemployed worker to find a job and the probability of an employed worker to become unemployed, respectively. It should be noted that the rich US literature on dynamism also considers measures of economic dynamism, typically firm birth and death rates. The complication here is that data on economic dynamism for European member states are plagued by with severe asymmetries in coverage, different conventions on business types across countries, and different definitions of firm dynamics than the US. See Appendix C for details. Falling market dynamism has been well-established for the US. De Loecker and Eeck-hout document an increase in the volume and value of mergers and acquisitions. They also document an increase in the size of listed firms and a reduction in their number, starting in 2000, and interpret these two facts as an increase in the consolidation of corporate ownership, and hence market power. They also find that markups are positively related to firm size within sectors, as predicted by standard models of competition. Decker et al. (2016) show that until the early 2000s, the growth distribution of young firms was highly skewed, with the median young firm either disappearing or stalling, but with the right tail dynamic enough to carry the mean. Since then, this skewness has drastically diminished. In addition, Decker et al. (2018) show that lower dynamism is 19 This is a controversial area and beset by data issues. For instance, it is not clear that the literature is capturing hours worked (e.g., part-time workers) or trends in international out-sourcing of jobs and tasks. 20 'Other services' includes sectors 55-82 except Financial Activities: Accommodation and Food Service Activities, Information and Communication, Real Estate Activities, Professional, Scientific and Technical Activities and Administrative and Support Service Activities. ECB Working Paper Series No 2253 / March 2019 25 the result of lower responsiveness of firms to productivity shocks compared to previous decades, indicating a rise in frictions and distortions preventing firms from realising their potential. Figure 13 shows the evolution of the churn and birth rates for US establishments since 1980. The long-run secular decline in dynamism is evident, despite occasional bursts of activity, which are to some extent the result of growth in the high-tech sector, and the trend substantially slows down in the aftermath of the crisis. For Europe, we refer to Figure 14, which comes from the harmonized cross-country analysis of Criscuolo et al. (2014). While there is a downward trend in start-up rates across several countries, the pattern is not ubiquitous. For instance, in the UK, the Netherlands, Portugal, Belgium, Sweden and Finland, start-up rates were either steady or trending up before the crisis. The absence of data during the recovery is a limitation to a comprehensive analysis of this issue.21 The estimated finding and exit rates are shown in Figure 15 for the US over 2000ql-2017q4. There is an obvious cyclicality in the job-finding rate; it was very high in 2000, at the height of the dot-com bubble, and plunged to a little over 20% in 2010, with unemployment at almost 10%. While it has rebounded substantially, it is still below its pre-crisis peak, despite unemployment being lower at the end of the sample than its pre-crisis trough. Even the pre-crisis peak was much lower than its level in 2000. Indeed, unemployment in 2017q4 was 4.1% and the monthly finding rate 49%; in 1999q4, with unemployment also at 4.1%, the monthly finding rate was 75%. This secular decline in labour market dynamism becomes starker once we consider the trend behaviour of the job-separation rate. With the exception of a brief cyclical spike at the onset of the crisis, it has been on a clear secular decline since the beginning of the 2000-2017 period examined here. In fact, the decline started around 1980, which coincides well with the initial phase of the decline in dynamism. Figure 17 repeats this exercise for the euro area.22 Though the job-finding rate is an order of magnitude lower than the US, there does not seem to have been a particular change in the trend of labour market dynamics. The job-finding rate declined sharply in 2009, and then again in 2011 and 2012, in line with the cycle, but it has increased considerably with the recovery, to levels consistent with historical experience.23 For the separation rate, a similar picture emerges; it fell before the crisis, then exhibited twin peaks coinciding with the two stages of an increase in the unemployment rate, to fall 21 Note that the declining dynamism observed for Spain has been documented for a more recent period by Benito-Moral & Queiros (2018). 22 There is too little movement at monthly frequencies in the euro area, so we employ the method of Elsby Hobijn & §ahin (2013) and estimate transition rates at different durations and weight them optimally to calculate average rates. 23 The predicted value from a regression of the job-finding rate on unemployment is 7.25% for 2017q4, almost identical to actual value of 7.32%. ECB Working Paper Series No 2253 / March 2019 26 again with the current recovery. Indeed, the finding rate is well-captured by unemployment.24 Overall, the evidence suggests that the well-documented reduction in economic dynamism in the US does carry over to the euro area, at least not with the same intensity, and certainly not in the labour market. By most metrics, the US economy remains more dynamic than the euro area economy, but the question here is in terms of trends, not levels. While the euro area remains less dynamic than the US, it is not clear that it is particularly less dynamic than it was over the early 2000s. What could be behind the apparent divergence in dynamism between the euro area and the US after the mid-2000s? One possibility may be the differential role of the high tech sector in the two economies. In the US, a substantial part of the pre-crisis dynamism was driven by large reallocation in the high-tech sector, a particularly dynamic part of the economy, which has since become substantially more sclerotic, Decker et al. (2016). Once high tech is excluded, dynamism exhibits an even sharper decline and productivity gains since the early 1990s are primarily driven by consolidation in the retail sector, aided by ICT (Information and Communication Technology) innovations, and hence low dynamism. A simple way to measure the importance of the high-tech sector across countries is value-added share accruing to the ICT sector, defined in a harmonised way by the OECD.25 In 2011, the US had 7.1% of its total value-added from the ICT sector, compared to 5.1% for Germany and France, 4.9% for Italy, and 4.6% for Spain. See also Table 4 for some additional metrics on the IT divide between the euro area and the US. 8 The macroeconomic implications So far our evidence suggests that while in the United States firm market power has increased in recent years, it has remained broadly unchanged in the euro area. What are the macroeconomic implications of these findings for the euro area? How do these essentially micro phenomena aggregate up to macroeconomic variables relevant to policy makers, such as investment and TFP? Put simply, even if market power developments are flat, nonetheless their effect still imparts an effect on the economy. On the one hand, the conventional view holds that these developments are, from a welfare perspective, more favorable for the euro area. Having more competitive markets 24In Figure 17a, we show the standardised residuals from a regression of the finding rate on unemployment rate for the two regions. The difference is stark; the residuals for the US show a clear downward trend, from initially positive to negative. For the EA, in contrast, the residual consistently fluctuates around zero, indicating that the evolution of the finding rate is well-explained by the cycle. 25 This includes manufacturing of computer, electronic and optical products, telecommunications, computer programming and information service activities, software publishing. See https://data.oecd. org/ict/ict-value-added.htm ECB Working Paper Series No 2253 / March 2019 27 in the euro area would imply that firms invest and innovate more and therefore have lower costs and consumer prices (a point argued for instance by Gutierrez & Philippon 2018). However, on the other hand, it could also be argued that the euro area has missed out on the superstar firms, which enjoy some market power but also provide incentives to the firms to invest and to innovate. The answer to this is ex ante, not straightforward, as noted in the Introduction. To shed light on this matter, we investigate the interaction between our concentration ratios, investment, total factor productivity (TFP) and markup developments at the sectoral level in the next sections. 8.1 The interaction between concentration and investment We first focus on the relation between investment and market concentration over our data sample. We do so by estimating an equation that has the sectoral investment rate regressed on sectoral concentration ratios: IYs,t = as + at + p1CR4 s,t_i + l32CR24 ^ + es,t (21) where IY is the investment rate, CR4 is the concentration ratio (as proxied at sectoral level by the market share of the four largest firms), t denotes the year and s denotes sector. We include in our analysis 23 sectors at NACE 2 level. The equation also controls for sector (aj and time {at) fixed effects. The inclusion of these fixed effects allow us to measure the impact of concentration, after controlling for broader macroeconomic developments and sector-specific aspects. To test for the presence of non-linearities, we include a quadratic term for sectoral concentration: this allows us to verify whether the inverted U-shaped relation, as highlighted by Aghion et al. (2005), is also present in our data sample.26 The estimation results, reported in Table 3, indeed suggest a non-monotonic relation between investment and concentration. Higher concentration is initially associated with increasing investment, as indicated by the positive estimated coefficient ft. Beyond a certain threshold, however, increases in concentration become associated with lower investment, as indicated by the negative coefficient estimate for ft (it is negative for all industries). Figure 18 also illustrates this relation. Essentially, what we see is a heavy cluster of low Ci?4-low I/Y firms. These are sectors which are either highly labour intensive 26 Note that Aghion et al. (2005) conjecture that there is an inverted U-shaped relation between the degree of competition on the one hand and innovative activity on the other hand. Empirically, the authors document the relationship between the price cost margin on the one hand and the number of patents on the other hand. In our Discussion Paper instead, we proxy the degree of competition by the sectoral concentration ratios and innovative activity by the investment rate, with the latter being the best available proxy which is consistently and for a sufficient period of time available across the 4 big euro area countries. ECB Working Paper Series No 2253 / March 2019 28 (and thus may have low capital investment demands) or are firms which are fairly un-dynamic (for example, if they are not in contested markets). Similarly, we also have a cluster of firms which are not very concentrated but invest a lot. This is like a neck-and-neck story. An interesting intermediate cluster of low to medium concentration but high investment rates.27 The overall fit is revealed by the red (non-linear) line. 8.2 The interaction between market power, markups and TFP growth In a next step, we consider the relation between market concentration and TFP growth. Analyzing how market concentration relates to TFP growth among the largest euro area countries is relevant given the important role TFP plays in generating growth and raising living standards. As is the case for investment, it is ex ante not obvious that there is a monotonic relationship between market concentration and TFP growth across sectors. On the one hand, some studies have highlighted the importance of superstar firms (see for instance Autor et al. 2017a). In this set-up, highly productive firms that benefit from increasing returns to scale {superstar), take an increasing market share given that "winner takes all" dynamics prevail. This will trigger a rise in market concentration but will also lift productivity and innovation. As such this development is consistent with reallocation to more efficient and innovative firms. However, high market concentration could also be driven by insufficient anti-trust enforcement and excessive barriers to entry. In this case, high market concentration could decrease economic dynamics and hamper productivity growth and innovation (see Gutierrez & Philippon 2017). To analyze the relation between market concentration and TFP growth outcomes in the 4 big euro area countries, Figure 19 plots the kernel density of TFP growth over the period 2006 to 2015 for both the Total Economy and the Manufacturing sector. The results show that there is in fact a wide distribution of TFP growth outcomes. Splitting the results according to the distribution for the highest (i.e. top 25 percentile) and lowest (i.e. bottom 25 percentile) concentrated sectors, shows however that the width of the distribution differs importantly between high and low concentrated sectors. For low concentrated sectors, the distribution is more narrow than for high concentrated sector, implying that highly concentrated sectors are associated with more extreme outcomes, both "good" and "bad" (positive and negative).28 For Manufacturing, again, we have 27Note that we are using the investment ratio in this exercise, but TFP growth can also be used. In fact TFP growth distributions give somewhat sharper results. A caveat to the present analysis is that it uses investment in physical capital, while recent trends have seen a rising importance of intangible capital on firms' production inputs, see Haskel & Westlake (2017). 28 Given that there was a deep recession in the middle of our sample and that some of the most concentrated firms are in cyclically sensitive industries (such as Construction and Manufacturing), the generality of this concentration-as-spreading mechanism is unclear. For this reason, the crisis years were dropped from the kernel density plot. Deleting the crisis year attenuated this spread but did not remove it. ECB Working Paper Series No 2253 / March 2019 29 more disperse outcomes, but a notably fatter tail on the positive TFP growth side. To understand the drivers of these more extreme outcomes in the highly concentrated sectors, we contrast these developments for low versus high technology intensive sectors. Low and high tech sectors are here defined according to the Eurostat definition for the Manufacturing sector.29 This is a series combing various approaching to measuring high technology take up, including technological intensity (R&D expenditure/value added), trade in high-tech products, and the high-tech and biotechnology elements to patents. Figure 20 shows the resultant kernel density plots for Manufacturing. For low tech industries, the distribution of TFP growth outcomes in low and highly concentrated sectors is nearly identical. Hence, the low tech industries appear to account neither for the very good nor the very bad TFP growth outcomes. The extreme results seem instead to be solely attributable to highly concentrated - high tech industries. These results would indicate that in the 4 big euro area countries both the good (superstar dynamics) and the bad drivers (barriers to entry) of concentration may be at work in these sectors. However, further and deeper analysis would be required to better understand and quantify the relative importance of the various drivers. Interestingly, when looking at the markup dynamics across sectors, highly concentrated industries with a high tech component have the lowest median markup. This result holds both when comparing their median markup with the median markup of highly concentrated industries with a low tech component and when comparing it with the median markup of industries with a high tech component but low concentration. Figure 21 shows that the markup distribution for highly concentrated industries with a high tech component is bi-modal and with a very fat (high markup) tail. This would thus confirm the recent findings in the US literature, namely that at the top end of the distribution, some high tech/high concentrated sectors have high markups. However, contrary to the US findings, we do not observe a rising trend in these markups over our sample period. Inspecting the data, therefore, and leaving aside issues of causality, there appears to be a case for saying that encouraging high-tech practices (as gauged by Manufacturing) raises productivity and (median) markups. 9 Conclusions This Paper has contributed to the literature on market power in the euro area, which is still somewhat in its infancy. Our analysis encompassed the traditional measures of firm and sectoral concentration ratios and markups, as well as those of economic dynamism. 29 Note that for the high tech sectors we combined the high and medium-high tech sectors as denned by Eurostat, see Appendix D. ECB Working Paper Series No 2253 / March 2019 30 Our findings for the euro area are the following: 1. Concentration ratios have remained broadly flat in recent years, albeit with some differences across sectors and countries. We find that concentration is higher at the country level than at the single market (big four) aggregate level and that Italy appears to be the least concentrated, while Germany the most. The Manufacturing sector is on average somewhat more concentrated than the Total Economy. Over time, although concentration has been broadly flat in most countries, it has been declining somewhat in Germany and increasing slightly in Spain. 2. A similar story pertains to markups. The aggregate euro area markup has been fairly stable, varying around a value of 10-15% and has even declined marginally since late 1990s/early 2000s, driven largely by developments in Manufacturing, and potentially the impact of trade and monetary integration in the euro area. Markups tends to be lower and somewhat more volatile in the Manufacturing sector. Of those firms and industries which have enjoyed high and rising markups, there is little evidence that they belong to the most concentrated ones. Thus the De Loecker & Eeckhout (2017) story that there has been a growth of high markup firms (rather than the growth of markups in themselves), appears not to hold in the euro area. Moreover, we observe that the highest markups are not necessarily located in the most concentrated sectors. 3. As regards economic dynamism, there has been no obvious trend secular change in the euro area. This contrasts with the United States, where economic dynamism, although in absolute terms still higher than that of the euro area, has witnessed some considerable decreases over time reflecting the shifts in market structure over recent decades. It is worth pointing out therefore that if the euro somehow became more concentrated (following the US experience) its already less favorable dynamism might deteriorate yet further. 4. In terms of the debate as to the merits of market concentration, we find (relying on results for Manufacturing) that firms in sectors which exhibit high concentration but are categorized as 'high tech users generally are associated with higher TFP growth rates in our micro sample (naturally, the caveat of the direction of causation is important to bear in mind). By contrast, markups tend to display a bi-modal distribution when looked at through the lens of high concentration and high tech usage - namely, there is a tail of firms with above-average markups and below average markups. ECB Working Paper Series No 2253 / March 2019 31 10 Discussion One clear conclusion from our work is that the US and the euro area have experienced quite different developments in terms of market power in recent decades. Whilst there is a consensus that market power and economic dynamism is in decline in the United States, it has stayed approximately stable in the euro area. This is a surprising, perhaps even startling, outcome since we typically consider these two economic areas to be not only at a relatively similar level of development and subject to the same shocks, but also to have been characterized by a quite similar economic performance in recent decades (investment rates and growth rates slowing, real interest rates declining, muted inflation, rising inequality etc). This would suggest that shifts in market power are not the main reason behind these developments. To continue the comparison of the US and the euro area, there are many positive and negative developments applying to each. For instance, the rise in concentration and higher aggregate markups in the US have been associated with high TFP growth, high-tech sectors. Other than productivity gains, this has often led (or have been considered to have led) to lower prices, new products and new sources of consumer welfare (such as some 'free' digital services). However, it may also be associated with a polarized labour market and declining labour shares of income and dispersion of labour incomes. If, as some suggest (e.g., Gordon 2016)30, technological progress is slowing then the US may then be in a position of having highly concentrated but essentially stagnant markets. Moreover, federal anti-trust enforcement has traditionally been seen as weaker compared to the EA, which, if true, may prove a stumbling block to managing such an outcome (e.g., Jennings (2006), Amelio et al. (2018)). Regarding economic performance in the euro area, there is clearly still considerable room for movement across firms towards frontier practises (and better technology diffusion, Veugelers 2017). Moreover, there still seem to be many firms and industries with excessively high markups, given, the high number of competing firms, or the apparent absence of any particular technological advantage underpinning their power. A situation of persistent and exceptional profits with little in the way of new entrants, suggests a role for reduced product market regulation and a strengthening of competition policies (e.g., Amelio et al. 2018). There remains considerable scope to improve R&D, hi-tech activity, reduce barriers to new entrants in the euro area. Indeed, economic dynamism is already at a relatively low level, and thus the possibility of further market concentration risks that level going even lower. Structural reforms in European product markets and further progress on the Service Directive (of 2006) therefore remain a potent policy message. Finally, it should be noted that exercises such as ours are inevitably imperfect and 30 References which take an alternative perspective include Brynjolfsson & McAfee (2014), Bloom et al. (2017). ECB Working Paper Series No 2253 / March 2019 32 miss many subtle interactions in the nature of cross-border economic activities. The US and the euro area seem to be different in terms of concentration and markups dynamics. However, it can be that in some sectors, markets are truly global and others not. If this is the case, then our analysis may be incomplete. Tech sectors are likely to be global so market shares and markups should be considered in a world market while some sectors are likely to be truly local. At the same time, recent evidence for the US suggests that global firms may be reducing concentration in local markets while increasing concentration at national level in the US (see Rossi-Hansberg et al. 2018). Drawing relevant markets is key to understanding market structures which are likely to be important to the pass-through of prices to marginal costs along with incentives to innovate. The rise of global firms and their complex ownership structures represents a challenge for competition authorities. Moreover, the increasing degree of non-domestic components to price and cost developments may complicate domestic monetary-policy setting. It may also require a change in inflation forecasting methods to accommodate international linkages, Forbes (2013). The boundaries of the firm are becoming less defined. Complex ownership structures across firms are increasingly common. This new reality challenges concepts as relevant markets, market shares and traditional market concentration measures. Not considering these links may convey an incorrect assessment of market-power developments. When considering the ultimate owner (considering participation links across firms), the euro area and US may in fact be more similar once this information is taken into account. Another issue of interest is how euro area firms respond when competing against global giants (such as the large ICT firms). Does the presence of these firms in European markets raise (home) productivity or does it choke off the rise of home rivals? The answers to these questions would require better data on various aspects of firms' performance such as their ownership structure, their innovation record, their export status, their dependence on global value supply chains. These are important policy-relevant questions for future research, which require a concerted effort to gather and back date richer firm based data among euro area countries. ECB Working Paper Series No 2253 / March 2019 33 Tables and Figures Table 1: Literature overview: US Study Period Approach Results Markup developments Nekarda & Ramey (2013) 1980-2013 Sectoral (New Keynesian) fO.96 (1980) to 1.07 (2013) De Loecker & Eeckhout (2017) 1960-2014 Micro: CompuStat (Production Function (PF), Cost-of-Goods-Sold (COGS)) 1 1.18 (1980) to 1.67 (2014) Traina (2018) 1950-2016 Micro: CompuStat (PF, COGS+Selling, General and Administrative Expenses(SGA)) i—> 1.1 (1980) to 1.16 (2016) Eggertsson, Robbins & Getz Wold (2018) 1970-2015 Aggregate (New Keynesian) t 1.04 (1980) to 1.2 (2015) Hall (2018) 1988-2015 Sectoral (PF) 1 1.12 (1988) to 1.38 (2015) Firm concentration developments Peltzman (2014) 1963-2007 hhi t since 1982 Grullon et al. (2017) 1972-2014 cr4 and hhi t since 1997; > 75 % of industries saw increase Autor et al. (2017a) 1982-2012 cr4, C20 and hhi t across sectors Philippon et al (17) 1995-2015 cr4 and hhi t across indicators Table 2: Literature overview: Europe Study Period Approach Results Markup developments De Loecker & Eeckhout (2018) Calligaris etal. (2018 a) 1980-2016 Micro: CompuStat (PF, COGS) global: 1 1 1 (1980) to 1.6 (2016); Europe: 10.98 (1980) to 1.64 (2016)) 2001-2014 Micro: Orbis (PF, COGS) global: 14-6 % between 01-14 Diez etal. (2018) 1980-2016 Micro: Orbis (PF, COGS+SGA) AE: 139%; less evidence for EMEs Canton & Thum-Thysen (2017) 2006-2013 Sectoral (PF, prof, services) EU13:110-20% Deutsche Bundesbank (2017) 1996-2014 Sectoral (PF) EU7: | in less R&D intensive industries, no clear trend in other Weche & Wambach (2018) 2007-2016 Micro: Orbis (PF, COGS) EU28: < > during crisis; levels clearly above US Firm concentration developments Dottlingetal. (2017b) 1995-2015 CRA and HHI EU: <—> Deutsche Bundesbank (2017) 2000-2012 C10 and HHI DE, IT, FR: <—> Valettietal. (2018) 2010-2015 CR4 and HHI EU5: <—> Table 3: Investment and Concentration: Regression Evidence 0.240*** 0.261*** 0.262*** 0.262*** (-5.85) (-6.07) (-6.03) (-4.63) -0.236*** -0.254*** -0.254*** -0.254*** (-5.76) (-6.03) (-5.99) (-3.43) Fixed Effects Country N Y Y Y Year N N Y Y Trim (90%) N N N Y R2 0.268 0.348 0.349 0.337 Note: '***' indicates significance at the 1% level. Numbers in parentheses indicate standard errors. ECB Working Paper Series No 2253 / March 2019 36 Table 4: Research and Development Comparisons (2000-2015) R&D Researchers High-tech Exports Barriers to Entrepreneurship* Admin Burdens on Startups (% GDP) (Mill) (% of manufactured exports) Germany 100 103 74 128 175 France 79 96 115 132 154 Italy 45 44 35 101 195 Spain 45 67 32 145 205 United States 100 100 100 100 100 Notes: * Barriers to entrepreneurship and Admin Burdens from OECD over sample 1998, 2003, 2008, 2013 (US average=1.69, 1.50) Sources: World Bank Indicators, US (average reference values=2.7%, 3963 per Mill, 21.4%). o DD Figure 1: CRA evolution over the period 2006-2015 Ö) T3 CD w CD 0 ro ro 01 32 30 28 26 24 22 20 18 IS 14 12 10 L Overall economy Single Market - median across sectors 'Single Market - weighted mean ■Country Aggregation - weighted mean Manufacturing 32 30 28 26 24 22 20 18 16 14 12 10 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 Note: In the Single Market approach, market shares are defined across DE, ES, FR, IT in a given sector. The median and mean correspond to the Single Market approach and are computed across industries. The Country Aggregation-Weighted mean corresponds to the aggregation computed at sector level for each country using turnover weights. 00 Figure 2: Ci?4 evolution over the period 2006-2015 by country Figure 3: CR4 evolution over the period 2006-2015 by country: Manufacturing DE o o CNJ 2006 2009 2012 ES o o CO o CNJ 2015 2006 2009 2012 2015 FR o o CO o 2006 2009 2012 o o CO o CNJ IT 2015 2006 2009 2012 2015 Mean (unweighted) ■ Median Sales weighted mean ECB Working Paper Series No 2253 / March 2019 Figure 4: Markup evolution based on sectoral data Figure 6: Markup evolution (Micro Data) Total economy -SM - weighted mean ......SM - median ----SM - P90 -CA - weighted mean Ma mifacturing 1.5 1.4 1.3 SM - we lglite d me an ......SM - median ----SM-pBO -CA - we lghted me an 1.2 I I- 1.0 I- 3006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2006 2007 200S 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 Note: The markup is the ratio of sales to variable costs. Variable costs include labour costs, external supplies, intermediate costs and taxes on products for IT and FR. For DE and ES, variable costs do not include taxes on products. SM- p50 and SM - p90 across sectors correspond to the SM approach and are computed for each sectoral distribution and then aggregated using sectoral turnover weights. SM- weighted mean is obtained by first aggregating firms at the sectoral level using market shares, and then sectors using sectoral turnover weights. The CA- country aggregation corresponds to the weighted mean of markups computed at sector level for each country using turnover weights. Figure 7: Evolution of Micro Markup: Weighted Mean markup versus Markup of Ci?4 firms. DE, ES, FR & IT 2006 2009 Weighted mean of markup - All firms 2012 2015 — Weighted mean of markup - Top4 ECB Working Paper Series No 2253 / March 2019 43 Figure 8: markup evolution across sectors with high and low concentration I Note: The Red dots indicate most concentrated sectors according to the CR4 indicator computed in 2006 (sectors with above-mean concentration among all sectors). Figure 9: markup evolution across sectors with high and low concentration II Note: See notes to figure 8. The size of the bubbles represent the relative share of the sectoral turnover over total sales. ECB Working Paper Series No 2253 / March 2019 44 ECB Working Paper Series No 2253 / March 2019 45 o DD Figure 11: Concentration Ratios with Employment and Sales in the euro area Ö) T3 CD w CD 0 ro ro 01 Overall Economy Manufacturing -SM - Unweighted mean -SM - Employment share top 4 -SM - Unweighted mean -SM - Employment share top 4 13 i 18 14 10 14 10 2006 2007 2003 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2006 2007 2003 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 Figure 12: Concentration Ratios with Employment and Sales in the euro area (by macro sector) Manufacturing — SM - weighted mean Employment share top 4 Water and electricity Construction 2006 200S 2010 2012 2014 Wholesale and retail trade 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 Transportation and storage 30 25 20 15 10 5 0 2006 2006 2010 2012 2014 30 25 20 15 10 5 0 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 2006 2008 2010 2012 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 Other services 2014 Figure 13: Establishment churn and entry rate in the US (%) CO CM CD CM 1980 Entry Rate Source: US Bureau of the Census. Figure 14: Startup rates across OECD countries (%) % 30 ■ 2001-2003 ■ 2004-2006 □ 2007-2009 □ 2010-2011 Note: The graph reports start-up rates (denned as the fraction of start-ups among all firms) by country, averaged across the indicated three-year periods. Start-up firms are those firms which are from 0 to 2 years old. Source: Criscuolo et al. (2014). ECB Working Paper Series No 2253 / March 2019 48 Figure 15: Job-finding and job-separation rate in the US (%) 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 2016 2018 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 2016 2018 (a) Job-finding rate (b) Job-separation rate Note: Job-finding and separation rates estimated as in Shinier (2012fo), using the redesign adjustment suggested by Elsby, Hobijn & Sahin (2013). Source: BLS. Figure 16: Job-finding and job-separation rate in the euro area (%) 10 2001 2003 2005 2007 2009 2011 2013 2015 2017 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 2016 2018 (a) Job-finding rate (b) Job-separation rate Note: Job-finding and separation rates estimated as in Shimer (2012fo), aggregated across durations using the optimal weighting method of Elsby, Hobijn & Sahin (2013). Source: Eurostat. ECB Working Paper Series No 2253 / March 2019 49 Figure 17: Residuals from regressing the finding rate on unemployment ' 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 2016 2018 ' 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 2016 2018 (a) Job-finding rate (b) Job-separation rate Note: The job-finding rates is estimated as in Shimer (2012fo), aggregated across durations using the optimal weighting method of Elsby, Hobijn & Sahin (2013). The graphs show the 3 quarter moving average of the standardized residuals from a regression of the job-finding rate on the unemployment rate. Source: BLS and Eurostat. Figure 18: Investment Rate and Concentration 0 .2 .4 .6 .8 1 CR4 Note: In the Single Market approach, market shares are defined across DE, ES, FR, IT in a given sector. The median and mean correspond to the Single Market approach and are computed across industries. The Country Aggregation Weighted mean corresponds to the aggregation computed at sector level for each country using turnover weights. ECB Working Paper Series No 2253 / March 2019 50 Ol PO Ol Appendices and Supplementary Material A Data Several different data sources have been used for this project. We choose to combine macro and micro data to derive and examine stylized facts on market dynamism and secular trends on sectoral profitability While firm-level data allows capturing the heterogeneity of firm behavior, these datasets can in some cases lack representativeness and generally are not stable over time for a discussion of long-term trends. A.1 EU-KLEMs Annual data from the EU-KLEMS database was used to examine long-run trends at the country and sectoral level. The database contains industry level measures of output, inputs and productivity for 28 European countries, Japan and the United States, for the period from 1970 onwards. The sectoral classification in EU-KLEMS follows the ISIC Rev. 4 industry classification. Concepts and methodologies to calculate the various growth and productivity variables are consistent with the latest European System of National Accounts (ESA2010). The present analysis covers six major aggregate sectors: Manufacturing (NACE 2 category C), Water, Electricity and Gas (NACE 2 category D-E), Construction (NACE 2 category F), Wholesale and Retail Trade (NACE 2 category G), Transportation (NACE 2 category H), Non-financial Services (NACE 2 categories I, L, and M-N). For each of these aggregates, we consider every 2-digit sector that forms to them. A.2 Firm-level data: Orbis and iBACH We rely on two sources of data for the analysis at the firm-level: the Orbis database from Bureau Van Dijk; and iBACH data. Information gathered under iBACH is our main source but it only includes information for FR, IT. Other countries, DE and ES are collected through Orbis. For further information on iBach, please see "The Bank for the Accounts of Companies Harmonized (BACH) database", Statistics Paper Series, Nb. 11 and on Orbis, please see https://www.bvdinfo.com/en-us/our-products/data/international/orbis. ECB Working Paper Series No 2253 / March 2019 54 A.3 Data cleaning We use unconsolidated firm-level data. Firm-level data representative of the aggregate economy is generally available in short frames. In this context, we consider the longest time span possible provided that there are no attrition bias associated to the data coverage. Hence, the first year of the sample is country specific and last year is 2016. In general, we cover around 10 years of data for each country from 2006 to 2016. Some sectors have been excluded from the analysis. We focus on the non-financial business sector excluding sole proprietorships.31 Sectors as Agriculture, non-market services as Education and Health care and the financial sector are not included. At the same time, some observations are disregarded in order to remove outliers and ensure robust results. The analysis is based on firms that are active in each year. These firms exhibit strictly positive (and non-missing) values for sales, number of employees, materials and wage bill.32 In addition, we adopt a standard outlier correction, i.e. drop input shares (wage bill/sales, material costs/sales, number of employees/sales) outside the percentiles p2, p98 by sector/year/country. A.4 Validation We compare total employment and total turnover with aggregate data from the OECD Structural Business Statistics33 for each country and year. This exercise is conducted in the original dataset and after the cleaning approach discussed above. B Additional Figures Here we show the results for the HHI for the micro data. This is to parallel the results shown for the Ci?4 measures earlier. Again we show the Total Economy, Manufacturing as well as the Total Economy for the countries. Finally, we show the evolution of sectoral shares. 31 2It comprises the following legal forms: Partnerships, Private limited companies, Public limited companies, Foreign companies and Branches. 32 On iBACH material costs includes material costs. In Orbis, only a part of material costs are observed. We use cost of goods sold as an approximation for material costs. 33 We use the SSIS under ISIC Rev.4 for all the years except 2004, for which we use ISIC Rev.3. This revision comprises very little changes for the aggregate figures we use. ECB Working Paper Series No 2253 / March 2019 55 Figure B.l: HHI evolution over the period 2006-2015 H HI - Overall economy TTTTT - Manufacturing 2005 2007 200S 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 200S 2007 200S 2003 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 Note: In the Single Market approach, market shares are defined across DE, ES, FR, IT in a given sector. The median and mean correspond to the Single Market approach and are computed across industries. The Country Aggregation Weighted mean corresponds to the aggregation computed at sector level for each country using turnover weights. o DD Figure B.2: HHI evolution across countries 2006-2015 (Total Economy) Ö) T3 CD w CD 0 ro ro 01 1500 1000 500 0 Germany Median • Unweighted mean eighted mean 1500 1000 500 0 Spain --Median ......Unweighted mean ^ eighted mean 3006 200T 200S 200S 3010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 200S 2007 200S 2003 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 1500 1000 500 Fiance — — Median ......Unweighted mean -^ eighted mean 1500 1000 500 Italy Median • Unweighted mean -We lghte d me an 200S 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2006 2007 2008 2003 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 Note: The mean and median are computed across sectors for each country. The weighted mean is computed across sectors using turnover weights. Ol Figure B.3: Sectoral Shares in the US, euro area and selected euro area countries us DE, ES, FR & IT Manufacturing -----Water, Electricity & Gas Wholesale & Retail Trade - Other 2010 2020 Construction o _ DE 1980 1990 2000 2010 292C 19S0 FR 19 SO 2000 2010 2C2C L.-J o 'J 1980 ES 1990 2000 2010 2020 19S0 IT 1990 2000 2010 2020 Manufacturing Wholesale & Retail Trade Water, Electricity & Gas Other Construction ECB Working Paper Series No 2253 / March 2019 C Additional Notes on economic dynamism As mentioned in the main text, the well-known series of firm births and deaths that are used in analyses of economic dynamism for the US are not easy to replicate in Europe, for several reasons. First, while reasonably harmonised data on economic dynamism for EU member states start in the 2000s, they are plagued by with severe asymmetries in coverage, and consistent reporting across a critical mass of countries only starting in 2006. Another issue is that business demography in the United States is quoted in terms of establishments, denned as a physical location a business operates in; each firm has hence at least one establishment. By contrast, demography in the EU is quoted in terms of firms, and hence by construction churn will appear lower. More importantly, the definition of births and death used in different countries is different. In the US, the focus is on employer establishments, units of firms with at least one employee. In the euro area, the unit of measurement is the firm (which may have more than one establishment), irrespective of whether it has employees or not. While Eurostat reports a breakdown of all measures by size, the crucial difference is that employer firm births also include non-employer firms that hire employees, while employer firm deaths also include employer firms that lose all employees but do not seize to operate. This dimension cannot be captured by the typical business demography series. Although Eurostat has been collecting data on employer firms for several years, there are wide reporting discrepancies across countries, and the series are especially short for Germany (starting in 2012) and France (starting in 2008). As these two countries account for roughly half of economic activity in the euro area, it could be misleading the make aggregate inferences for the euro area regarding pre- and post-crisis trends. Most national authorities also report data for all enterprises. Naturally this severely limits the usefulness of this database. The difference between the two databases may be substantive: existing non employer enterprises (e.g. self-employed or firms with unpaid family members) who hire employees are included in employer firm births, while employer firms who lose all employees but continue operating would be included in employer firm deaths.34 A final but more fundamental problem is that different incentives at the national level imply that there can be substantial differences across countries with respect to the legal status of firms, which can have a meaningful impact on results. For instance, Benito-Moral & Queiros (2018) report falling birth rates for Spain focusing on public limited and limited liability companies; considering all companies (even only focusing on employer firms) gives a considerably more muted response. In France, a tax incentive to incorporate for self-employed individuals led to a spike in birth rates in 2008, and possibly permanently affected birth rates. Without detailed knowledge of such intricacies across countries, it is impossible to make robust statements on economic dynamism for European countries, and prefer to focus on the transparent comparison of our measures of labour market dynamism. Nevertheless, we report some of the available series here for completeness. 34 Another caveat is related to the fact that in 2007 there was a break in the series due to a switch of the industrial classification system. Although this should not affect the total number of firms, in a few countries it does, for the employer firm dataset. ECB Working Paper Series No 2253 / March 2019 59 Figure C.l shows the churn rate for the US and the euro area and separately includes the churn rate for all firms and employer firms, for 7 countries: Austria, Spain, Italy, Luxembourg, Latvia, Netherlands and Portugal (denoted by EA7). We chose these countries both because they have both good coverage of employer firm dynamics for the duration of the 2004-2015 period and because birth and death trends are broadly similar for both the all firms and the employer firms series, while allowing for short-term divergence. We do this because there can be extraneous country-specific administrative reasons why recorded churn rates may differ for all firms and employer firms, and it is difficult to infer the "true" rate. We see that the churn rate for all firms and employer firms for the EA7 group do exhibit somewhat different dynamics; the churn rate for all firms is quite volatile before 2010 around a trend, and exhibits a small rise thereafter. The churn rate for employer firms is similarly volatile but remains stationary around 20%. In any case, there is no evidence of declining dynamism over this period for the EA7, compared to the US, which exhibited a decline of about 3 percentage points from 2005 to 2015. In Figure C.2, we repeat this exercise for France and Germany, as, despite limited data, it is important to see how dynamism in these countries evolves, due to their importance for euro area aggregates. The churn rate for all firms was quite stable in France until 2009, when a large increase in the birth rate led to a corresponding increase in chum. This is the result of a spike in the birth of zero-employee firms in 2009, after the introduction of tax incentives for the self-employed, and hence does not necessarily reflect an increase in start-up rates, but is indicative of the administrative noise mentioned above.35 This spike eventually dies out and it is unclear whether the observed decline in the churn rate indicates falling dynamism or is the result of data issues. The employer firm churn rate is not very informative either, as it is very volatile in its initial observations, and so it is not known whether the initial point was characteristic of pre-crisis dynamism or not. Before 2008, when the series for all firms for France were unaffected by measurement problems, the churn rate was increasing, as in the US. Germany, on the other hand, exhibits clear downward dynamism for the all firms definition, a phenomenon that does not seem to be related to measurement issues. This likely started before the crisis, although the sample is too short (starts in 2005) to draw definitive conclusions.36 Germany does have some interesting structural features other than increasing market power that could explain falling economic dynamism, such as an aging population and large current account surplus, driven both by a robust export sector and high savings rates. Finally, the employer firm series is not at all informative, as it is very short and volatile. 35 Another complication for France is a change in classification practices for the business economy category (B-N codes), which introduces a break in the series and may affect measurement. However, the entry and exit rates for the non-agricultural sector (B-S, which includes health, education, arts and other unclassified services, in addition to the business economy), which did not experience a classification change, are roughly stable, and hence we assume that the churn for the business economy is also unaffected. We continue using the business economy category as it is the most widely available across countries and time. 36 Also note that firm deaths are not recorded for 2008, so the series is interpolated for that year. ECB Working Paper Series No 2253 / March 2019 60 Figure C.l: Churn rate for all firms and employer firms, US and EA 2000 2003 2006 2009 2012 2015 US churn, employer establishments-EA7 churn, all firms EA churn, all firms EA7 churn, employer firms Note: US data come from the Census, euro area data from Eurostat. US data are for employer establishments and euro area data for firms (which may operate more than one establishment). The EA7 sample include Austria (AT), ES, IT, Luxembourg (LU), Latvia, Netherlands (NL) and PT, but only ES, IT, LU, NL and PT appear every year from 2004-2015. Figure C.2 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 FR, all firms DE, all firms FR, employer DE, employer firms Note: Data come for Eurostat. FR is missing data in 2006 and DE in 2004 and 2008. ECB Working Paper Series No 2253 / March 2019 61 D EuroStat Definition of Technology Usage High-technology: Manufacture of basic pharmaceutical products and pharmaceutical preparations Manufacture of computer, electronic and optical products Medium-high-technology: Manufacture of chemicals and chemical products Manufacture of electrical equipment Manufacture of machinery and equipment n.e.c. Manufacture of motor vehicles, trailers and semi-trailers Manufacture of other transport equipment Medium-low-technology: Manufacture of coke and refined petroleum products Manufacture of rubber and plastic products Manufacture of other non-metallic mineral products Manufacture of basic metals Manufacture of fabricated metal products, except machinery and equipment Repair and installation of machinery and equipment Low-technology: Manufacture of food products Manufacture of beverages Manufacture of tobacco products Manufacture of textiles Manufacture of wearing apparel Manufacture of leather and related products Manufacture of wood and of products of wood and cork, except furniture; manufacture of articles of straw and plaiting materials Manufacture of paper and paper products Printing and reproduction of recorded media Manufacture of furniture Other manufacturing Source: Seehttps://ec.europa.eu/eurostat/statistics-explained/index.php/Glossary:High-tech_ classification_of_manufacturing_industries. ECB Working Paper Series No 2253 / March 2019 62 References Acemoglu, D., Carvalho, V M., Ozdaglar, A. & Tahbaz-Salehi, A. (2012), 'The Network Origins of Aggregate Fluctuations', Econometrica 80(5), 1977-2016. Adalet McGowan, M., Andrews, D. & Millot, V (2018), 'The Walking Dead? Zombie Firms and Productivity Performance in OECD Countries', Economic Policy p. 685-736. Aghion, P., Bloom, N., Blundell, R., Griffith, R. & Howitt, P. (2005), 'Competition and Innovation: An Inverted-U Relationship', Quarterly Journal of Economics 120(2), 701-728. Aghion, P. & Howitt, P. (1997), Endogenous Growth Theory, MIT Press Books, MIT Press. Amelio, A., Buettner, T., Hariton, C, Koltay, G., Papandropoulos, P., Sapi, G., Valletti, T. M. & Zenger, H. (2018), 'Recent Developments at DG Competition: 2017/2018', Review of Industrial Organization 53(4), 1-27. Andrews, D. & Petroulakis, F. (2017), Breaking the Shackles: Zombie Firms, Weak Banks and Depressed Restructuring in Europe, Working Paper 1433, OECD Economics Department. Ashenfelter, O. & Krueger, A. (2017), Theory and Evidence on Employer Collusion in the Franchise Sector, Working paper, Princeton University Industrial Relations Section. Autor, D, Dom, D., Katz, L., Patterson, C. & VanReenen, J. (2017a), 'Concentrating on the Fall of the Labor Share', American Economic Review 107(5), 180-185. Autor, D., Dom, D, Katz, L., Patterson, C. & VanReenen, J. (2017fo), 'The Fall of the Labor Share and the Rise of Superstar Firms', NBER Working Paper 23396. Azar, J., Schmalz, M. & Tecu, I. (2018), 'Anticompetitive Effects of Common Ownership', The Journal of Finance73(4), 1513-1565. Azar, J. & Vives, X. (2018), Oligopoly, Macroeconomic Performance, and Competition Policy, Working Paper. Azar, J. & Vives, X. (2019), 'Common Ownership and the Secular Stagnation Hypothesis', AEA Papers and Proceedings. Baqaee, D. R. & Farhi, E. (2018), 'Productivity and Misallocation in General Equilibrium', NBER Working Paper 24007. Barkai, S. (2016), Declining Labor and Capital Shares, Working Paper 2, University of Chicago. Bartelsman, E., Haltiwanger, J. & Scarpetta, S. (2000), Measuring and Analyzing Cross Country Differences in Firm Dynamics, in T. Dunne and J. B. Jensen and M. Roberts, ed., 'Producer Dynamics: New Evidence from Micro Data', NBER/University of Chicago Press, chapter 1, pp. 15-76. Benito-Moral, E. & Queiros, F. (2018), Firm distribution, market power and business dynamism: Evidence from spain, Working paper, Universität pompeu fabra. Berry, S., Levinsohn, J. & Pakes, A. (2004), 'Differentiated Products Demand Systems from a Combination of Micro and Macro data: The New Car Market', Journal of Political Economy 112(1), 68-105. Bessen, J. (2017), Information Technology and Industry Concentration, Research Paper 17-41, Boston University School of Law. ECB Working Paper Series No 2253 / March 2019 63 Bloningen, B. & Pierce, J. (2016), Evidence for the Effects of Mergers on Market Power and Efficiency, Discussion Paper 2016-082, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. Bloom, N., Jones, C, Reenen, J. V. & Webb, M. (2017), 'Are Ideas Getting Harder to Find?', NBER Working Paper 23 782. Brynjolfsson, E. & McAfee, A. (2014), The Second Machine Age: Work, progress and prosperity in a time of brilliant technologies, Norton. Calligaris, S., Criscuolo, C. & Marcolin, L. (2018a), 'Mark-ups in the digital era', OECD Science, Technology and Industry Working Papers No. 2018/10. OECD Publishing. Calligaris, S., Criscuolo, C. & Marcolin, L. (2018Ö), Markups in the digital era, Working Paper 2018/10, OECD. Canton, E. & Thum-Thysen, A. (2017), 'Estimating Mark-ups and the Effect of Product Market Regulations in Selected Professional Services Sectors: A Firm-level Analysis', European Economy Discussion Paper 046. Crampton, P. (2003), Competition and Efficiency as Organising Principles for All Economic and Regulatory Policy Making, Intervention prepared for the first meeting of the latin american competitoin forum, OECD. Criscuolo, C, Gal, P. & Menon, C. (2014), The Dynamics of Employment Growth: New Evidence from 18 Countries, Policy Paper 14, OECD Science, Technology and Industry. Crouzet, N. & Eberly, J. (2018), Understanding Weak Capital Investment: the Role of Market Concentration and Intangibles, Paper prepared for jackson hole economic policy symposium, Federal Reserve Bank Kansas City. De Loecker, J. & Eeckhout, J. (2017), 'The Rise of Market Power and the Macroeconomic Implications', NBER Working Paper 23687. De Loecker, J. & Eeckhout, J. (2018), 'Global Market Power', NBER Working Paper 24768. De Loecker, J. & Warzynski, F. (2012), 'Markups and Firm-Level Export Status', American Economic Review 102(6), 2437-2471. Decker, R. A., Haltiwanger, J. C, Jarmin, R. S. & Miranda, J. (2018), Changing Business Dynamism and Productivity: Shocks vs. Responsiveness, NBER Working Papers 24236, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc. Decker, R. A., Haltiwanger, J., Jarmin, R. S. & Miranda, J. (2016), 'Where has all the Skewness gone? The Decline in High-Growth (Young) Firms in the ITS', European Economic Review 86(C), 4-23. Deutsche Bundesbank (2017), 'Mark-ups of firms in selected European countries', Deutsche Bundesbank Monthly Report December 2017pp. 53-57. Diez, F., Leigh, D. & Tambunlertchai, S. (2018), Global Market Power and its Macroeconomic Implications, Working Paper 18/137, International Monetary Fund. Dottling, R., Gutierrez, G. & Philippon, T. (2017a), Is there an Investment Gap in Advanced Economies? If so, Why, Proceedings from 2017 sintra forum on central banking, European Central Bank. ECB Working Paper Series No 2253 / March 2019 64 Dottling, R., Gutierrez, G. & Philippon, T. (2017fo), 'Is There an Investment Gap in Advanced Economies? If So, Why?'. Presented at the 2017 ECB Forum on Central Banking (Sintra). Edmond, C, Midrigan, V & Xu, D. Y. (2018), How Costly Are Markups?, Nber working papers, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc. Eggertsson, G. B., Robbins, J. A. & Getz Wold, E. (2018), 'Kaldor and Piketty's Facts: The Rise of Monopoly Power in the United States', NBER Working Paper 24287. Eggertsson, G., Robbins, J. & Wold, E. (2018), Kaldor and Piketty's Facts: The Rise of Monopoly Power in the United States, Working Paper 24287, National Bureau of Economic Research. Elsby, M., Hobijn, B. & §ahin, A. (2013), 'Unemployment dynamics in the oecd', The Review of Economics and Statistics 95(2), 530-548. Elsby, M. W. L., Hobijn, B. & Sahin, A. (2013), 'Unemployment dynamics in the OECD', Review of Economics and Statistics 95(2), 530-548. Forbes, K. J. (2013), Has Globalization Changed the Inflation Process?, mimeo, MIT. Gabaix, X. (2011), 'The granular origins of aggregate fluctuations', Econometrica 79(3), 733-772. Gali, J. & Gertler, M. (1999), 'Inflation Dynamics: A Structural Econometric Analysis', Journal of Monetary Economics 44(2), 195-222. Goldberg, P. & Hellerstein, R. (2013), 'A structural approach to identifying the sources of local currency price stability', Review of Economic Studies 80(1), 175-210. Gordon, R. J. (2016), The Rise and Fall of American Growth: The U.S. Standard of Living Since the Civil War, Princeton University Press. Grullon, G., Larkin, Y. & Michaely, R. (2017), 'Are US industries becoming more concentrated?', Forthcoming, Review of Finance. Gutierrez, G. & Philippon, T. (2017), Declining Competition and Investment in the U.S., Working Paper 23583, National Bureau of Economic Research. Gutierrez, G. & Philippon, T. (2018), How EU Markets Became More Competitive Than US Markets: A Study of Institutional Drift, Working Paper 24700, National Bureau of Economic Research. Hall, R. (1988), 'The Relation between Price and Marginal Cost in US Industry', Journal of Political Economy 96(5), 921-947. Hall, R. (2018), New Evidence on the Markup of Prices over Marginal Costs and the Role of Mega-Firms in the US Economy, Working Paper 24574, National Bureau of Economic Research. Hartmann, P. & McAdam, P. (2018), Price and Wage-Setting in Advanced Economies: Takeaways from the ECB's 2018 Sintra Forum, in 'Price and wage-setting in advanced economies', European Central Bank, chapter 1, pp. 6-25. Haskel, J. & Westlake, S. (2017), Capitalism without Capital: The Rise of the Intangible Economy, Princeton University Press. Hopenhayn, H. (1992), 'Entry, Exit, and Firm Dynamics in Long Run Equilibrium', Econometrica 60(5), 1127-50. ECB Working Paper Series No 2253 / March 2019 65 Jennings, J. P. (2006), 'Comparing the US and EU Microsoft antitrust prosecutions: How level is the playing field?', Erasmus Law and Economics Review2{\), 71-85. Liu, E., Mian, A. & Sufi, A. (2018), Low Interest Rates, Market Power, and Productivity Growth, mimeo. Lopez, A. & Vives, X. (2019), 'Overlapping Ownership, R&D Spillovers, and Antitrust Policy', Journal of Political Economy. McAdam, P. & Willman, A. (2004), 'Supply, Factor Shares and Inflation Persistence: Reexamining Euro-area New-Keynesian Phillips Curves', Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics66(sl), 637-670. Motta, M. (2003), Competition Policy: Theory and Practicer, Cambridge University Press. Nekarda, C. & Ramey, V. (2013), The Cyclical Behavior of the Price-Cost Markup, Working Paper 19099, National Bureau of Economic Research. OECD (2005), 'Policy roundtables: Barriers to Entry 2005', OECD Directorate for Financial and Enterprise Affairs, Competition Committee. Peltzman, S. (2014), 'Industrial Concentration under the Rule of Reason', Journal of Law and Economics 57 {4). Rossi-Hansberg, E., Sarte, P.-D. & Trachter, N. (2018), 'Diverging trends in national and local concentration', Working Paper No. 18-15. Shimer, R. (2012a), 'Reassessing the Ins and Outs of Unemployment', Review of Economic Dynamics 15(2), 127-148. Shimer, R. (2012Ö), 'Reassessing the Ins and Outs of unemployment', Review of Economic Dynamics 15,127-148. Tirole, J. (1988), The Theory of Industrial Organization, MIT Press Books, The MIT Press. Traina, J. (2018), Is Aggregate Market Power Increasing? Production Trends Using Financial Statements, Working Paper 17, University of Chicago Booth School of Business. Valetti, T., Koltay, G., Lorincz, S. & Zenger, H. (2018), Concentration Trends in Europe, Mimeo, European Commission. Veugelers, R. (2017), An Innovation Deficit behind Europe's overall Productivity Slowdown?, in , ed., 'Investment and Growth in Advanced Economies', ECB: Frankfurt am Main. Weche, J. P. & Wambach, A. (2018), 'The fall and rise of market power in Europe', ZEWDiscussion Paper No. 18-003. Zingales, L. (2017), Towards a Political Theory of the Firm, Working Paper 23593, National Bureau of Economic Research. ECB Working Paper Series No 2253 / March 2019 66 Acknowledgements All opinions expressed are personal and do not necessarily represent the views of the European Central Bank or the European System of Central Banks. We thank Jan De Loecker for extensive discussions, as well as Robert Anderton, Nicola Benatti, Ettore Dorrucci, Michael Ehrmann, Philipp Hartmann, Luc Laeven, Michele Lenza, Alberto Martin, Ricardo Mestre, Marcel Peruffo and to seminar audiences at the ECB. We also thank Bernardo Mottironi and Charlotte Sandozdit-Bragard for research assistance. Maria Chiara Cavalleri European Central Bank, Frankfurt am Main, Germany; email: maria_chiara.cavalleri@ecb.europa.eu Alice Eliel European Central Bank, Frankfurt am Main, Germany; email: alice.eliet@gmail.com Peter McAdam European Central Bank, Frankfurt am Main, Germany; email: peter.mcadam@ecb.europa.eu Filippos Petroulakis European Central Bank, Frankfurt am Main, Germany; email: filippos.petroulakis@ecb.europa.eu Ana Soares European Central Bank, Frankfurt am Main, Germany; email: ana_cristina.soares@ecb.europa.eu Isabel Vansteenkiste European Central Bank, Frankfurt am Main, Germany; email: isabel.vansteenkiste@ecb.europa.eu © European Central Bank, 2019 Postal address 60640 Frankfurt am Main, Germany Telephone +49 69 1344 0 Website www.ecb.europa.eu All rights reserved. Any reproduction, publication and reprint in the form of a different publication, whether printed or produced electronically, in whole or in part, is permitted only with the explicit written authorisation of the ECB or the authors. This paper can be downloaded without charge from www.ecb.europa.eu, from the Social Science Research Network electronic library or from RePEc: Research Papers in Economics. Information on all of the papers published in the ECB Working Paper Series can be found on the ECB's website. PDF ISBN 978-92-899-3515-9 ISSN 1725-2806 doi:10.2866/379250 QB-AR-19-034-EN-N