Gender, Property, and the State 247 The relationship between sexual inequality, the emergence of class structures, and the rise of the state have been enduring interests in anthropological studies of gender. The subordination of women appears to emerge as an aspect of state formation. According to Gailey (1987:6), "Institutionalized gender hierarchy ... is created historically with class relations and state formative processes, whether these emerge independently, through colonization, or indirectly through capital penetration." We are led to ask what relationship class and state formation have with the oppression of women and, when gender hierarchy occurs, why women are the dominated gender. How does the state have power to penetrate and reorganize the lives of its members, whether in Sumerian legal codes declaring monogamy for women or in welfare laws in the United States that influence household composition? Eventually, studying state formation may help us understand the origins and interrelationships of class and patriarchy and the social reproduction of inequality. Much discussion of this subject has centered = on Engels' book The Origin of the Family, Private Property, and the State, a nineteenth-century text in which Engels argues that the emergence of the concept of private property and its owner-: ship by men, as well as the development of a monogamous family, led to the subordination of women. In Engels' scheme, prior to this gender relations were characterized as egalitarian and complementary. All production was for use, and people worked together for the communal household. Thus, changes in gender relations were linked to changes in material conditions because the ownership of productive property (initially domestic animals) was concentrated in the hands of men. This thesis has been influential in many Marxist and feminist analyses of women's subordination. For example, Leacock notes that "there is sufficient evidence at hand to support in its broad outlines Engels' argument that the position of women relative to men deteriorated with the advent of class society" (Lea-cock1973:30). Following Engels Leacock observes that in early communal society the division of labor between the sexes was reciprocal, and a wife and her children were not dependent on the husband. Further, "the distinction did not exist between a public world of men's work and a private world of women's household service. The |arge collective household was the community, and within it both sexes worked to produce the goods necessary for livelihood" (Leacock 1973:33). In this view the oppression of women was built on the transformation of goods for use into commodities for exchange; the exploitation of workers and of women was generated by this process, which involved the emergence of the individual family as an isolated unit, economically responsible for its members, and of women's labor as a private service in the context of the family. This led to the "world historical defeat of the female sex" (Engels 1973:120; Silverblatt 1988:430). In a reanalysis of Engels Sacks agrees that women's position declined with the elaboration of social classes but disputes Engels' emphasis on the role of private property in this process (Silverblatt 1988:435). Rather, Sacks links state formation and the decline in the centrality of kinship groups to the deterioration in women's status. She delineates two relationships defining women in noncapitalistsocieties: sisterhood and wifehood. "Sister" refers to women's access to resources based on membership in a kin group. This relation implies autonomy, adulthood, and possible gender symmetry. "Wife," on the other hand, refers to a relationship of dependency on the husband and his kin. Sacks suggests that the development of states undermined women's status by dismantling the kin group corporations that formed the basis for sister relations (Sacks 1982). However, critics of Sacks' position have argued that the process of state formation may involve uneven and contradictory developments. For example, elite women in the Kingdom of Dahomey, West Africa, challenged state imperatives by means of control of marketing associations. Thus, Silverblatt rebuts Sacks' evolutionary paradigm, suggesting the inevitability of the decline in women's status with state formation; instead, she suggests that we acknowledge the complex history of the emergence of elite privilege in the rise of the state. In addition, elite women such as the royalty of Dahomey may or may not share the goals of peasant women. They may instead join with male elite in suppressing the authority and power of peasant market women. This illustrates the potential contradictions of gender affiliation on one hand, and class position on the other. Several anthropologists have observed that Engels lacked reliable ethnographic information and oversimplified the complexities of gender relations in kinship societies and in precapitalist states (Gailey 1987:15). In a critique of Engels Moore argues against his essentialist assumptions that there is a "natural" division of labor in which men are concerned with productive tasks and women with domestic ones. She also disagrees that an inevitable relationship will transpire between property, paternity, and legitimacy in which men "naturally" want to transmit property to genetic offspring (Moore 1988: 47-48). While Rapp (in this book) agrees with these criticisms, she points out that Engels addresses many current concerns, such as the relationship between women's participation in production and female status and the implications of the separation of the domestic-public domains for women's roles in society (see also Silverblatt 1988:432). She warns against overgeneralizing when trying to understand the origins of the state and ignoring the history and context in which political formations change. In her view we must examine kinship structures that were supplanted with the rise of the state and replaced by territorial and class specific politics. Kinship domains, formerly autonomous, were subjugated to the demands of emergent elites with repercussions for gender roles and relations. Among the processes that we need to examine are the politics of kinship, the intensification of military complexes, the impact of trade on social stratification, and the changing content and role of cosmology. For example, in stratified societies the establishment of long-distance trade and tribute systems may affect elite marriage patterns, leading to the emergence of dowry and the exchange of women to cement male 246 248 Gender, Property, and the State political alliances. Similar alliances are forged in societies that have experienced a rise in militarism. When economies change and demand increases for a traded commodity, exploitation of labor to produce it may also increase, and marriage systems that expand trading relations may be solidified through the exchange of women. Women themselves may be important figures in trading networks, as in West Africa and in Mesoamerica, where women are active in the marketplace. Alternatively, the extension of the state into localized communities can significantly influence gender roles and relations. This occurs, for example, by undermining women's ritual responsibilities (see Mathews, this book} or by generating conflict between government policy and the respective interests of men and women (see Browner, this book). Finally, changes in political hierarchies were legitimated by cosmological explanations in early states such as the Inca and the Maya. For example, as Maya society became increasingly stratified, a category of elite rulers known as ahaw emerged. These rulers were legitimized by myths that established them as mediators between the natural and supernatural worlds and as protectors of the people. State ideology involved the celebration of both male and female forces and the elite contained both men and women. Mothers of kings were always members of the high elite, and this class affiliation was also validated in myth (Scheie and Freidel 1990; Freidel and Scheie, this book). In this book, Ortner also examines the process of state formation, with particular regard to its effect on gender ideology. She analyzes the widespread ideology that associates the purity of women with the honor and status of their families. This pattern is evident in Latin America and the Mediterranean and in societies of the Middle East, India, and China. Broad similarities exist in these varied societies. Ortner questions why the control of female sexual purity is such a ubiquitous and important phenomenon. She notes that all modern cases of societies concerned with female purity occur in states or systems with highly developed stratification, and they bear the cultural ideologies and religions that were part of the emergence of these states. She argues that no prestaté societies manifest the pattern linking female virginity and chastity to the social honor of the group. Thus, concern with the purity of women was, in Ortner's view structurally, functionally, and symbolically linked to the historical emergence of state structures. The rise of the state heralds a radical shift in ideology and practice, with the emergence of the patriarchal extended family in which the senior man has absolute authority over everyone in the household. Women are brought under direct control of men in their natal families and later by their husbands and affinal kin. Ideologically women are thought to be in danger, requiring male protection; they are idealized as mothers and for their purity. One of the central questions in Ortner's discussion is the role of hypergamy (up-stalus marriage, usually between higher-status men and lower-status women) in state systems. Ortner suggests that one of the significant developments in stratified society involves the transformation through marriage from an essentially equal transaction to a potentially vertical one, where one's sister or daughter could presumably marry into a higher strata (wife of a nobleman, consort of a king). Hypergamy may help to explain the ideal of female purity because concepts of purity and virginity may serve to symbolize the value of a girl for a higher-status spouse. Thus "a virgin is an elite female among females, withheld, untouched, exclusive" (Ort-ner1981:32). Hypergamous marriages often involve the exchange of significant amounts of property, particularly in the form of dowry. The relationship between dowry, inheritance, and female status has been explored in a number of societies with varying marriage patterns. Dowry has been described as a form of premortem inheritance, parallel to men's rights in property accrued through inheritance after death of parents or other legators. However, McCreery (in this book) argues that considering dowry as a form of inheritance prior to death and as part of a woman's property complex obscures an important difference between the clear legal inheritance rights that men possess and the dowry that women may or may not receive. Women obtain dowry at the discretion of their parents or brothers, and dowry is not based on the same rights as other forms of inheritance to which men have access. McCreery uses the cases of China, India, and Ceylon (Sri Lanka) to examine women's property rights and how they relate to dowry. Chinese jaw more heavily emphasized the family as a corporate group of men related through patrilineal descent and consequently severely restricted the rights of women. Indian law gave greater weight to individual rights, including those of women. Finally, in Ceylon both men and women could own and dispose of private property. in general, it seems that dowry is not best understood as a form of premortem inheritance to the bride; in Ceylon and China especially the legal bases of dowry and inheritance are distinct. Dowries appear to serve as a means of social mobility in stratified societies in which rights over women are used in competition for higher status. While dowry has been viewed as a form of inheritance for women, the dowry system in northern India has taken a pernicious turn as brides are burned to death, poisoned, or otherwise "accidentally" killed by husbands and inlaws who believe that the women have brought inadequate dowries. Registered cases of dowry deaths in India in 1987 numbered 1,786, although women's groups contend that the real number is higher. Legislation banning dowries has been ineffective in preventing these murders, and the dowry system continues to be deeply embedded in local culture. Some feminist critics argue that dowry deaths represent a response to a growing materialist consumerism sweeping India that has stimulated demands for larger and ever-increasing dowries. While the status of Indian women as reflected in the exchange of property at marriage appears to be deteriorating, in other parts of the world women's legal status and property rights have improved through state-sponsored changes in the judicial system. For example, Starr (in this book) examines how in Turkey the impact of capitalistic agriculture and settled village life profoundly affected gender relations Gender, Property, and the State 249 and women's access to property. These changes occurred in the cultural context of Islamic notions of male dominance and female submission and legislation giving equal rights to women. Ottoman family law gave women rights to divorce and some protection against polygamous marriage, but inheritance practices remained constrained by Islamic law, in which women were under the authority of their husbands, had the status of a minor, received half the share of the patrimony obtained by their brothers, and had no rights to children of a marriage. According to Ataturk's secular reforms in the 1920s, women's rights were expanded to full adult status, equal rights to paternal inheritance, protection for widows, and other legislation promoting equality for women. At first these state-initiated rights were incongruent with cultural practices, but by the late 1960s women had begun to use the courts to protect their rights to property and their reputation. Starr points out that while Eng-els emphasized the negative impact of private ownership on women's status, in this case law and culture played a positive counterbalancing role resulting in women's emancipation. In all the works included in this chapter of the book we see the enduring influence of the issues raised by Engels with regard to the relationship between gender, property rights, and state structures. However, cross-cultural data demonstrate that this relationship is much more complex and varied than Engels' original formulation. Equally, universal evolutionary paradigms that posit a uniform impact of the rise of the state on gender roles cannot do justice to the myriad ways in which specific cultural histories, diverse social hierarchies, and systems of stratification affect gender relations and ideology. Thus, Silverblatt (1988:448) asks, "What of the challenges that women and men, caught in their society's contradictions, bring to the dominant order of chiefs and castes, an order they contour and subvert, even as they are contained by it? And what of the other voices, the voices that chiefs and rulers do not (or cannot or will not) express?" The complex histories of the relationship between any particular state and gender relations in it show that while state formation has contributed to the definition of womanhood, 250 Gender, Property, and the State women have also contributed to the definition of states (Silverblatt 7 988:452). REFERENCES Engels, Frederick. 1973. The Origin of the Family, Private Property and the State. New York: International Publishers. Gailey, Christine Ward. 1987. Kinship to Kingship: Gender Hierarchy and State Formation in the Tongan Islands. Austin: University of Texas Press. Leacock, Eleanor Burke. 1973. Introduction. In Frederick Engels (ed.). The Origin of the Family, Private Properly and the State, pp. 7-57. NewYork: International Publishers. Rayna Rapp The recent wave of feminism lias prompted many anthropologists concerned with the status of women to return to Engels' work, The Origin of the Family, Private Properly, and the State. While anthropologists vary widely in their assessment of the autonomy of women in prestate societies, there seems to be a general consensus that with the rise of civilization, women as a social category were increasingly subjugated to the male heads of their households. That is, civilizations are properly described as patriarchal. This consensus is based, implicitly or explicitly, on the tradition in which Engels was writing. His schema links the growth of private productive property to the dismantling of a communal kinship base in a prestate society. In this process, marriage Frnm Dialectical Antlirupology 2:309-316, 1977. Reprinted by permission ol'KUiwer Academic Publishers. Moore, Henrietta L 1988. Feminism and Anthropology. Minneapolis: University of Minnesota Press. Ortner, Sherry, 1981. Gender and Sexuality in Hierarchical Societies: The Case of Polynesia and" Some Comparative Implications. In Sherry B. Orty ner and Harriet Whitehead (eds.). Sexual Mean-I ings: The Cultural Construction of Gender and Sex^ uality, pp. 359-410. Cambridge: Cambridge" University Press. 5acks, Karen. 1982. Sisters and Wives: The Past and! Future of Sexuai Equality. Urbana: University of ]|.; linois Press. Scheie, Linda and David Freidel. 1990. A Forest ort Kings. NewYork: William Morrow. f Silverblatt, Irene. 1988. Women in States. Annual Review of Anthropology 17:427-461. ..; An Archaeology of Knowledge Concerning the Origin of the State 251 grows more restrictive, legitimacy of heirs more important, and wires generally become means of reproduction to their husbands. At the same time, reciprocal relations amongst kinsfolk are curtailed, unequal access to strategic productive resources gradually develops, and estates or classes arise out of formerly kin-based social organizations. In this analysis, the creation of a class hierarchy is intimately linked to the creation of the patriarchal family. Restrictions on women's autonomy emerge with class society. Engels' analysis informs many of the themes concerning women that are currently being investigated, such as the relation between productive contribution, control over distribution ol products, and female status in society; the relation of the mode of reproduction to the mode of production; and the effects of the relative separation or merger of the domestic and public spheres of activity on the roles available to women.! Consciously or n0t, our questions are often framed within the general territory mapped in Origins. Yet the major problematic of the book—the postulated intertwined origins of class oppression and gender oppression—has barely been examined. Engels was working with a paucity of ethnological, archaeological and historical cases; he lacked data on primär)' or pristine state formation, and knew only minimally of highly stratified prestate societies. We, however, have access to a great deal more information concerning societies in transition between primitivity and civilization with which to examine his theory.J Twentieth-century archaeologists and social theorists have amassed a substantive and growing body of theory and data concerning state origins to which we can, in principle, turn. Yet when we do, we discover that our question is certainly not theirs. We face a double theoretical problem in using their models. First: their search for "prime mover" explanations severely limits the questions that are being asked. There exists within evolutionär)' anthropology a strongly entrenched tradition which seeks to universalize its explanations. Such theories tend to be extremely reductive, and often condense a multiplicity of processes into unilinear variables. These theories range from a concentration on the extraction of social surplus via increasing division of labor and more productive technology (Childe, 1950, 1952); to a focus on the social-contract necessities of hydraulic societies (Wittfogel, 1955, 1957); to status-limitation, perhaps linked to population pressure (Fried, 1960, 1967); to the effects of population pressure and warfare within circumscribed environments (Carneiro, 1970, Harnei-, 1970). In the search for universal prime movers, the concern of these theorists has been extremely retrospective. They tend to see the state as an inevitable and efficient solution to a particular set of problems. But when the evolution of the state is viewed as a unilincal success story, we lose the specificity of history. A plethora of ranked chiefdoms, proto-states, city-states, feudal domains, empires and even national states have perished over a span of millenia during which the political apparatus we now identify as "the state" evolved. In over-generalizing, we ignore history, and the context in which political formations change.1 This leads to a second theoretical problem. For political structures in the primitive world both arise from, and encounter resistance within the kinship base that organizes prestate societies.'1 Not uncoincidentally, it is within the kinship domain that women's subordination appears to occur. Yet kinship barely exists in prime mover theories, except as a backdrop to the progress of the growing state. Kinship structures were the great losers in the civilizational process, and they must be examined if we are to understand both incipient class formation, and the changing domains of women. It seems to me that with the rise of state structures, kinbased forms of organization were curtailed, sapped of their legitimacy and autonomy in favor of the evolving sphere of territorial and class-specific politics. Emergent elites needed access to the primary resources of kin-based groups, especially, their labor power. Formerly autonomous kinship domains were domesticated to increased, institutional demands of production and distribution. What was once the realm of total social reproduction got stripped and transformed to underwrite the existence of more powerful, politicized domains. In the process, not only kinship, but women lost out. This is the process we need to examine. In recent years, many archaeologists have been inclined to reject prime mover explanations for social stratification in favor of more processual, systemic ones. The refutation of the hydraulic imperative and population pressure models on both theoretical and empirical grounds should make us wary of overly-simple explanations which pump causes out of correlations.' The "new archaeology" often uses ethnographic models for hypothesis building.'1 In the process, there are some fascinating hints about the role of kinship structure, and possibly women, in stratification. Some of the processes examined in state formation, such as the politics oi kin- 252 Gender, Property, and the State ship, the changing content and role of cosmo-logical systems, the intensification of military complexes, and the role of trade in stimulating or increasing social stratification concern our question directly. I will discuss each of these in schematic form, suggesting some of the lines of inquiry they direct us to pursue. (1) The politics of kinship: The conical clan floats through the literature, bringing with it an increasing tension in alliance, descent, and the transmission of status positions. Adams awards it an ambiguous and critical role in both Mesoamerica and Mesopotamia, and many anthropologists have examined the internal tensions of ranked kinship systems (Kirchoff, 1959; Sahlins, 1958, 1963; Fried, 1967). In highly ranked kinship systems, the role of women is of crucial importance. They not only transmit status, but may be contenders for leadership positions either directly, or through their children. This seems to be the case in Polynesia and in parts of Africa. As Gailey shows for Tonga (1978), the existence of elite, ranked women became more problematic as stratification increased. We need to know more about marriage patterns in such systems. In archaeology, ethnology, and Western history, we find that elite marriages may be implicated in the politics of establishing and maintaining longdistance trade and tribute systems.' Dowry is associated with highly stratified systems and dowered, elite women may appear as pawns in a classic case of male alliances formed via their exchange/ Orlner (1976) suggests that in state-organized systems, marriage may shift from a horizontal to a potentially vertical transaction, with a tendency toward hvpergumy through which elite women accumulate at the top of the system. These structural properties of the marriage system she links with ideologies requiring sexual purity and protection of women (but not of men). Silverblatt, in a study oflnca elite marriages, suggests that as the Incas extended their rule, they used an indigenous, pre-existing system of male/female ritual domains. These were ranked as male-conqueror/female-conquered. Conquered ayllus, identified as female and potential wives of the Incas, had to send women to Cuzco to senc in the temples, courts, and as noblemen's wives. For the conquered community, this practice represented a loss of autonomy in marriage patterns, and a burden; at the same time, it made possible upward mobility to the specific males who sent sisters and daughters to Cuzco, separating them out in prestige from the collectivity. The women themselves demonstrated the same sort of ambivalence: they gained a great deal of prestige, but lost any autonomy they might have had in arranging their own marriages and living within their natal communities (1976). (2) Changing Cosmologies: Both Silverblatt and Ortner aid us to focus on the relation of women to cosmological systejns in early states. Along with Wiley (1962, 1971), Eliade (1960), and Adams (1966), they remind us that religious systems were the j>lue that cemented social relations in archaic societies. Such systems were used, as in the Incaic case, to underwrite and justify changes in political hierarchies. They exhibit signs of ideological warfare on the battleground between local and elite pantheons. Tension about female status is often found within them as well. Fliacle claims that the ritual expression of sexual antagonism and the existence ol bisexual and/or androgynous gods accompanies the social organizational changes associated with the neolithic. Female and androgynous gods are often subsumed, or covered up, by ascendant male figures. This cover-up is sometimes performed indigenously, and often the work of later missionaries. This sort of layering over female and/or androgynous figures has been uncovered in Mesoamerica (Nash, 1976), Peru (Silverblatt, 1976) and is, of course, a favorite theme of classicists for early Greek society (Arthur, 1976; Pomeroy, 1974). Pagels (1976), working with 2nd century A.D. Gnostic texts, analyzes the symbol system of sects in which the early Christian god was bisexual, and the Holy Family consisted of mother, father, and son. Such sects were organized into non-hierarchical religious communities, in which offices were rotated, and women participated in both teaching and preaching—a far cry from the An Archaeology of Knowledge Concerning the Origin of the State 253 ascendant Christian cosmology and practice which became the mainstream tradition. Cosmologies have histories; by peeling away their layers we may learn about how the ascendant estate legitimated itself. Cosmological changes are ideological precipitates of structural tensions; it is clear that their form and content have a great deal to tell us about class and gender. (3) Intensification of Warfare: As early states became increasingly militaristic, social organization was transformed.''1 We need to know what happened to kinship structure, inheritance and succession in the process. Several case histories lead us to believe that under conditions of intense warfare, men were not only burdened by conscription, but were blessed with increasing power as household heads—a kind of trade-off. Muller (1975) finds this to be the case in feudal Wales. Elite males may gain land, political domains, and alliance-forming wives in the process. Yet the recent sweeping statements about male supremacy and warfare (Harris and Divale, 1976) are overgeneralized. even for state-making groups. Some evidence seems to contradict the association of warfare and an elevation of male status at the expense of female autonomy. I lack data on pristine states, but in the ancient West, the correlation often works the other way: Spartan women held offices, controlled their own property and had a great deal of sexual freedom, allegedly because they kept society functioning while the men were at war. Moreover, producing soldiers was considered as important as training them. In Athens, women's access to public places and roles seems to have increased a great deal during times of warfare, especially the Peloponnesian Wars, during which they left their virtual purdah conditions. In Rome, during the Second Punic War, women gained in inheritance settlements and held public offices formerly closed to them (Pomeroy, 1974). In the medieval Franco-Germanic world, noble women attained approximate parity in politics and property-management during the eras of the most brutal military crisis. McNamara and Wemple argue that their relative autonomy is inversely linked to the existence of any form of public power structure; to the extent that none exists, women are freer to control their inheritance and their marital destinies (1973). All these examples concern elite women only; we know very little about the effects of warfare on laboring women, who probably suffered then, as they do now. Nonetheless, it is not clear that warfare degrades women's status; the specific context within which military organization and practice occurs must be taken into account. Blood and gore clearly are not uni-versalizable variables in theorizing about women's subordination. (4) Trade: the role of trade in increasing and/or spreading stratification is an intriguing one. Foreign trade goods may be spread in many ways, by middlemen, via migrations, through central trading centers, and in marriage exchanges, to name but a few. Recent literature tells us that the social relations of a production and distribution which undergircl trade may be relations of incipient stratification between classes and genders (Kohl, 1975; Wiley, 1974; Adams, 1974). We need to know who produces goods, who appropriates them, and who distributes them. As demand for a traded commodity increases, exploitation of labor to produce it may arise. Marriage systems may also get intensified to expand the reproduction of trading alliances. The ethnographic literature runs rampant with examples of polygyny to increase access to goods that wives make. There are also many instances of increasing class division linked to increasing bride-wealth. Sisters and daughters are sometimes portrayed as pawns in alliances that many into expanding trade networks.11 It may be women who are used to "prime the pump" of kinship reciprocity in such circumstances. But appropriation and distribution are not exclusively male functions. In Mesoamerica and the Andes to this day, women are active in the marketplace. Silverblatt (1976) suggests that they were important traders in early Incaic times; Adams records their existence in Mesopotamia as well (1966). And of course, their presence is felt in stratified groups throughout Africa and the Caribbean as well, in contemporary ac- 254 Gender, Property, and the State An Archaeology of Knowledge Concerning the Origin of the State 255 counts (Mintz, 1971). Under what conditions does long-distance trade pass into the hands of men, and when is it possible for women to continue to perform it? When women are traders, do they constitute an elite, class-stratified group? To the extent that trade is implicated in the intensification of production for exchange, women as producers, reproducers, and traders must be implicated, too. What I am suggesting in these examples is that structural tensions arise within kinship-based societies and that these need careful examination if we are to understand state-formation. I am making a plea for careful historical reconstructions, informed by a feminist perspective, rather than an overly mechanical and generalizing view which erases certain questions before they can be written. As we come to identify the factors in state formation as they affect women, we must be careful to think in probablistic rather than deterministic terms. We need to contextual-ize the relative power of kinship and class, the interplay of domestic and extra-domestic economy, the flexibility within cosmological systems, and the relative autonomy or subordination of women, in light of the possibilities open to each society. We should expect to find variations within state-making (and unmaking) societies over time, and between such societies, rather than one simple pattern. There is another arena to which we can turn in examining how the processes of state formation and penetration a fleet gender relations. The area we now rather euphemistically call the Third World has served as a bloody iaboratoiy in which stratification by culture, class and gender occurred. While obviously differing from pristine state formation, this process of rapid penetration by patriarchal national states allows us to see how the conditions of primitivity are shattered. In examining the colonization of the indigenous societies of the Americas, Asia, Africa, we need to be very cautious. Each area is heir to its own particular history, as is each colonizing power. Specific histories condition the patterns of resistance, acceptance, or modification of the social organization produced by colonization. We cannot subsume such com- plexity into one simple model of precapitalist penetration. Nonetheless, certain patterns affecting the ways of life of women can be traced at a general level. Wherever women have been active horticulturalists of collective lands, the imposition of private property, taxation, labor migration and cash cropping has had devastating effects. Their realm of productivity and expertise has been deformed and often destroyed (Boserup, 1970; Blumberg, 1976; Tinker, 1976). Depending upon context, they may become either super-exploited, or underemployed, but always more dependent upon men. The evidence also suggests a general pattern concerning political organization: prior to colonial penetration, indigenous cultures appear to have been organized into gender domains on essentially parallel lines. Men and women both had organizational forms and rituals which were conditioned by gender-linked relations of production and distribution.1- Case histories from Africa, Asia and the Americas suggest that pa-'-, triarchal, colonizing powers rather effectively dismantled native work organizations, political structures, and ritual contexts. The pro-,, cess of demobilizing women occurs when essentially parallel forms are subsumed into one, and that one is male. Leadership and authority are assigned to activities which are male, while female tasks and roles are devaluated, or obliterated. Van .Allen's work (1972) describes the political associations of Igbo women which survived the British freeze, and were effectively used to organize the 1929 tax riots. We have case histories recording the effects of assigning credit, technology and education to men such that traditionally female activities are drastically curtailed, or cease to exist. Female marketing is increasingly circumscribed by the influence of internationalization; its agents prefer to deal with men.'1 Several authors have gone so far as to argue that women thus divested of their social organization and collective roles have become rather like underdeveloped, monocrop regions. Once they lived in a diversified world; now they have been reduced to the role of reproducing and exporting labor power for the needs of the international world economy (Bossen, 1973; Deere, 197(3; Boulding, 1975). please note: in these processes, class stratification as well as gender stratification is operating- Vast categories of men, too, lose autonomy in the broadest sense. My point is that men and women lose it differently, and their lives are transformed differently. State formation and penetration is pro-cessual; its form and force are highly variable, both within and between societies. Yet it is important to remember that the processes which began millenia ago are ongoing. Cumulatively, they continue to transform the lives of the masses of people who exist under their structures. It is a long way from the Sumerian law codes declaring monogamy for women to the welfare laws of the United States which affect parental dyads and household structure. But in both cases, the power of the state to penetrate and reorganize the lives of its members is clear. As we seek to understand the complex, stratified societies in which we now operate, we are led to reflect on archaic societies in which the dual and inter-mined processes of hierarchy we now retrospectively label "class" and "patriarchy" took their origins. NOTES 1. For analyses implicitly or explicitly influenced by Origins, see Brown, 1975; Sacks. 1 97-1; Reiler, 1975; Sanday, 1974; Rubin, 1975: Meillassoux, 1975. 2. Summaries of the state formation literature mav be found in Service, 1975; Flannerv, 1972; Webb, 1975; Kracler, 1968. 3. A less determinant and more processual perspective on stratification and state formation is sei forth in Fiannery, 1972; Tilly, 1975, and SablotT & Laniberg-Karlovsky, 1975. Such thinking also informs the corpus of Marxist historiography. 4. This has been a major thrust in S. Diamond's work (1951, 1974). 5. Adams. 1966, presents the most cogent critique of the hydraulic hypothesis. Population pressure models are rejected for Iran in Wright & Johnson, 1975, and for the Valley of Mexico by Brumfiel, 1976 and Parsons, 1974. See Cowgill, 1975 for a theoretical and methodological critique. 6. For instances of the "new archaeology's" use of ethnographic evidences for hypothesis building, see Fiannery, 1967; Renfrew, 1975, both volumes edited by Sabloff & Lambcrg-Karlovsky, 1974 and 1975. and Adams, 1966 and 1974. 7. Such links are suggested in Fiannery, 1967; Wiley & Shimkin. 1971. and by much of the literature on stratified chiefdonis, fur exam-pie, Sahlins, 1958; Kirclioif, 1959; and Fried, 1967. In European history, wc find instances in the international royal marriage patterns. See McNamara & Weniple, 1973, fur some of the implications of feudal marriage patterns. 8. See Arthur, 1976; Ortiier, 1976; Goody Sc Tambiah, 1973. 9. The temple and militatv-complexes figure in the state formation schemes of Steward, 1955; Adams, 1966, and Wiley, 1971, to name hut a few. 10. The archaeology of trade is discussed in Sabloff and Lamberg-Karlovsky, 1975, and is critically summarized in both Adams, 1974, and Kohl, 1975. See also Wiley, 1974. [f. Ethnographic examples used lo speculate about ancient trade are provided by Adams (1974) who cites materials on the Cheyenne and Blackfoot, and Fiannery (1967) who uses Tlingit materials. In these cases, marriage alliances were intensified along with trade. 12. Parallel and interarticulating forms of gender social organization are analyzed in Siskind, 1976: Brown, 1970; Silverman. 1976; Van Alien, 1972. and Sacks, 1976. 13. See Mintz, 1971, Boserup, 1970, Tinker. 1976, and Blumberg, 1976 for specific examples. Agricultural schools throughout Africa often closed their doors to women, the traditional horticulturalists. Agricultural machinery for "women's work" often falls into the laps of men as the sole possessors of access to credit. REFERENCES Adams, R.M. (1966). The Evolution of Urban Society. Chicago: Aldine. Adams, R.M. (1974). "Anthropological Perspectives on Ancient Trade," Currant Aiitliropology, Vol. 15. Arthur, M. (1976). "Liberated Women: The Classical Era," in Bridenthal and Koontz (eds.), Becoming Visible: Women in European Histon: New-York: Houghton and Mifllin. 256 Gender, Property, and the State The Virgin and The State 257 Blumberg, R. (1976). "Fairy Tales and Facts: Economy, Fertility, Family and the Female. Boserup, E. (1970). Women's Role in Economic Development. London: George Allen and Unwin. Bossen, L. (1973). "Women in Modernizing Societies. "American Ethnologist, Vol. 2. Boulding, E. (1975). "Women, Bread and Babies". University of Colorado, Institute of Behavioral Sciences, Program on Research of General Social and Economic Development. Brown, J. (1970). "A Note on the Economic Division of Labor by Sex." American Anthropologist, Vol. 72. Brown, J. (1975). "Iroquois Women," in R. Reiter (ed.). Toward an Anthropology of Women. New York: Monthly Review Press. Brumfiel, E. (1976). "Regional Growth lit die Valley of Mexico," in Flannery (ed.). The Early Mesoamerican Village, New York: Academic Press. Carnciro, R. (1970). "A Theory of the Origin of the Svmc," Science, Vol. 169. Childe, G. (1950). "The Urban Revolution," Town Planning Review, Vol. 21, No. 3. Childe, G.'(1952). "The Birth of Civilization," Past andPresenl,Vo\.2,No. 1. Cowgill, G. (1975). "Causes and Consequences of Ancient and Modern Population Changes," American Anthropologist Vol. 77. Deere, C. (1976). "Rural Women's Subsistence Production in the Capitalist Periphery," Review oj Radical Political Economics, Vol. 8. Diamond, S. (1951). Dahomey: A Prolostutv in West Africa. Ann Arbor: University Microfilms. Diamond, S. (1974)./« Search of the Primitive: A Critique of Civilization, New Brunswick, N.J.: Transaction Books. Eliacle, M. (1960). "Structures and Changes in the History of Religions," in Kraeling and Adams (eds.), City Invincible, Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Flannery, K. (1972). "The Cultural Evolution of Civilizations, "Annual Review of Ecology and Sys-tematics. Vol. 3. Planner)'. K. (1974). "The Olmec and the Valley of Oaxaca," reprinted in Sabloff and Lamberg-Karlovsky (eds.). The Rise and Fall of Civilizations. Menlo Park, Ca.: Cummings. Fried, M. (1960). "On the Evolution of Social Stratification and the State," in S. Diamond (ed.), Culture and Histon. New York: Columbia University Press. Fried. M. (1967). The Evolution of Pol idea I Society. New York: Random House. Gailey, C. (1978). "Origins of the State in Tonga: Gender Hierarchy and Class Formation," Dialectical Anthropology. Vol. 3. Goody, J. and Tambiah, S. (1973). Bride-wealth and Down. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. • • Harner, M. (1970). "Population Pressure and the; Social Evolution of Agriculturalists," Southwestern journal of Anthropology, Vol. 26. Han-is, M. and Divale, \V. (1976). "Population, Warfare and the Male Supremacist Complex," American Anthropologist, Vol. 78. Kirchoff, P. (1959). "The Principles of Clanship Human Society," in Fried (ed.), Pentlings in Anthropology, Vol. 2. New York: Crowell. Kohl, P. (1975). "The Archaeology ofTracle," Dialectical Anthropology, 1:43-50. Kräder, L. (1968). Formation of the Stale. Engle-wood Cliffs: Prentice-Hall. McNamara, J. and Wemple, S. (1973). "The Power of Women through the Family in Medieval Europe: 500-1) 00," Feminist Studies, Vol. 1. Meillassoux, C. (1975). Fem ums, greniers el. caphaux. Paris: Maspero. Mintz, S. (1971). "Men, Women, and Trade," Com-para live Studies in Society and History, Vol. 12. Müller, V. (1975). "The Formation of the State and the Oppression of Women: England and Wales," manuscript. Nash, J. (1976). "Aztec Women," manuscript. Ortner, S. (1976). "The Virgin and the State," Michigan Papers in Anthropology. Vol. 2. Pagels, E. (1976). "When did God Make Man in His Image?" Signs, Vol. 2: Parsons, [. (1974). "The Development ofa Prehistoric Complex Society," fou rnal of Field A rchaeol-ogy. Vol. 1. Pomeroy, S. (1974). Goddesses, Whores. Wives and. Slaves. New York: Schocken. Reiter, R. (1975). "Men and Women in the South of France,"in R. Reker (ed.), Toward an Anthropology of Women. New York: Monthly Review Press. Renfrew, C. (1975). "Trade as Action at a Distance," in Sabloff and Lamberg-Karlovsky (eds.), Ancient Civilizations anil Trade. Albuquerque, N.M.: University of New Mexico Press. Rubin, G. (1975). "The Traffic in Women," in R. Reiter (ed.), Toward an Anthropology of Women. New York: Monthly Review Press. Sabloff and Lamberg-Karlovsky (eds.). (1975). Ancient Civilizations and Trade. Albuquerque, N.M.: University of New Mexico Press. Sacks, K. (1974). "Engels Revisited," in Rosaldo and Lamphere (eels.). Woman. Culture and Society. Stanford: Stanford University Press. Sacks. K. (1976). "State Bias and Women's Status," American Anthropologist. Vol. 78. Satiday, P. (1974). "Toward a Theory of the Status of Women," in Rosaldo and Lamphere (eds.), Woman, Culture and Society. Stanford: Stanford University Press. Sahlins, M. (1958). Social Stratification in Polynesia. Seattle: University ofWashington Press. Sahlins, M. (1963), "Poor Man. Rich Man, Big-Man, Chief," Comparative Studies in Society and Hillary, Vol. 5. Service, E. (1975). Origins of the Stale and Civilization. New York: Norton. Silverblatt, 1. (1976). "Inca Women: Conquered Moon, Conquering Sun," manuscript, Department of An thro po log)', University of Michigan. Siskind, J- (1976). "Kinship: Relations of Production," manuscript. Steward, J. (1955). The Theory of Culture Change. Urbana: University of Illinois Press. Tilly, C. (1 975). Reflections on the History of European State Making," in Tilly (cel.), The Formation of National Stales in Western Europe. Princeton: Princeton University Press. Tinker, I. (1976). "The Adverse Impact of Development on Women," in Tinker and Bramsen (eds.), Women and World Development. Overseas Development Council. Sherry B. Ortner In an extraordinarily wide range of societies in ilie world one Finds a peculiar "complex": ideologically it is held that the purity of the women reflects on the honor and status of their families; and the ideology- is enforced by systematic and often quite severe control of Tliis article is rtpriiilecl (rum Feminist Studies, volume 4. numbers (October lil78): 19-35, bv permission of the publisher. Feminist Studies, Inc.. c/o Women's Studies Program, University of Mankind, College Park, MD 20742. Van Allen, J. (1972). "Sitting on a Man," Canadian journal of African Studies, Vol. 6. Webb, M. (1975). "The Flag Follows Trade," in Sabloff and Lamberg-Karlovsky (eds.). Ancient Civilizations and Trade. Albuquerque, N.M.: University of New Mexico Press. Wiley, G. (1962). "The Early Great Styles and the Rise of Pre-Columbian Civilizations," American Anthropologist, Vol. 64. Wiley, G. (1974). "Prccolunibian Urbanism," in Sabloff and Lamberg-Karlovsky (eds.). The Rise and Fall of Civilizations. Menlo Park, Ca.: Cummings. Wiley, G. (1974). "Commentary on the Emergence <)l'Civilization in the Mara Lowlands," in Sabloff and Lamberg-Karlovsky (eds.), The Rise and Fall of Civilizations. Menlo Park, Ca.: Cummings. Wiley, G. and Shimkin, D. (1971). "The Collapse of the Classic Maya Civilization in the Southern Lowlands," Southwestern journal of Anthropology, Vol. 27. Wittfogel. K, (1955). "Oriental Society in Transition," Far Eastern Quarterly, Vol. 14, p. 469—178. Wittfogel, K. (1957). Oriental Desjmtism. New Haven: Yale University Press. Wright, H. and Johnson, G. (1975). "Population, Exchange and Early State Formation in Southwestern Iran," American Anthropologist. Vol. 77. women's social and especially sexual behavior. One sees this pattern manifested among peasant societies in Latin America and around the entire Mediterranean area, among pastoral nomadic tribes of the Middle East and southwest Asia, among the castes of India, and among the elites of China. In extreme cases, such as classical Athens or among Brahmins of India, women were confined to the house for life. In imperial Turkey, the sultan had vast numbers of wives and 258 Gender, Property, and the State The Virgin and The State 259 daughters "in an elaborately organized harem, or seraglio, with disciplinary and administrative officers, ruled over by [his] mother." Among poorer peasants and nomads, a variety ol" other devices—veils; rules of body-disguising dress and of modest demeanor; restrictions on expression, communication, and movement; all overseen by the family in particular and the gossip of the community in general—serve to restrict women's social and sexual behavior as effectively as if they were locked up.1 Reviewing the variety of cases, one tends to get involved in particular cultural symboliza-tions and practices, and to lose sight of the broad similarities of pattern. Further, the pattern does not seem to be confined to anv particular type of society, or to any consistent stratum: peasants and elites, agriculturalists and pastoral nomads, all seem to embrace some version of the female purity ethic with equal intensity and commitment. It seems difficult to imagine that there might be a single interpretation that would cover, or at least interrelate, all the cases. In fact, in the anthropological analyses of particular cases, a variety of interpretive frameworks have been used: psychoanalytic, structural, functional, ecological, political, or some mixture of several of these. Let me begin to situate the question of whv the control of female sexual purity is such a widespread and virulent phenomenon, by reviewing briefly some of the major attempts at interpretation in the anthropological literature." In an early essay from a psychoanalytic perspective, Kathleen Gough analyzed the female initiation rites among the Nayar and other groups of the Malabar region of India. Gough interpreted the rituals as signifying the formal renunciation by the girl's con-sanguineal kinsmen of rights to her sexuality, in a social context in which there is evidently strong incest temptation. Further, during these rites the young girl was actually or symbolically deflowered by a person other than her prospective husband; and Gough interpreted this point as representing male fear of the defloration of virgins in the course of nor- mal sexuality. Although Nayar women do noi: seem to fit our model in that, following their initiation they had great sexual freedom, We must not forget that their freedom was gained at the expense of Nambudiri Brahmin women, who were subject to virtually total scs elusion and control. Untold numbers of Nambudiri women died virgins, while Nambudiri men mated with the conveniently available Nayar.;l ' : In a subsequent counteressay, Nur Yalnian challenged (and ridiculed) Cough's interpretation and recast the whole argument in terms of the control of female purity. He stressed that the rites establish the purity of the women in their own castes and serve to define and regulate the women's subsequent choices of mates, who must always be of equal or higher caste status. The issue, he argued, is control of caste purity and status as a whole, which must be maintained by regulation of female sexuality, because regardless of the descent principles operating within intra kinship groupings, caste as opposed to kin af-filiation is always inherited bilaterally. Fur-ther, if caste membership is defined as coming only through one parent, that parent is always the mother. Thus for purposes of sustaining caste purity, the woman's purity in particular must be controlled, protected against pollution by lower-caste mates. Men, on the other hand, arc free to have sexual relations with anyone, "high or low" as Yalman> says, and he then explains this in both cultural and natural terms. Culturally, the Indians distinguish between internal and external pollution. Women are subject to internal pol- • lution in sexual intercourse, which is very:: hard if not impossible to cleanse, but men are subject only to external pollution in intercourse and can be cleansed by a simple ritual ~ bath. Yet Yalman goes further than this oil-; tural point, and relates the ideology to natural factors: "the bond between the genitor . and the child is tenuous; it can always be denied or minimized; the children can always be repudiated by the father."' More recent studies have tended to get ; away from elusive unconscious factors and symbolic cultural notions of pure and impure,.: and to stress the brass tacks of economics and politics. Lawrence Watson describes the practices of the Guajiro of Venezuela, among Ivhom the virginity of a girl upon marriage is absolutely demanded, the result being assured by a combination of psychological terrorism and physical punishment, mostly enacted by mothers on their daughters. For a serious offense, "the mother may place the tip of a hot branding iron on the girl's vagina to make the punishment a convincing object lesson." Watson casts his interpretation of this system in terms of the political structure of the society, in which every group is concerned about maintaining its status in a rigid class system; the group's status depends in part upon the quality of the women it can deliver in the marriage alliance process. Especially among the upper classes, influential chiefs overtly use marriage alliances of daughters and sisters as a way of building up fallowings for political and military backing. "If ... a woman causes her father or uncle to lose valuable political allies because of deficiencies in her sexual behavior, she becomes a liability and she can seriously impede her lineage's chances of building up a secure base of political support." In this interpretation, the sadistic control of female purity is simply a form of real poll HI;.'' And finally, Jane Schneider presents an argument in terms of ecological and economic factors, and the politics thereof. In her important paper, "Of Vigilance and Virgins . . . ", she begins with the general point that "honor can be thought of as the ideology of a property holding group which struggles to define, enlarge, and protect its patrimony in a competitive arena." She then goes on to argue that both pastoral and peasant societies tend to be highly socially fragmented and "un-solidary," although the reasons for this social fragmentation are different in the two cases. And according to Schneider, honor is the code that keeps this "centrifugal" situation together: it "helps shore up the identity of a group (a family or a lineage) and commit to it the loyalties of otherwise doubtful members. [It] defines the group's social boundaries, contributing to its defense against the claims of equivalent competing groups. [It] is also important as a substitute for physical violence in the defense of economic interests. . . . Honor regulates affairs among men." But why the honor of the women ? Why should the women's honor represent the honor of the group as a whole? Because, says Schneider, resolutely practical to the end, among the pastoralists concerned with lineage continuity, female reproductive capacity is valuable, and women are "contested resources much like pastures and water." As for the agrarian peasants, the problem seems primarily to be the potential fragmentation of the family of procreation, with fathers, sons, and brothers set off against one another because of inheritance rules; here the daughters/sisters provide the one shared focus of concern that can hold the group together." I will restrain my temptation to dissect the circularities and self-contradictions of many of these arguments and will simply say that, with the exception of the psychoanalytic argument, all of them share common functionalist orientations: the purity of women is seen as adaptive for the social coherence, economic viability, or cultural reputation of the group, regardless of whether the group is a caste, lineage, or family. When the theorists trv to explain why women in particular should represent the coherence and integrity of the group, rather than, say, a totemic bird or a sacred flute, the answers are more variable—in terms of women's natural childbearing abilities, women's physical structure (internal pollution), women's function as tokens of alliance, or women's symbolic roles in the family. None of these answers is very satisfactory; all use as explanations the very things that need explaining. We are still left with the paradox that male-defined structures represent themselves and conceptualize their unity and status through the purity of their women. I would argue then that all of these explanations can be lumped together and that they share a set of common failings. First, all are static functional accounts, and lack time depth. Second, all share the common functionalist fallacy of reifying the unit under study and treating it as closed, exclusive, and 260 Gender, Property, and the State isolated from a larger social context—the family, lineage, or caste is treated almost as a society in itself. And finally, all explanations, with the exception of the psychoanalytic discussion, take the point of view that the problem is one of male/male relations, in which the women are intermediaries, rather than the problem being, as it at least equally is, a problem of male/female relations. Although each of the arguments contains some useful kernel of truth, none provides a framework for encompassing and accounting for the phenomenon as a whole in cross-cultural, cross-class, and cross-sex perspective. What I should like to do in this paper, then, is to offer some observations, thoughts, suggestions, and hypotheses for exploring this problem more systematically, and in a way that will illuminate problems of social and cultural process in general, as well as male/female relations in particular. I would begin by noting that all of the modern cases of societies concerned with female purity are in fact of a certain type, namely, that all are part of, or have historically been part of, states, or at least systems with fairly highly developed stratification.' Thus hyperpure Brahmins and hyperpoor Mediterranean peasants share the status of being part-structures, elements in larger stratified political structures. Even when the larger state structures in which they originally developed are no longer organically intact, all of the modern groups in question bear the cultural ideologies, and particularly the religions, which were part of the organic emergence of their ancestral states in the first place. Most of the societies concerned with female purity are involved in so-called great traditions, especially Christianity, Islam, and Hinduism. And these religions evolved in conjunction with the emergence of states (or "civilizations," or empires) which, although most are no longer intact, nonetheless shaped the societies and cultures of the groups that bear their cultural heritages. And most of the peasants whose ancient states have decayed are now involved with modern states in ways that are structurally similar to their places in the original ones. It is true that there are pre-state societies which, for example, require the virginity of women at marriage, and probably the majority of human societies expect relative sexual faithfulness of women after marriage. But no pre-state societies, as far as I have been able to ascertain, evince the sort of pattern I am concerned with here—the ideological linkage of female virginity and chastity to the social honor of the group, such chastity being secured by the exertion of direct control over women's mobility to the point of lifetime seclusion, and/or through severe socialization of fear and shame concerning sex." What I am suggesting, then, is that this sort of concern with the purity of women was part of, and somehow structurally, functionally, and symbolically bound up with, the historical emergence of systematically stratified state-type structures, in the evolution of human society.9 Before examining what the purity of women might have to do with the emergence-of states, however, let me sketch very briefly; what I see as the patterns and tendencies of female/male relations in pre-state societies, or rather in contemporary societies that have historically been outside of known state sys-: terns, and that have not themselves evolved the social, political, and economic characteristics of states. I would begin with the point that there is always, even in the most primitive of known societies, some sort of asymmetry between the sexes. Even the most manifestly egalitarian of band societies accords some edge of authority or charisma or status to men, if only on the view that the big game that the men bring home is superior as food to the women's gathered produce. In slightly more complex band societies, it seems that there is always some sacred center or ritual from which women are excluded. And although women may have their sacred ceremonies, from which men are excluded, the male ceremonies are considered to be for the welfare of the group as a whole, while the women's ceremonies are specific to the welfare of women. Finally, in the most complex of the known band societies, primarily in Australia, male authority is asserted through, and reinforced by systematic control of the mar- riage system, the exchange of women and woods. Control of the marriage system, always in the hands of men, transforms diffuse authority or charisma into the beginnings of real power and control. Nonetheless, being bartered about in a system of marriage exchange is not the same thing as having one's day-today behavior and freedom of movement directly controlled, and in fact women in band societies evidently have a great deal of autonomy of action, as long as they comply with the legal rules of the game. There is also no ideology in these societies about protecting female purity. If anything, the ideology is just the reverse, and women are often seen as, to some degree, dangerous and polluting. According to Mary Douglas, pollution beliefs are systematically related to cultural category ambiguities and anomalies;11' the danger and pollution of women would seem to derive in large part from the fact that women systematically appear as ambiguous vis-a-vis two very important, and partly related, category distinctions that may be common to all human societies. The first distinction is the nature/culture dichotomy, and I have discussed at length elsewhere woman's ambiguity vis-a-vis this opposition. 11 The second is the structure/ antistructure, or order/disorder dichotomy, in which men and male groups are identified with structure, order, social organization itself. Insofar as women are moved around in marriage, in a social exchange system controlled by, and culturally seen as composed of, structured groups of men, women appear interstitial within the fundamental kinship architecture of society.1" Further, the ambiguity of women would derive not only from a marriage perspective; insofar as there is descent ideology, whether patrilineal or matrilineal, women are seen as "in between" in these sorts of systems as well, for descent groups (such as clans) see themselves as groups of males, with women as their reproductive agents. With respect to either or both of these oppositions— naaire/culture, stmcture/antisu-ucture—women may appear ambiguous, and hence potentially polluting and dangerous. And although none of the simplest hunting/gathering socie- The Virgin and The State 261 ties manifest the phobia about female pollution and danger that appears among, for example, New Guinea horticulturalists, most have a variety of taboos and avoidance rules that seem concerned with keeping at least some of the boundaries drawn. Now between hunting/gathering band societies on the one hand, and states on the other, there is obviously a vast range of types of societies, of widely varying structure and complexity. I have yet to find or devise a classification scheme that organizes all of them in some satisfactory evolutionary sequence. I will plow right through all this complexity, however, and simply say that through all the types of pre-state societies, female/male relations stay broadly within the pattern established over the range of band societies—from relatively mutualistic and balanced, to the extreme cases of sex antagonism, with male self-segregation, and strong expressions of fear of women as dangerous. But again the expression of and reaction to fear of women in those extreme cases, and here I am thinking largely of New Guinea and South America, involves exclusion of women, or attempts thereof, rather than systematic domination and control. My image here is the New Guinea or South American village, with the men huddled in men's houses in the center off-limits to the women, and the women strung out around the periphery in their individual huts with their uterine families. Even in North America, a much less extreme area on this score, we find the male sweat lodges, the kivas into which women are not allowed, and so forth. But as long as the women do not trespass on the off-limits areas, they have considerable autonomy of action, and indeed a certain edge of power insofar as they can appropriate and judiciously imply control of some of the powers with which the male culture endows them. As in band societies, the one area in which men do exercise systematic control over women is the marriage system. Again, however, there is no ideology that the women exchanged in marriage must be virginal, sexually naive, and mystically pure; nor is seclusion of women practiced as a means of controlling their sexuality. 262 Gender, Property, and the State Finally, however, we get to the great divide: the rise of the state. Here there is a radical shift of both ideology and practice. On the ground, we have the emergence of the patriarchal extended family. Indeed here for the first time the term patriarchy becomes applicable, because the structure involves the absolute authority of the father or other senior male over everyone in the household-all junior males and all females. And now women are for the first time brought under direct and systematic control, first by their natal families, and then by their husbands and their affinal kin. Among elites, one has the image of women being rounded up in great numbers and confined in harems and analogous arrangements elsewhere. Among the Brahmins of India, they are locked in great purdah palaces and never emerge into the world. The notion develops that men are directly responsible for the behavior of their women, rendering it part of every man's definition of self and manliness that "his" women never escape his control; his honor, and the honor of his group, are at stake. At the same time, there is a great shift in the ideology concerning women. Before they were dangerous, but now they are said to be in danger, justifying male protection and guardianship. Before they were polluting, and this had to be defended against, but now they are said to be pure, and to need defending. At the same time, one finds for the first time symbolic idealization of woman in the mother-aspect, rather than in the sexual-reproductive aspect. Eventually, as the symbol system gets itself together in one part of the world with which we are all familiar, the ideal woman emerges as all the best things at once, mother and virgin. Now the way in which I've described the pattern, and the way in which it might, at first glance, be viewed, is in terms of the domestication of women, a sort of Neolithic of the sexes wherein women, like plants and animals, were brought under control in the service of the race. Actually, however, my thinking is to envision the process in terms of the beginnings of the domestication of men, as part of a larger pattern of systematization of hierarchy and control in the evolution of state structures. I will return to this point later. In any case, the whole business is terriblv complex. What I shall do here is simply offer a brief checklist of points that I think would be important to consider in trying systematically to account for the changes in sex-role i ■ -lations and ideology that seem to be associated with the emergence of the state. The checklist consists of the following items, in no particular order: the question of diffusion, the question of changes in the division of labor, changes in religious thought, changes in family structure, and changes in marriage patterns. I shall only be able to say a few words about each, merely pointing in the direction I think investigation should go. Diffusion, first, is something that cannot be entirely ruled out. It is possible that the p; ■-tern I have described—idealization offemale chastity; ideology of protection, control, and seclusion of women—developed in one area of the ancient old world, and reached other early states through trade and other dif-fusionary mechanisms. Most of the known contemporary societies with this pattern are geographically contiguous, in a broad band from the circum-Mediterranean area, across the Middle East and southwest Asia, across India, and up into China.11 The new world indigenous states would thus have to be investigated for independent evolution of the pattern." Even if indicated, however, we know that diffusion in itself never explains very much, for peoples hear of many peculiar customs practiced by their neighbors, yet those practices will only be adopted if the Su-cial structural and ideological conditions are: ripe for their reception. That is, the diffusion would only have taken hold as independently developing societies evolved the sorts of structures within which such a pattern of sex role relations would be functional and meaningful. The second point, very briefly, is the question of whether changes in the division of labor may have motivated changes in sex-role relations and ideologies. One standard view has it that, with the rise of plow agriculture and/or systematic irrigation systems associ- 1 ated with the rise of states, women were excluded from major roles in the sphere of production, while their reproductive value in the family was more strongly emphasized. My own reading of the data is quite different. It is probably true that men became associated with plowing as a specific activity, and with the engineering and control of irrigation systems, and both of these points are quite important in the symbolics of male prestige. Nonetheless it seems that women continued to be fully productive, and if anything worked even harder than they did before, in both grain production in the western old world and rice production in the east. The gradual withdrawal of women from production (where it happened) was, I think, a very late development. It will thus not account for the emergence of the female purity pattern, although it will have repercussions in that pattern later. In the domain of religion, next, I would stress the point that an elaborated notion of purity in general only conies in systematically with the emergence of state structures. In pre-state societies, including the simplest that we know, one of course finds the notion that exceptional purity, often including temporary celibacy, is required for specific important purposes. Generally, it is associated with some major male undertaking—a hunt, a raid, or a ritual—and is conceived in terms of purifying or at least not polluting male energies, so that they will be strong and focused for the big event. Nonetheless, there is no notion that it would be good for some people, female or male, to strive for permanent exceptional purity, including permanent celibacy. Such notions probably come in with permanent standing priesthoods of some kind, and these of course are standard, virtually diagnostic, features of early states. If the chastity of priests was the first application of the notion of chastity to a social group, its rationale was probably similar to that for the episodic demands for purity in pre-state societies: the priest is charged with protection of sacred objects and activities, and he (or sometimes she) must be in a permanent state of non-pollution for thejob. But it would seem that there is more to it than The Virgin and The 5tate 263 this. In particular I would suggest that in state religions and cosmologies, what seems to happen is that the whole purity ceiling is raised, so to speak. That is, one finds systematic elaboration of higher realms of purity and sacredness than existed before, with more exacting demands upon the laity for conforming to religious ideals. Thus it may be a matter of the religion postulating higher, more sacred, and more demanding gods (e.g., the Aztec gods who required human sacrifice), and/or a more articulated after-death state (as, for example, in The Egyptian Book of the Dead). Transcendental power, divinity, sacredness, and purity are all more articulated than previously. It is not at all difficult to account for the emergence of such ideologies in state structures, in relation to the overall increased complexity of society—for example, more complex divine hierarchies may reflect more complex social hierarchies; or more demanding gods may reflect the greater demands of the state and the dominant classes; or more elaborated notions of afterlife may be interpreted as promising the newly emergent masses their rewards later rather than now, and so forth. The situation is of course infinitely more complex than this, but cannot be explored here. My point is simply that one would begin to investigate the elaboration of the notion offemale purity by contextualizing it in the emergence of systematic views of transcendental purity in state cosmologies in general. Purity as something that whole categories of people might intrinsically possess, or might systematically be required to sustain, as itself, I think, a product of state-related religious thought. Mind/body dualisms (reflecting, among other things, new divisions of labor between intellectual/artistic/political elites and producing masses), and the control of sexuality, sensuality, and materialism (part of, among other things, a delaycd-gratifica-tion, reduced-material-expectations, ideology for the masses) would be aspects of this general pattern. Coming down from the cosmological heights to ground-level social structure, the fourth item covers changes in the structure of 264 Gender, Property, and the State The Virgin and The State 265 the family. Again I will be very brief, although the problem requires detailed scrutiny. The key point is undoubtedly the emergence of the patriarchal family structure, and probablv ideally the patriarchal extended family. But the way in which I would look at this phenomenon, as I noted earlier, is in terms of the domestication of men, both as husbands/fathers, and as sons. Probably the catalyst around which the whole thing crystallized was the property holding in one form or another, although it was certainly not yet "private" property. Be that as it may, what I think was at issue was the gradual deepening of involvement of individual males in responsibility, as husbands/fathers, for their specific family units—not just economic responsibility, for that was always accepted, but also what might be called political accountability. The family became in a sense an administrative unit, the base unit in the political-economic structure of the state. The husband/father was no longer simply responsible to his family, but also/or his family vis-a-vis the larger system. It became the base, and often the only base, of hisjural status. Now, judging from contemporary cases, I imagine that such deepening involvement of men in families was accepted only reluctantly, and as part of a tradeoff for patterns of deference and respect from wives and children. The reluctance of males to be involved with their families except on terms of distance, respect, and submission on the part of the other members is still I think to be seen in most of the world today, and the domestication of men is still largely incomplete. Nonetheless, the notion that males are not only economically but also legally and politically responsible for the proper functioning of the family unit seems to be part of the systematic extension of principles of hierarchy, domination, and order in the evolution of states as a whole. Responsible husbands/fathers are more systematically incorporated into the system. Responsible husbands/lathers, which is to say in this context patriarchal husbands/fathers, in turn keep everyone else in line—the women, of course, but also the sons. Indeed, perhaps the most striking characteristic of the patriarchal family is the prolongation of dependence and subjugation of sons. This j. such an overdetermined phenomenon that one can hardly begin to sort out its sources and components. However, let it suffice to say that sons are held back from the acquisition of property, wives, and emotional maturity by such a powerful combination of forces, emanating from both father and mother, that it is certainly one of the key changes that we see in family structure, regardless of household composition (that is, regardless of whether /; the family is "extended" or not). Male initiation rites virtually disappear in state societies; and far from fathers and other senior males facilitating, however frighteningly, a young male's passage to adulthood, the young adult male in the patriarchal family remains in a ju-rally dependent status at least until he is married, and often beyond. In many cases marriage itself becomes the only rite of passage, and thus manhood becomes equated with responsibility for wife and children, part of the pattern described above. This pattern is likely to have certain psy-chodynamic implications. One may wish to go the Freudian route, in terms of deep unconscious factors, and I am not immune to the persuasions of a well-done Freudian analysis. ' • Kathleen Cough's paper on female initiation rites, mentioned earlier, is an excellent and very convincing Freudian discussion of the sorts of fears and ideals of women produced in such family situations in the Indian case. However, one can probably account for a lot without recourse to unconscious factors, through careful symbolic analysis of cultural notions of mothers and wives in such systems. The pivotal point of such analysis would be that men were not only "domesticated" as part of the crystallization of authority structures of the state; they were alsojuvenilized— vis-a-vis women, senior men, and the rulers and overclasses of the system. Note that I have not tried to postulate motives for either women or men in this process. I have suggested that men were "reluctant" about being domesticated, but I would imagine that women had equally mixed feelings about the greater presence of male authority in the family unit. I do not think it is useful to view this process in terms of (in Engels* famous phrase) "the world historical defeat of women" by men, or other such motivated formulations. The crystallization of patriarchal familv corporations was doubtless a precipitate of larger political and economic processes. Nonetheless, once it got going, it became a social force in its own right, affecting not only the further evolution of gender relations, but also the economic and political evolution of the larger system itself. The final item on the present checklist is the question of changes in marriage systems. I noted earlier that concern for the purity of women is found, in contemporary societies, among both elites and lower strata. In southern Europe, the peasants seem much more concerned about the issue than the upper classes; for elites the relative freedom of their women is a symbol of their modernity, or else simply a symbol of their being above the codes. In India or China, on the other hand, the Brahmins and tipper classes were far stricter about the purity of their women than the lower castes and the peasants. In trying to account for the emergence of a code of female purity as part of the emergence of the state, one would perhaps want to begin with the question of which stratum started the whole thing. Thus some might argue that it was probably originally an elite conceit, in that elite women (if not other women) did not need to engage in productive labor, and could be secluded and protected from the pollutions of work and people as a mark of upper-class status. One could argue with equal logic, however, that there are aspects of peasant social life and social structure that would generate a concern for the purity of women, as in jane Schneider's discussion previously noted. The way out of the puzzle, I would suggest, lies in stressing the stratified nature of the state as a totality, and seeking the dynamics of the process in the interaction between elites and lower strata. In particular, my analytic instinct is to look at patterns of hypergamy (up-status marriage, virtually always between upper men and lower women) in state sys- tems, and to consider very centrally the possibility that one of the significant developments in stratified societies was the shifting of marriage from an essentially lateral transaction, beUveen essentially equal groups, to at least a potentially vertical transaction, where in one's sister or daughter is potentially a wife or consort of a king or nobleman, or could be dedicated to the temple and the services of the priesthood. I think it is fairly safe to expect to find patterns and ideals of hypergamy, or what might be called vertical alliance, in stratified societies. Vertical alliance would constitute one of several sorts of paternalistic ties between the strata. But what analytic consequences flow from putting this point at the center of the analysis? In the first place, as has been noted by others for India, the assumption of systematic hypergamy as an ideal and to some extent as a practice will account for the phenomenon of women accumulating at the top of the system.1"' Because lower-status families are eager to many their women upwards for political reasons, the elites would accumulate wives. At the same time, the elites would often be unable to get rid of their own sisters and daughters, for there is nowhere further tip for those women to go. Thus the emergence harems, purdah palaces, and so forth, would partly be a structural precipitate of the hypergamy system, rather than an indication of (among other possibilities) the extraordinary lust of sultans. At the same time, the accumulation of wives by polygynous royalty and nobility would certainly have value in the symbolics of power, for it would suggest their potency in everything from sex to politics to the fertility of the land. Thus the image of herds of penned-up women that is projected in these sorts of systems ilows partly from the dynamics of the marriage system, and not from men rounding up and controlling women as such. Second, hypergamy may provide the strongest explanation for the purity ot women ideal and for certain peculiarities of this ideal. The context of hypergamy is a context of orientation toward upward mobility, through manipulation of marriages. We know 266 Gender, Property, and the State that the economic value of women becomes a focus in these contexts, for it is here that we find the emergence of dowry, enhancing the girl's value for a higher-status spouse.10 In addition, however, there is the question of her mystical or spiritual value, her inner worthiness for such an alliance. The notions of virginity and chastity may be particularly apt for symbolizing such value, rather than, for example, external beauty, because virginity is a symbol of exclusiveness and inaccessibility, nonavailability to the general masses, something, in short, that is elite. A virgin is an elite female among females, withheld, untouched, exclusive. The assumption of hypergamy would also account for one of the major puzzles of the female purity phenomenon, namely, that the women of a given group are expected to be purer than the men, that upon their higher purity hinges the honor of the group. I would argue that the women are not, contrary to native ideology, representing and maintaining the group's actual status, but are oriented upwards and represent the ideal higher status of the group. One of the problems with the purity literature, I think, has been a failure to get beneath native ideology; the natives justify female purity in terms of maintaining the group's actual status, as a holding action for that status in the system, when in fact it is oriented toward an ideal and generally unattainable status. The unattainability may in turn account for some of the sadism and anger toward women expressed in these purity patterns, for the women are representing the over-classes themselves. And finally, the hypergamy assumption gives us at least one clue about a girl's (or woman's) motivation for cooperation in her own subordination and control. For if she is a good girl, she has the potential for personal status mobility which in fact exceeds that of most of the men of her group. Here it becomes intelligible that it is often women themselves who actively reproduce the patterns of female purity, socializing their daughters in fear and shame of sex, telling them that it is for their own good (which in a way it is), and spying on and gossiping about one another's daughters as part of an overall deep internalization of and loyalty to the sy ■ tern. Again the point is the future orientation of the ideology, toward some often quite illusory but nonetheless remotely imaginable st; -tus mobility, which the girl herself internalizes as the "someday my prince will comt theme. It is no wonder too that women later " may resent their husbands as deeply as hu bands resent their wives—not only or eve necessarily because of the husbands' direi domination, but for what their husbands rep- • resent in status terms. For if the husband is of one's own status level, then one has saved all that purity for nothing, while if he is of the ideal higher status level, he is likely to be an undesirable mate who is willing to take a lowerclass wife because of some personal or social defect—some lecherous old Molierian widower, or someone of noble credentials but no money. A final point about hypergamy leads me to my brief conclusions. Note that, once again, women are crossing boundaries, in this case boundaries separating classes or castes or status groups in vertical stratification systems. Thus the ambiguity of femaleness vis-a-vis social categories remains at the core of the problem, and views of women remain bound in the purity/pollution idiom. Perhaps partly because the boundary crossing is in an upward direction, however, the symbohzation of ambiguity shifts from danger to purity, although the deep structure, if one may use that phrase, remains the same. At the ideological level, then, one may say that there has been a fairly simple structural transformation, and nothing much has changed in male attitudes toward and mistrust of women. It is clear in contemporary cultures with female purity ideologies, that women are still feared as ambiguous and dangerous creatures. Nonetheless I wish to close on an optimistic note. Levi-Strauss has suggested that there is no reason to assume that women and men would, if left to their own devices, form durable bonds of mutual interdependence.1' The phase of social evolution that I have been discussing may perhaps least depressingly be viewed as a long, painful, and unfinished moment in the dialectic of the evolution of such bonds.18 NOTES This paper was written as an informal taik. It was my first stab in thinking about the problem and is highly speculative. It is really designed to generate and orient further thought and research—my own and others. The version printed here is a very slightly (mostly stylistically) revised version of one printed in Michigan Discussions in Anthropology 2 (1976): 1-16. I am grateful to the editors of Feminist Studies for encouraging me to reprint it and to Michigan Discussions in Anthropology for permission to do so. 1. Quote on the seraglio from The Encyclopaedia Britannica, 15th ec!., s.v., "Harem." For a Latin American example, see Lawrence Watson, "Sexual Socialization in Guajiro Society," Ethnology 11 (1972): 150-56. For the Mediterranean, see Joseph K. Campbell, Honour, Family, and Patronage (Oxford, England: Oxford University Press, 1974); j. G. Peristiany, ed., Honour and Shame: The Values of Mediterranean Society (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1966); jane Schneider, "Of Vigilance and Virgins: Honor, Shame, and Access to Resources in Mediterranean Society," Ethnology 10, no. 1 (1971): 1-24. For the Middle East and South Asia, see Rose Oldfield Hayes, "Female Genital Mutilation, Fertility Control, Women's Roles, and the Patrilineage in Modern Sudan," American Ethnologist 2 (1975): 617-33; Hannah Papanek, "Purdah: Separate Worlds and Symbolic Shelter," Comparative Studies in Society and History 15 (1973): 298-325; Kathleen Gough, "Female Initiation Rites on the Malabar Coast," Journal of the Royal Anthropological Institute 85 (1955): 45-80; Nur Yalman, "On the Purity of Women in the Castes of Ceylon and Malaber,"_/o/