Inequality and Society; An Introduction JEFF MANZA i Some of us have more than others. This lias always been the case, inequality is a universal feature of all known human societies. But the amounts and types of inequality have varied a great deal in different times and places. Primitive hunting and gathering societies, for example, typically shared their (limited) food supplies and resources among all members of the group more or less equitably, although decision-making powers were wielded by tribal chiefs, and medicine men (known as shaman) had relatively privileged positions, In these primitive communities, mere survival was often in question, and there was little, if any, surplus left over after basic necessities were met and thus no significant opportunities for some individuals to gain at the expense of others. By contrast, the agrarian settlements and societies of the Middle Ages often produced more than was needed for survival, and, as a consequence, a handful of households were able to accumulate (sometimes considerable) fortunes, as were traders in early urban settlements. Political rule in agrarian societies was generally authoritarian, with power concentrated either in the hands of local or regional landowners or increasingly centralized under kings as modern 2 INEQUALITY AND SOCIETY states began to emerge. The tiny stratum of privileged economic and political elites in agrarian societies generally lived entirely apart from the rest of the population, and there were no significant "middle" classes like those of capitalist societies today. The resources and life chances possessed by the masses of agricultural laborers ("serfs") did not vary a great deal, at least within particular geographic regions, over the course of many centuries. If we fast-forward to the rich capitalist societies oftoday, such as the United States, we find a more complex picture. There are vast inequalities between the very richest individuals and families and the poorest, but there is also a large middle class that enjoys some of the benefits of economic growth and . surplus wealth. At the very top are individuals and families enjoying extraordinary wealth, unprecedented in human history. Fortune magazine does an annual survey of the richest people in America, and another on the richest in the world. Topping Fortune's analysis of the richest individuals in the world on August 31, 2007, were Microsoft founder and former chair Bill Gates, and Mexican telephone mogul Carlos Slim Helu, each possessing approximately SCO billion in wealth. Individual fortunes of this magnitude have happened only once before, during the late nineteenth and early twentieth centuries (an earlier epoch of global financial and economic boom). The richest of the famous moguls—sometimes known as "robber barons"—in that era was John D. Rockefeller, whose fortune likely exceeded $100 billion (in inflation-adjusted dollars) at its peak.' The pace at which the wealthy are getting wealthier has grown remarkably in recent years. One way we can see this is to took at the change in the amount of money required to be on Fortunes annual list of the four hundred richest Americans. In 1982, a mere S210 million (in inflation-adjusted 2007 dollars) was required to be among the richest four hundred. To simply make the very bottom of the list of the four hundred richest Americans today, however, SI.3 billion is now required. In other words, one needs more than ji'.v times as much wealth to be in that exclusive club today as twenty-five years . ago. And indeed, across the globe the rich have gotten richer and today collectively control an enormous share of the world's wealth. One recent study . i The exact lire of Rockefeller's fortune atits peak atound 1913 is difficult Id estimate with any precision. Rockefeller's bjonrapherRois Chernow estimates thai hisforlunepeaked at a value nfarotsnd $25 billion (its 1998 inflation-adjusted dollars), although etherestimates pm it DverSlOO billion {when the value of his philanthropy is included). See Louis Uchstcik, "The Richest of the Rich, Ptoild ofa New Gilded Ajze," iVrir' Yvtk Tivrirj, July 15, 2007, www.tiyHinM.com/20Q7/07/15/htisineK/l5ijilded. 3stinl (accessed July 15, 2007), Tluee other fortunes of the Gilded eta may alio bavc exceeded the Gatrs/51int HcKi fortunes: thnic of Cornelius Vaniletbilt, John Jacob Aitor, arid Stephen Girard. Inequality mtd Society: An Introduction 3 i^amwSEj ....... estimates that the top 1 percent of the world's population controls about 32 percent all the world's wealth, whereas the bottom 30 percent of the world's population controls less than t percent.3 The global financial crisis and stock market decline, beginning in the fall of2008, however, have eroded some of the fortunes held at the top.;. Below the top, an educated upper middle class, made up of people working in salariedjobs in professional and managerial occupations, has grown steadily in size over the past hundred years. Dependirigon exactly how we define this group, it has increased from somewhere around 1 percent of the U.S. population at the turn of the twentieth century to 15 percent or mote early in the twenty-first century. Professionals, business executives, and business managers typically receive incomes sufficient to own attractive homes and expensive cars, to be able to travel extensively, and to provide their children with many educational and cultural advantages. Their educational credentials and knowledge make it much easier for professionals and managers to build stable career paths, even in a 21st-century economy in which few stay with a single firm their entire working life. Many of the workers directly supervised by professionals and managers—nurses, paralegals, technicians, office managers, secretaries, salespeople,.and others—work in safe, clean environments and receive incomes that put them ill the broader "middle class," even if they cannot afford the lifestyles of their bosses. "When we turn our attention to the vast majority of American society below the very top and the upper middle class, however, the picture darkens considerably. For the more than 70 percent of Americans without a college degree, the economic environment is increasingly challenging. Tn the transition from a largely industrial economy to the postindustrinl economies of the twenty-first century, there has been a drastic reduction in the number of well-paying blue-collar jobs, and a corresponding decline in opportunities overall for this group. If we want to understand inequality in America today, the lives and well-being of the rton-college-educated majority require special attention. For this group, entering the labor market has become more difficult, as has finding a secure occupational niche. Instability is also very high; even those who find a decent job at one point cannot be sure to still have that job in a lew years. America has one of the highest rates of economic instability among the rich countries in the l James D. Davics, Susanna Sandstroits, Anthony Shorrdckj, and Edward N. Wolff. "Estimating the Level and Diitriuislion of dorsal Household Wealth," World Institute for Development Economics Research, of the United Nations University, WIDER. Reiearch Paper, 2007/77 (November 20U?): 27, www.widcr.uiiu.edu/public3tions/wntkuin-papen/reseatch-paper5/2007/en_GIl/tp2007-77 (accessed April 300B). 4 INEQUALITY AND S0C1LTY r r t ill H HP world. It is a distinct possibility that at some point in dieir lives, those without a college education will experience one or more significant bouts of unemployment that will drain their savings and threaten their well-being. Another important aspect of inequality in America is that the economic gains of the past three decades have not been shared by most of its population. Although household income in the very middle (at the 50th percentile, or median) has grown slightly faster than inflation since the early 1970s, the share of income received by the "median" family has slipped. The trends over the past thirty years stand in stark contrast to the pattern of the thirty years before that (from the end of World War tl through the mid 1970s), when the middle class not only shared equally in the benefits of economic gtowth but actually saw its share of national income increase relative to those of the very rich. For tliose at the very bottom, the situation is even bleaker. Recent economic gains have done little to improve living standards for poor Americans, while changes in public policy have eroded access to many government benefits that can make life more secure for the poorest of families. To be sure, poverty rates, while fluctuating from year to year, have not shown an overall increase during the era of rising inequality. This is an important point, one that is sometimes overlooked in discussions of rising inequality. Generally low unemployment rates in America since the mid 1990s have helped the adults in the poorest families boost their employment income and have u nquestionably prevented even worse outcomes from occu rring. Yet many of thosejobs are dead-end, paying low wages and offering few opportunities for advancement. And poverty rates in America remain very high by comparison with other rich capitalist countries. Moreover, changes in the criminal justice system since the early 1970s have given rise to high criminal conviction rates and "mass" incarceration (with over two million Americans currently housed in prisons and jails, and some seventeen million Americans with felony convictions on their records). Skyrocketing rates of felony convictions, during a period when crime has been mostly stable or declining, has made life more difficulr for many poor families and their children. And, finally, the poor are much more likely today to live in neighborhoods with a high percentage of other poor families. Such neighborhoods with concentrated poverty are likely to have high crime rates, dangerous environmenta! conditions, and typically lack jobs and sometimes even basic services. This book examines many of the most important types of inequality in the United States, and compares the United States to other countries across the globe. It brings together a number of important pieces of research and theoretical writings on inequality that have been produced by sociologists, rucijiiiilify fiiiiJ Society: An InUmhiaian 5 economists, political scientists, and philosophers. Our aim is to provide a multtlnyered understanding, in which inequalities between individuals and groups (especially those based on race, gender, and class) are linked to public policies and situated in a global economic context. Sociologists have developed a concept for the ways in which inequalities are interconnected: the stratification system. Stratification refers to the full range and sources of inequality: inequalities arising from economic markets as well as between groups and those rooted in, or reinforced by, social and political institutions as well as global social and economic trends. Although no single theory of stratification can account for its multiple dimensions, when we think about inequality as an interconnected stratification system we are compelled to explore how the parts fit together. Although the political sources of inequality are sometimes acknowledged as important components of the stratification system as a whole, the ways in which political inequality reinforces social and economic inequality is frequently overlooked. Consider the fallowing example. A household with two children headed by a single mother without 3 college educarion is more likely to be poor than is 3 similar household headed by a college-educated couple in all societies today. Yet there can be enormous variation among countries in the percentage of such single-mother households that actually live below the poverty line. In 2000, about 6 percent of children in these households were estimated to live in poverty in Denmark, 22 percent in Switzerland, 31 percent in Germany, hut about 50 percent of children in such families in the United States were estimated to live below the poverty line.' These are large and substantial differences. One of our key innovations in this book is to link important social and economic aspects of inequality to political institutions and public policies. "Wq have thus included a variety of readings that take up facets of public policy and political representation alongside other major aspects of inequality in order to provide a fuller view of the American stratification system. Some of the readings collected here are classics, while others represent influential and/or significant pieces of contemporary scholarship. The selections arc grouped together in a way that facilitates linkages among them, although we imagine most readers will focus on a subset of the readings. In the rest of this introduction, I provide a brief summary of the book's framework, and some suggestions about how to approach the readings. 3 These eiiimiieiuederivEdJioiii data collected by die ciinortlhsary LiixumtiuTB income Study (LIS) Key Figures. www.liiproJeci.ots/keyfijjiirei/diiHrioviiiiei.lirm jaccencd April 3(108). 6 INEQUALITY AND SOCIETY Inequality mtii Society: An Inlioitiiclioii J III UNDERSTANDING INEQUALITY Why should we study inequality? We are intrinsically fascinated by tile lives of the rich and famous and perhaps concerned, as citizens, with the sources and justice of the distribution of wealth and poverty. But understanding the patterning of inequality in a country like the United States also helps us understand, in fundamental ways, the very nature of the society and world we live in. For one thing, inequality in any one domain can have a number of important "spillover" consequences. For example, economic inequality skews the distribution of non-monetary rewards and benefits, like access to health care. In highly unequal societies like the United States, the rich get state-of-the-art treatment but absorb far more than their pro-rata share of medical care, whereas the poor are often less healthy than they would be with the same income in a more egalitarian society. The maldistribution of medical care helps account for why the United States has a higher rate of infant mortality—and does worse on other well-measured health outcomes—than virtually all other rich countries, even though we devote a far higher portion of our gross national product to health care than anyone else. There are three important starting points for trying to understand the kinds ofinequalities we find in the United States and throughout the world, both in the past and at the present. First, as we have already noted, there is enormous variation in the stratification systems of different societies. Looking around the world today, we find large differences in the levels of inequality different societies permit. Socialist countries—such as Cuba today and the countries of Eastern Europe and the former Soviet Union before 1989—minimized private enterprise and regulate wages and living standards through centralized government planning. Although there were significant inequalities in the privileges enjoyed by party members and other elites (known as the nomenklatura) versus everyone else in socialist countries, these societies generally had much lower overall levels of inequality than ibund in contemporary capitalist countries. In continental western Europe, a more tegulated capitalist market economy and mote generous welfare states have led to a significant reduction in levels of poverty and inequality, especially compared to the United States. Many of the countries with the highest levels of inequality today are countries experiencing rapid social or economic change, such as Russia, China, South Africa, and several countries in South America. In these places, a tiny stratum of the super-rich control levels of wealth similar to those found among the wealthiest Americans and Europeans. But large majorities of the populations in these countries have seen only limited benefits from economic restructuring and indeed may face rising costs for basic goods (especially housing) that offset much of whatever increased household income they have gained. Understanding inequality thus requires exploring how different national and regional contexts produce different patterns of inequality. The second starting point lies in recognizing there are a wide variety of different inequalities in any society. There arc economic inequalities (such as income and wealth), political inequalities (such as power), and social inequalities (such as those based on race, ethnicity, religion, and gender and the different kinds of social status and prestige they give rise to). Social inequalities in particular are elusive and historically contingent. For example, different racial and ethnic groups are found in virtually all contemporary societies, but whether and how those differences matter for the patterning of inequality depend on a great deal on public policies regulating economic and political life. In the contemporary United States, African Americans and Latinos face discrimination in the labor market, a racially segregated housing market, and harassment by police and higher rates of incarceration in the criminal justice system. The practice and legal foundation of discrimination, however, has not stayed the same over time; it underwent enormous changes with the adoption of civil rights legislation in the 1960s. Those measures, and affirmative action programs developed later, have helped spur the growth of a black middle class by increasing opportunities for some African Americans to attend top universities and gain entry to desired economic opportunities that would have seemed nearly unimaginable sixty years ago. Or, to take another example, in the late nineteenth century, immigrants from Ireland and southern Europe faced enormous hostility and negative stereotyping. Indeed, some historians have argued that immigrant groups like the Irish, Italians, and Slavs had to become "wh ite" to end discrimination and integrate into the American mainstream. This was a protracted process. But between the late nineteenth century and World War II, all of these groups did become white and thus gained a measure of economic and political equality with more established northern Europeans. Our third starting point is that the relationship among different types of inequalities—and how they change over time—is critical for understanding the bigger picture. The study of how different kinds ofinequalities are linked is what forms the stratification system of any society. One type of inequality may exacerbate other types ofinequalities, depending on the context. For example, differences in the amount of income or wealth a family possesses will influence the educations! achievements of its children, irrespective of S INEQUALITY AND SOCIETY Inequality ami Society: An Introduction how hard children work in school. Conversely, the existence of class and/or racial inequality ran in some contexts reduce gender inequality, by providing a ready-made supply of low-wage domestic workers who can, in turn, free up educated women from time-consuming domestic chores such as housework and raising children. For a long time, scholarship on inequality did not systematically examine these interactions, but they have become the focus of much recent research. These three themes—the variations in stratification systems, the multiple sources ofinequality, and the relationships among inequalities—define the challenges we face in understanding inequality and the stratification system of a society like the United States. ill CLASSICAL THEORIES OF INEQUALITY Part I of this book starts with some classic treatments ofinequality and social stratification, works that continue to shape debates right up to the present. Adam Smith's (1723-1790) influential writings on the division of labor inspired Karl Marx's (1818-1883) elaboration of the sources and consequences of class divisions in capitalist and other societies. For Smith, a division of labor between individuals and the development of markets to efficiently allocate the fruits of that labor allow for a vast increase in wealth and productivity. Marx developed a radically different conception of the meaning of the division of labor and die consequences of the rise of market capitalism, For Marx, the rise of the division of labor creates the possibility for some people to exploit others. His concept of "class" provided both a set of analytical tools for understanding major inequalities across different types of societies, as well as the foundation of a theory of history based on the idea that class singles are the crucial mechanism for the transition from one type of society to another. Whether or not we agree with the mode! of revolution and historical change he developed, Marx has served as a critical touchstone for the development of subsequent research and theory on stratification systems. This is true even though most later scholars and writers on inequality do not situate themselves in the Marxist tradition. For many sociologists, the writings of the German sociologist Max Weber (1864—1920) provides one basis for moving beyond Marx. Weber called attention to the limitations of an analysis ofinequality centered solely on class, noting that other kinds of social attributes, most importantly those based on honor or "status," could also serve as wellsprings ofinequality. Status inequal- ity, for Weber, is especially consequential as individuals with similar status situations or identities coalesce into what he called "status groups." The most important of these status group memberships are those involving race or ethnicity, although many other types of statuses have provided the foundation for group memberships in different societies. Weber also pioneered the idea that alongside Marx's notion of exploitation, we need to pay attention to the ways in which groups mobilize to restrict the opportunities of other, less powerful groups. Marx's focus on class inequality did not contain much room within it Tor a complex theory of how race, ethnicity, and/or gender provide the basis for bath meaningful identities and group-based conflicts. Weber's insights, by contrast, were paralleled in the work of scholars beginning to theorize and study the origins and types of racial and gender inequality. In the remarkable work of sociologist W. E. B, Du Bois (1868-1963), social divisions such as those based on race (and the ideas they give rise to) are the result of political struggles rather than on any biological characteristic of individuals or groups. In his historical writings, especially his monumental study of the past-Civil War era, Du Bois developed the notion that the politics of racial struggle— not class—lay at the center of the peculiar development of American political institutions. Although he was explicitly concerned with the dynamics of race in America, Du Bois's ideas have obvious parallels to, and heavily influenced, later scholarship on ethnic and gender inequality. Another line of critique aimed at M arx came from sociological writers after World War II drawn to "functionalist" theories of societies. The key idea of functionalist sociology was that societies evolve in response to critical needs of social order. In their 19'!5 manifesto, one of the most widely discussed (and debated) works about inequality ever written by sociologists, Kingsley Davis and Wilbert Moore argued (without direct attribution) that Marxist claims that inequality was an artificial human construction that could be abolished in some future communist society were impossible. Inequality, they asserted, is a necessary condition of all known human societies, and for good reason. It provides individuals with the incentives to work and produce and, even more important, motivates the most talented members of society to prepare themselves to perform the most important tasks (and perform them well). Although the kind of functionalist reasoning employed by Davis and Moore has largely fallen out of fashion in the contemporary social sciences, the argument they develop about why inequality is universal remains a core point of departure for contemporary debates. 4- 10 INnqUALITY AND SOCIETY ititsjiiii/ity r o FijfrC Viinl P.iHy Polllla in Awattä (New York: Roul-icdrje, 201)2). IS INEQUALITY AND SOCIETY Inequality ami Society: An Iittmtlueiimi 2p ' •. v < (-Hi in a coherent spectrum, providing citizens with information that reminds them of egalitarian ideas and values, as the extensive literature on the cognitive bases of political beliefs suggests. When the party system includes strong left parties, political debates in the media are much more likely to include pro-equality viewpoints, and media coverage of groups and individuals making egalitarian arguments grows. In the United States, however, such views are only more haphazardly present in ordinary political debate. The narrowness of the party system does not mean that egalitarian political ideas have always been absent from American politics. At times since the 1890s, and in certain parts of the country, the Democratic Party has operated as a kind of social democratic party, with organized labor and liberal groups having varying degrees of influence inside the party. But the Democratic Party has also, throughout its history, been strongly influenced by its strong southern wing, following the Civil War and the identification of the Republican Party with the cause of racial equality. The southern Democrats were deeply hostile to any policies challenging the Jim Crow system, which greatly narrowed the range of acceptable possibilities for egalitarian public policies even in those eras, such as the 1930s and 1960s, when momentum for equality peaked. Political Money Anothersource ofpolitical inequality is the unique role ofmoney in the financing of American politics. Dramatic increases in the availability ofmoney in the American political system in recent decades have often prompted concern among observers of American politics and sometimes among the very politicians living inside the money system. Rising inequality and strong income growth at the top have given the rich more resources to "invest" in politics, and they have. The basic facts are startling enough. Campaign finance data (Figure 3} suggests that since 1978, there has been a nearly 10-fold increase in real dollars contributed by business interests to candidates for American national elections as well as a steady and seemingly inexorable growth in contributions from affluent individuals. One would be hard-pressed to imagine that contributors give large amounts and get nothing in return, although specifying those impacts has proved tricky for researchers. Where does this extraordinary flow ofpolitical money come from? The reporting of campaign contributions is now quite systematic, so we can develop a basic survey, Contributions come from individual donors or from political action committees (PACs) organized by a wide range of individual FIGURE 3 trends IK national election campaign finance, 197u-zdog 2,500 2,000 1.500 P 1,000 500 1978 !98o 1981 l»8.l 19B6 1988 1990 19!» 1994 '95* M>»8 vmo *°<» MD"> Year Total Business H Tola! Labor □ Total Ideological ■ Total Individual sounce: Author's Compilation, Federal Election Commission Reports (www.fec.gov) and Center for Responsive Politics (www.npcnsecteis.org). Individual contribution data available for 1992 on. businesses, business associations, unions, and professional associations, as well as ideological groups such as the National Rifle Association (NRA) and Emily's List (a PAC that supports women candidates for office). PAC contributions can be reasonably divided into three broad categories: business related, labor, and ideological (with the latter running the gamut from fir left to far right). !n addition to money given by organized PACs, individuals account (lists SOCIETY Iiuqmilily ami Somty: An hiln&uction 31 1 wMKc for a large proportion of total donations, die vast majority of which arc made by affluent individuals or families.13 Combining the rising amounts being given by affluent individuals with the growing disparities between business and labor PACs, we find that from the standpoint of who gives there can be little doubt that the signals imparted to elected officials overwhelmingly favor the affluent. How and in what ways does political money matter? Theories of "investor" influence on the parties and legislation have, as I noted, proved difficult to definitively test and prove. It is not often that there is hard evidence of outright vote buying. The primary effect, of money can be thought of as shaping four distinct political outcomes: (1) who runs for political office (making a serious run for political office increasingly requires the capacity to raise huge amounts of money), (2} who wins (underfunded challengers face an almost impossible task), (3) the voting patterns of legislators (who may think about the needs of past, present, or hoped-for future donors), and (4) other outcomes such as facilitating access to legislators through the interest group process. At every stage of this process, there are compelling arguments and empirical evidence to suggest money skews outcomes; but equally important, in no area is money plausibly viewed as the single decisive factor. Stronger arguments can be mounted for more subtle forms of influence, such as access to elected officials that money provides. Donors are much more likely to receive the opportunity to press their case to elected officials they have donated to than those who do not give. Such access may shape legislation at the margins, for example rhrough the creation of special hidden tax breaks or exemptions inserted into legislation that can, in the aggregate, be quite expensive and deleterious to the overall purpose of a bill. Access ensures that special interests arc listened to. But access alone docs not drive the policy agenda. Of perhaps equal or greater concern in relation to political money is its impact on agenda-setting organizations. Increasingly centralized corporate : For cvample, id 2dit!so (lite average donation was JSCs). Set Verba, Scholimais, and Brady, I'mVcW Bpallly, pp. lni-lSS, f a control over the media and the decline af independent media weakens advocacy of progressive causes such as calls for more equality. The remarkable growth in the resources Sowing into consctvativc think tanks and foundations is perhaps even more important. Starringin the 1970s, business organizations and conservative foundations began providing resources on a heretofore unprecedented scale in support of policy formation organizations inside the Beltway. The growing capacity of these policy organizations to intervene in political debates, get their representatives into the media, and provide policy advice to presidents and Congress is well established. By all accounts, such organizations play a significant tole in setting the policy agenda. To the extent that the policy organizations with the greatest resources are disproportionately promoting a conservative policy agenda—as numerous studies have found—they contribute to a larger environment in which many egalitarian policy ideas are simply not on the agenda for discussion." Ill GLOBAL INEQUALITIES The system of inequality in the United States, as in other countries, is heavily influenced by being situated in a global economy in which high levels of poverty and inequality ace found. In Part V, several key aspects of the global system of inequality are examined. One of the most important widely discussed subjects in recent years is how the changing patterns of the global economy arc influencing inequality in difTetcnr countries, as well as the distribution of wealth between countries. Three changes in recent decades define the current era of rising globalization. First, there has been a steatly increase in "Hows" across borders: more trade between countries, higher rates of migration across borders (rising rates of immigration into the United States mirror the pattern found in many other rich countries), and—perhaps most important—capital for investment that is increasingly unconstrained by national borders. Many firms have found it profitable to relocate their operations from higher-wage wealthy countries to places in which they can find workers at a fraction of the cost. Truly multinational corporations, with operations in numerous countries, increasingly populate the peaks of the modern world economy. Workers travel across borders in growing numbets in pursuic 13 Tise absence of competing and similarly endowed policy organizations promoting prnrjressive ideas has remained something of a mystery. Foundations supporting programs aimed at lidping, tile poor and proeresiive civic activism have resources that far exceed that of conservative foundations sup. porting right-wing thins: utiii and policy orrjaniiatiotts. But these organiialitMi have nor invested in ideas Its neatly the same degree as the leading com creative foundations. Si .111111 INEQUALITY AND SOCIETY litetjualHy ami Society: An introduction JJ of economic opportunities. The global financial sector has become interconnected such that when something significant happens in the financial market of one country it will influence developments in many other parts of the world. Second, alongside increased flows of trade, capital, and people have been changes in the hierarchy of countries across the globe (and the corresponding incomes and wealth of citizens in those countries). Some countries— especially countries in Southeast Asia like South Korea, Taiwan, Singapore, and more recently Brazil, Russia, China, and India—have and/or are expecting booming economic growth. Other countries, including most countries in Africa, have stagnated or even seen economic declines. Because the two largest countries in the world—China and India, with nearly one third of the world's population—are getting richer, as evidenced by rising household incomes and increasingly powerful domestic and global companies, overall global inequality has declined in recent decades. But the pattern of change has been uneven. Third, the global economy has often been seen as a source of internal social and economic change, contributing to rising infra-country inequal ity in recent years. In this sense, the seemingly rosy picture of declining belt wen-country inequality risks masking Dther inequality-producing aspects of globalization. The United States is far from alone in experiencing rising domestic inequality. The global economy has produced a class of global entrepreneurs who manage business or financial empires across borders, and receive extremely high levels of compensation to do so. It encourages companies to shift higher-wage manufacturing jobs to parts of the world in which wages are low. It creates opportunities for some but disadvantages for many others. The ovcral 1 impact of globalization on intra-country inequalities is complicated, interacting in ways that make assessment difficult. Finally, the rise of an increasingly global economy is often thought to threaten the autonomy of national governments. The idea is that if the government in a country like Germany or the United States were to raise taxes too high, let government budget deficits get too big, or provide overly generous government benefits for individuals, increasingly mobile international companies would be reluctant to maintain their investments in the German or American economy. Such a scenario would put powerful pressures on the government to conform to a lower-tax, lower-spending preference for companies seeking good investment returns. This theory has, however, only partially borne out by developments over the last twenty years. Three outcomes appear consistent with the globaliza- tion thesis. Unemployment levels are on average higher in the last twenty years than they were in the twenty years before that. Unions—the backbone of the social forces that helped create the welfare state in the ftcst place—are in decline, frequently sharp decline, in almost all countries. And there has been a movement toward more "workfare" and service spending in the mix of programs supported by welfare states rather than cash grants (or "welfare") programs. But the evidence that globalization undermines the capacity of governments to maintain generous welfare states has not yet occurred. Overall welfare state spending has not retrenched; while there is some evidence of year-to-year fluctuation in spending (depending on the rate of such factors as unemployment), the overall trend is clear: with but a couple of exceptions, countries have maintained generous levels of welfare state spending, even in the face of globalization. lit DOES INEQUALITY MATTER? The final section of the book is devoted to explorations of questions about how and why inequality matters. There are a variety of ways in which we might think about whether, or to what extent inequality matters. The high levels of inequality in the United States, compared to other rich democratic countries, means that the poor have fewer resources to acquire needed goods and services than they would in more egalitarian countries (and in the United States, the rich have vastly more to spend than the rich in other countries). This is a vitally important fact in its own right. The further down the income distribution, the more difficult it becomes for families to meet basic needs. Another important consequence has been that economic prosperity has not been shared. While all Americans benefited in economic growth between the end of World War II and the early 1970s, that pattern has not held more recently. The very highest earning households have absorbed the bulk of the income being generated, whereas the college-educated population has seen more modest gains, and everyone else has largely stagnated. But beyond the consequences of rising inequality for household well-being and shared prosperity, what else can be said? A few issues are worth paying attention to. One is political. Rising wealth at the top makes it easier for affluent individuals to "invest" in the political system, and the interests and concerns of the rich are unlikely to be those of the rest of the population. Inequality of income and wealth may be linked to a variety of other kinds of outcomes that raise concerns. Rich families can purchase better education and intellectual enrichment for their children than poor Families, raising the 34 INEQUALITY AND SOCIETY inequality and Society: An Inlrathtctitm 35 possibility that meritocracy may be undermined by unequal inputs into the training and development of children. Medical care appears at least in part to be more unevenly distributed in incgalitarian societies; the rich receive more than their pro-rata share of health care, and hospitals and other medical facilities may be oriented marc toward the needs and interests of their (more profitable) affluent clients. Rising inequality tends to create pockets of concentrated poverty, where survival may depend on the acquisition of a capacity for "street smarts" and even violence which is frowned upon in middle-class settings. Another consequence of inequality is its consequences for happiness and satisfaction. To the extent that people look up to those who have more than they do, they never feel completely satisfied with the possessions they do own. Most Americans want bigger houses, faster cars, fancier jewelry, and so forth. One important consequence of this for many American families has been a willingness to take on high levels of debt to try to attain such lifestyles. The size of the debt burden carried by American families was one factor in the financial crisis that began in the fall of2008. "Luxury fever," as the economist Robert Frank calls it, also affects subjective well-being—we arc never fully satisfied with what we have. Even though America has higher average incomes than virtually all other countries in the world, we are no happier as a consequence. International surveys show that Americans are not as satisfied as would be expected based on average income levels. Ill CONCLUDING THOUGHTS As students of inequality, we want to try to understand the vast and multifac-etedways in which inequalities have developed and how they operate to create a system of stratification. The organizing approach of this book is to highlight not just the brute facts of inequality between individuals and groups, and how these are changing in the current era of rising inequality, but also to situate these facts in historical and political context. Looking around the world, we find strong vibrant economics in societies with widely differing levels of inequality. More egalitarian countries, like many of those in Western Europe, manage to provide both high average incomes and at the same time, low rates of poverty. These outcomes are the result of conscious policy choices. It is not so much that America has higher rates of poverty and inequality because of the structure of its economy—although that is one factor—but also because, relative to our peer nations, we have political institutions and public policies that foster, rather than blunt, the forces of inequality. It is for this reason that our approach in this book is to highlight the role of politics, and a political analysis of inequality, alongside the questions that social scientists mote typically ask about stratification systems. This does not mean that classical approaches can be neglected. Indeed, we start by examining classic theories of inequality because these theoretical ideas provide an important poi nt of departure for contemporary understa ndings. At the same time, however, much intellectual progress has also been made in the past half century, as indeed we would expect. The classics of the field focused heavily on class inequality but often treated capitalism as an undifferentiated economic system. Mare recently, however, it has become clear that there is wide variation across time and space in how different types of capitalisms produce different kinds of stratification systems. Much attention has been focused on questions of class inequality and on rising tevels of inequality and wealth in an effort to chart the sources Df the changes that underpin these phenomena. Wi have developed much better and more sensitive tools for measuring economic inequality and broader theories for understanding how economic inequalities manifest themselves in other ways. If there is one overriding conclusion that this survey into the state of inequality and the stratification system in America leads us to, it is that nothing is set in stone. There have been striking changes in the types of inequalities found around the world and in the United States over the past 150 years. A simiiarpattcrn can be expected to continue into the future. Indeed, the financial crisis that began in the fall of2008 may well lead to significant changes in stratification systems in the United States and across the globe in the near future. Although the study of the sources and consequences of inequalities cannot by itself resolve the normative and philosophical questions of how much inequality is desirable or justifiable, it does provide a critical basis for thinking about some of the most pressing social questions of our age. m$wßm mméM Blil HHGBÍwfj THE PERFECT BALANCE PF CLASSIC READINGS AND CONTEMPORARY re ~ ~ > " • - — ... -t c- «1 ■ ^(..... n> a "2. i" 2 w =r -fr o O <• -J " w 3! °> w ~>. s tr CD Uhl V Sil* .4L V. M* « Í» J, l *»1 Mi"t~ MvTOJM H MV Inequality and Society includes Hid esseiilial classics on, ncqoahty as w ° coiitrihiitions from \m\a3's sociBlo»,sls Worts liy Kail Marx, W E. B uii bois, -C. Wriglit Mills, anil T. H. MarsliallaniJear alongside exciting sefectrons by scliolars such as Daiton Ccdey, Rosalieth Kanter, Leslie iVcCall, and Amartya Spii THE DNLY INEQUALITY READER TO ADDRESS POLITICAL INEQUALITY r1,; ! Pi ■. ' 1 !'L illÉ l|l ' \ 7 ' 1 r \1 * i !' 1 ) ' . \ í / TI i _: . 1 ■ ■ 1 / IPSA w Uli 11 ^ial'Science Perspectives on Social Stratification >>mmum »••> .. - is*-- » SI i lii siMitioii lo cohering classic topics in inequality studies, Manza and Sander adiliess tlie tBfeaiiWslsif -iif^íected rrliitiDii* : IiDiv in cnuajiív un inpiju.ility an: ica vinš afferteri h s of political jinrlif stem Hint nnviienc lohtjcal institutu,... lDlicies ttiat uiccnii 1fioi,i Vicnh unions ■"nnnnfmni IFřF liňll nf Mm ft li ■s ......... .... 4240773661