CHAPTER 7 THE STATE Who controls the economy: firms or governments? Aims • To understand how state and supra-national institutions shape economic processes • To recognize the different kinds of states within the global economy • To appreciate the changing role of the state in an era of globalization • To demonstrate why geographical scales matter in the reconfiguration of the state. 7.1 Introduction On 22 June 2005, China National Offshore Oil Corporation (CNOOC) made an unsolicited US$18.5 billion cash offer to woo Unocal (the Union Oil Company of California) from the latter's American suitor, Chevron, The bid apparently made a lot of sense to CNOOC, China's third largest state-owned oil company, because a successful takeover would allow it to tap into Unocal's huge oil and natural gas reserves in Asia. CNOOC's cash bid was also 15 per cent more than Chevron's offer of US$16.5 billion. Three days after CNOOC had announced its intention to discuss its takeover bid with Unocal and the US regulator, however, a group of 41 US Congressional representatives asked the US government to closely scrutinize CNOOC's bid on the grounds that China might gain control of precious US energy resources at a time of sky-high oil prices and growing tensions over China's huge trade surplus with the US. The representatives also asked the US Treasury Department to review the possible stripping of Unocal's core technology and assets by CNOOC. As the political pressure mounted, the House of Representatives voted in favour of forbidding the Treasury Department from using federal funds to process a recommendation 188 ACTORS IN ECONOMIC SPACE for the approval of CNOOC's bid. On 3 August 2005, CNOOC decided to drop its bid for Unocal, blaming US political opposition to the deal. This example of the proposed acquisition of a privately-owned US oil company by its state-owned Chinese counterpart illustrates the inherent limits to the global reach of such giant corporate entities: even though CNOOC's bid was financially more attractive than Chevron's offer, the final verdict effectively remained in the hands of the US state. Like other failed attempts to buy into 'corporate America', this example showcases the complex political-economic issues involved in the globalization of firms and the continued importance of nation-states in the political-economic governance of their domestic economies. It also reiterates the fact that the nation-state retains important regulatory controls of its national space-economy in an era of accelerated globalization of economic activities. With large firms becoming increasingly globalized, they are likely to confront different national regulatory regimes and to engage in tussles over the control of their economic interests vis-a-vis the nation-state. As this suggests, as we move into Part III, we are switching the focus to the key actors in economic space, and the role they play in creating economic geographies: the four chapters focus on the role of the state, transnational corporations, workers and consumers, respectively. As we know from our understanding of the commodity chain developed in Chapter 4, in reality these actors are interconnected and interdependent. In this Part of the book, however, we focus on each actor individually in order to explore their importance and influence in more detail. In this chapter we will explore the extent to which the state remains a powerful shaper of economic geographies. We will profile the ongoing role of the nation-state in economic governance, and shed light on the changing abilities of nation-states to address political-economic processes such as uneven development, economic restructuring, and poverty. This integral role of the nation-state in the modern economy highlights an important point - the economy is inter-meshed with the politics of the nation-state at a variety of geographical scales. As will be explained more explicitly later in this chapter, these state politics may be about inter-national geopolitical imperatives such as the failed CNOOC bid above, debates within a particular macro-regional grouping of states such as the European Union, the intra-national politics of resource transfers and investment within nation-states, or local politics. In all instances, we simply cannot underestimate the continued significance of the state for our understandings of the dynamics of economic development. The chapter is divided into five major sections. The next section (7.2) introduces the contemporary debate on the (ir)relevance in economic governance. Here, we present some grossly oversimplified views on the nation-state championed by enthusiastic proponents of globalization known as ultra-globalists. In Section 7.3, we offer an explanation of the dependent relationships between THE STATE 189 states and firms and discuss different state functions that concern this state-firm relationship. This section explains the mechanisms through which the state manipulates the economy via its 'visible hand'. Section 7.4 further elaborates on the geographical diversity of nation-states in today's global economy. We show that state functions tend to work out differently in states dominated by contrasting political-economic ideologies in different places. In Section 7.5, we demonstrate how these state functions are changing in relation to the reconfiguration of state capacity at different geographical scales, while we then move to on problematize the state somewhat by considering how control over its geographical territory can in reality be limited and partial (Section 7.6). Throughout the analysis, we emphasize both state functions and their different manifestations in different places (i.e. their geographies). 7.2 The 'Globalization Excuse' and the End of the Nation-state? We begin by reviewing how the nation-state has become increasingly viewed as irrelevant in today's global economy. This is commonly known as the ultra-globalist position, particularly promoted through the popular accounts offered by business gurus such as Kenichi Ohmae (1995) and popular journalists such as Thomas Friedman (1999). The following quotation sums up this position nicely: What is new today is the degree and intensity with which the world is being tied together into a single globalized marketplace and village. What is also new is the sheer number of people and countries able to partake of today's globalized economy and information networks, and to be affected by them . . . This new era of globalization ... is turbocharged. (Friedman, 1999: xvii, xviii) In this view, globalization is not just a phenomenon to be reckoned with. More importantly, it is a force that integrates capita!, technology, and people in a 'borderless' world. Globalization, we are told, thus creates a single global market and a gigantic 'global village' that is neither stoppable nor controllable by individual nation-states. In outlining this new global system, these ultra-globalists have created a popular imagination for the end of the nation-state as institutions of political-economic governance (see also Section 2.5}. This explanation of the demise of the nation-state can be thought of as the 'globalization excuse*, i.e. explaining phenomena such as the reconfiguration of state functions by invoking an external factor known as globalization. Globalization becomes the convenient explanation for whatever happens to the 190 ACTORS IN ECONOMIC SPACE THE STATE 191 nation-state, not as something (e.g. a set of processes) that needs to be explained. Indeed, we can observe this line of explanation throughout the media, popular books, political speeches, and so on. Typically, this explanation is offered in the following manner: 'Because of globalization, we have to . . .'. These ultra-globalist stories often start with technological innovations in transport and communications that facilitate global flows of capital, people, information, and culture - all different aspects of globalization (see also Chapter 5). In the economic sphere, giant corporations and international financial institutions are claimed to be orchestrating global flows of capital and technology. This rise of corporate power and global finance has been presented as one major explanation for the demise of the nation-state. The global reach of these corporations and institutions has been described as 'effortless' and 'limitless': the world is their oyster. In some extreme cases, the annual sales of these large global corporations (e.g. Wal-Mart, General Motors, and Toyota) are compared with the annual production of national economies to demonstrate their corporate power. In this account, the nation-state is deemed powerless in its capacity to control its national economic affairs (e.g. inward investments) and its own corporations (e.g. outward investments). In deciding on whether to invest in a particular country, these global corporations often play one nation-state off against another in order to obtain maximum benefits such as political support, financial incentives, lax environmental regulation, and market access. The successful bargains achieved by these corporations in both advanced industrialized countries and poor developing countries has led to the universalistic claim by ultra-globalists that host nation-states are no longer able to effectively govern their economies. Meanwhile, the successful global reach of these corporations is seen to offer supporting evidence against the nation-state's relevance in domestic economic regulation. This occurs primarily when global corporations are capable of evading the regulatory and monitoring systems of particular countries of origin. While we have already introduced the grounded nature of technological change in Chapter 5 and will offer a more nuanced alternative to this uncritical view of the global reach of transnational corporations in Chapter 8, it is useful to point out here that such a view has widespread purchase in the political arena. Many politicians jump on this globalization 'bandwagon' in order to rationalize what is occurring within their territories. In this way, globalization becomes a 'scapegoat' used to explain the failure of economic policies or to justify policy interventions. 'Because of globalization' and 'there is no alternative (TINA)' explanations are commonly invoked today in the report cards of most governments and authorities throughout the world. By willingly acknowledging the inexorability of globalization, some political leaders are seemingly surrendering the various economic policy toolkits that they used to deploy so effectively to manage national economies. 7.3 Functions of the State (in Relation to the Economy): Long Live the State! Is the nation-state really withering away as these ultra-globalists allege? Not really. In this chapter, we argue for an alternative and more nuanced economic-geographical reading of the role of the nation-state in today's global economy. The state-firm nexus continues to produce all kinds of political-economic geographies, ranging from how certain regions and electorates receive favourable treatment because of intra-national politics, to how the national government intervenes to prevent 'encroachment' of foreign companies (e.g. the CNOOC example above). As shown in this and the next section, the nation-state performs a range of important functions in relation to the economy, though its capacity to execute these functions depends on the historical and geographical context of the state in question. More specifically, our broader theoretical rationale for the intertwined role of nation-states and politics in governing the modern economy can be understood in three ways. First, we reject the ultra-globalist position that polarizes the nation-state and the global firm. In particular, we note that both firms and markets are engaged with the nation-state in a mutually dependent relationship. Firms need the state to function in the five areas described in this section, while the state's political legitimacy will be challenged if it fails to deliver enough economic development and opportunities through the activities of firms and markets within its borders. Second, the ultra-globalist story depicting the nation-state as being the same everywhere is clearly a gross oversimplification of reality. Indeed, the nation-state comes in different shapes and sizes; there are many different varieties of nation-states (see next section) and they cannot all be described as 'powerless'. In arguing for this geographical diversity of nation-states, we bring into our account the highly uneven nature of the global political economy (see also Chapters 2 and 3). This recognition of geographical diversity is also important because it showcases different power relations within the global economy. While some nation-states may succumb to global forces and hence their stories can be seen to corroborate the claims of ultra-globalists, there are many other nation-states that consciously shape and fashion globalization processes to their own benefit. In fact, some nation-states have arguably been reshaping the global economy in their own image in recent decades (e.g. the US). Third, and perhaps most importantly, we subscribe to a more measured view of the nation-state that understands it as always remaking itself and undertaking necessary adjustments to new global realities. In this view, the nation-state does not exist as a static body of institutions and norms. On the contrary, it is a dynamic entity capable of self-transformation for the sake of political renewal and, sometimes, survival. We should not be misled by the ultra-globalist 192 ACTORS IN ECONOMIC SPACE THE STATE 193 position into seeing globalization as the dynamo reshaping the global economy and the nation-state as the passive victim. In the penultimate section (7.5), we shall consider in detail some of these reconfiguration processes of the nation-state. To begin our unpacking of the intermeshing of state politics and the modern economy, we need to understand some of the most fundamental issues in relation to state functions - how do nation-states interact with firms and markets? Here, we introduce the full range of economic functions performed by modern nation-states today and show how they can work out very differently in different places. We will emphasize their geographical concreteness rather than abstract characteristics. While the state is also expected to take care of many non-economic functions (e.g. national defence, foreign policy, cultural development, law and order, public health, and so on), we have identified five important state functions in managing the national economy: • ultimate guarantor and institution of last resort; • regulator of economic activities; • architect of the national economy; • owner of public enterprises; • provider of public goods and services. Ultimate guarantor Markets can fail miserably. It is in these situations that the state steps in, thus becoming an institution of last resort and the ultimate guarantor. While the market may appear to be self-organizing, it can fail in the wake of unforeseeable forces (e.g. financial crises and natural disasters). This is the most basic role for the state, and the one which is most recognized by neoclassical economics. We can think of four important aspects to this role: 1 Dealing with financial crises: market failure is particularly likely in the financial industry where bankruptcy of major financial institutions can result in severe financial crises in different national economies. Whereas some nation-states in advanced capitalist economies choose to leave these bankruptcies to the 'creative destruction' of the market mechanism, other states may decide to intervene in the market for political and social reasons. These latter states may seek to avert a banking crisis by offering financial backing to failed banks. For example, the Japanese government stepped in to assist the Long Term Credit Bank of Japan in October 1998 when the latter had collapsed under mounting non-performing loans. Such intervention can help to restore public confidence in the financial system, and stabilize the economy at large. 2 Guaranteeing national economic instruments: the international economic credibility of a nation-state in part depends on its ability to maintain the value of its currency and government bonds. For example, US Treasury Bills, a form of government-issued IOU (I Owe You), have strong credibility in the international financial community. Many institutional investors such as pension funds and insurance companies have purchased these Treasury Bills because of their attractive interest payments and the security of repayment upon maturity. In comparison, the bonds issued by many developing countries (e.g. Brazil and Argentina) may be subject to a lot more uncertainty and are therefore less attractive to potential investors. In terms of currencies, states ensure that their currency is the universal standard, or legal tender, accepted in their territory and try to maintain the relative value of that currency. The experiences of some South American countries during the early-to-mid 1990s (e.g. Argentina and Mexico) and some Asian economies in the late 1990s (e.g. Indonesia, Thailand and South Korea) are telling here. In both instances, the nation-states in question were unable to guarantee their national currency with sufficient foreign reserves or gold, resulting in massive depreciation and subsequent financial crises as people sought to rapidly sell reserves of the currency. 3 Securing international economic treaties: the nation-state is also important in that no other institutions (e.g. firms and markets) have the political legitimacy to conclude and sign international trade and investment agreements. Nation-states often engage in bilateral free trade agreements (FTAs) with one another in order to advance their common economic interests. By the end of 2005, there were close to 300 such FTAs either in the planning and negotiation stages, or concluded (http://www.wto.org, accessed 1 December 2005). Smaller states such as Singapore have deployed these FTAs highly effectively to expand their economic space and connectivity in the global economy. Nation-states also engage in bilateral investment guarantee pacts in order to protect the commercial interests of their national firms in foreign territories. 4 Property rights and the rule of the law: nation-states are also crucial in establishing and maintaining private property rights and upholding the rule of the law through a well-defined legal system. Property rights refer to the right of an individual or a corporate entity to own properties (e.g. land, building, machineries, ideas, designs, and so on) and derive income from these properties. This aspect of state functions defines the quintessential character of modern capitalism (see Chapter 3) because without effective property rights, capitalists (individuals or firms) cannot capture profits derived from their properties and therefore do not have any economic incentives to invest in these properties. A nation-state thus has numerous state departments to deal with property rights issues such as land titles, patents and trademarks, and business registries, and it also enacts many laws to protect these property rights. 194 ACTORS IN ECONOMIC SPACE THE STATE 195 Regulator States are also the primary regulators of the economic activities that take place within, and across, their borders. This aspect of state functions can be interpreted in different ways. For those of a pro-market persuasion, the nation-state should simply seek to enable and protect market-driven activities. And yet, the nation-state's primary source of legitimacy originates from its citizens. In turn, it is expected to protect its citizens from harmful or negative effects of the market and firm activities. The nation-state therefore often engages in a wide variety of forms of regulation of economic activities, ranging from economic and environmental to social and ethical considerations: • market regulation: the nation-state ensures the fairness of the market mechanism. The extent to which the state actively regulates market behaviour varies in different national economies. The US, for example, is particularly known for its strong preference for open market competition and anti-monopoly stance. For example, in twentieth-century America, many large corporate empires were broken down into smaller business units in order to prevent excessive market power held by these corporate giants, e.g. the dismantling of Rockefeller's Standard Oil into a few oil giants in 1911, including today's ExxonMobil and Chevron, and the former AT&T into many local 'baby' Bell companies in 1984. Many other nation-states have established fair trade commissions and anti-monopoly units in their departments of commerce to ensure market competition in different industries. This anti-monopoly approach to regulating the market economy can be contrasted with the experience of other nation-states that direct own and operate monopolies, mostly in developing countries. In these latter cases (see the next subsection), the state becomes a direct owner and manager of business enterprises, replacing the market as a primary mechanism of economic governance. • regulating economic flows: the contemporary nation-state plays a very important role in regulating its borders. This function is particularly important in an era of accelerated globalization associated with massive cross-border flows of capital, commodities, people, and information. In regulating capital flows, some states may be very restrictive and do not allow financial capital to enter and leave their countries easily without completing cumbersome regulatory procedures or paying hefty taxes. Border regulation is of particular importance in relation to labour flows. The border crossing point between China's Shenzhen and Hong Kong's Lo Wu shown in Figure 7.1 is the most heavily-used checkpoint between the two administrative systems in one country (China). Millions of people cross this border every year for work, leisure, and social visits. More importantly, however, only a fraction of these people from mainland China are allowed to migrate to Hong Kong on a permanent Figure 7.1 The border crossing between China's Shenzhen and Hong Kong's Lo Wu Source: Martin Hess, with permission. basis. As globalization has intensified, so levels of international migration of various kinds (e.g. short-term/permanent, high skill/low skill) have increased. Increasingly, destination countries (e.g. Canada or Australia) are seeking to regulate the kinds of migrants that they allow in, using points systems to assess the skills, qualifications and financial resources that potential migrants can bring into the economy. As another example, the accession of ten Eastern and Central European countries to the European Union in 2005 saw different initial responses from existing member states. While many countries negotiated that they would not have to allow migrants from these states for a set period, by contrast the UK, Ireland and Sweden immediately opened their borders to documented migrants in sectors where there were labour shortages (e.g. construction). Architect of the national economy In managing their national economies, most nation-states pursue a wide range of economic policies in order to sustain, shape and promote economic development. These economic policies may be linked to trade, investment, industry, and TRADE POLICIES Imports 1. Tariffs 2. Non-tariff barriers Import quotas Import licenses Import deposit schemes Import surcharges Rules of origin Anti-dumping measures Special labelling and packaging regulations Heallh and safety regulations Customs procedures and documentation requirements Subsidies to domestic producers of import-competing goods Countervailing duties on subsidized imports Local content requirements Government procurement preference for domestic producers Exchange rate manipulation_ Exports Financial and fiscal incentives to exporters Export credits and guarantees Setting of export targets State-sponsored overseas export promotion agencies Establishment of export processing zones and/or free trade areas Voluntary export restraints through export quotas Embargo on strategic exports Exchange rate manipulation_ FOREIGN DIRECT INVESTMENT POLICIES Inward FDI Government screening of investment proposals Sectoral restrictions or prohibitions Ownership restrictions Requirement for local personnel in managerial positions Compliance with national codes of business conduct Insistence on local content of production Insistence on minimum level of exports Technology transfer requirements Locational restrictions or preferences Restrictions on remittances of capital or profils abroad Level and methods of taxing profits Direct promotion of FDI through competitive bidding, overseas promotional agencies, and investment incentives _ Outward FDI Restrictions on capital export (e.g. exchange control regulation) Necessity for government approval Direct government ownership in outward FDI State-level FDI negotiations on behalf of national firms Direct promotion of outward FDI through overseas promotional agencies and investment incentives (e.g. taxation benefits) _ _ INDUSTRIAL POLICIES Promotional Investment incentives: capital- and tax-related Labour policies: subsidies and training State procurement policies Technology policies Small firm policies Policies to encourage industrial restructuring Policies to promote investment Regulatory Merger and competition policies Company legislation Taxation policies Labour market regulation: labour union and immigration policies National technical and product standards State ownership of production assets Environmental regulations Health and safety regulations_ Criteria affecting the selectivity of these policies 1. Particular sectors of industry To bolster declining industries To stimulate new industries To preserve key strategic industries 2. Particular types of firm To encourage entrepreneurship and new firm formation To attract foreign firms To help domestic firms against foreign competition To encourage firms in import-substituting or export activities 3. Particular geographical areas Economically depressed areas Areas of growth potential or new settlement_ Figure 7.2 Major types of economic policies pursued by nation-states Source: Adapted from Dicken (2003), Figures 5.4, 5.6 and 5.8. Reprinted by permission of Sage Publications. THE STATE 197 technology (Figure 7.2). In many cases, economic policies will also involve labour and finance. The most critical issue here is whether a particular nation-state pursues these economic policies in a strategic manner in order to seek or advance its national competitive advantage, If so, the relevant economic policies can be termed strategic economic policies: • strategic industrial policies: these policies stand out as the most significant dimension as the nation-state gets directly involved in nurturing and promoting certain industries (e.g. automobile and electronics) and firms. Sometimes, explicit trade and investment policies are combined to favour these industries and firms. » strategic trade policies: a strategic state will manage trade actively in order to protect the interests of its domestic producers. In addition to managing imports, nation-states often pursue strategic trade policies (e.g. export subsidies) to ensure their most favoured national firms - known as 'national champions' - are able to export globally and earn significant levels of foreign currency. • attracting foreign investment: the role of the state becomes even more visible in these policy interventions. As the competition for global investment steps up significantly during the 1990s and the twenty-first century, many nation-states are now pursuing economic policies that are highly favourable to foreign investors. For example, general tax incentives, the availability of prime land, training of the domestic workforce, and so on are often combined to form an attractive package to attract foreign investors. • regional development policies: in most countries, the nation-state actively pursues these policies to balance inherent inequality in the development of different regions (see also Chapter 3}. These regional development policies may range from direct grants and financial incentives offered to poorly developed regions to central policy interventions (e.g. training the labour force and favourable industrial policies to target specific regions). The above strategic economic policies often work out very differently in contrasting economies. For example, the US, widely known as the champion of free trade, does not necessarily apply the doctrine to its imports from around the world. As recently as 2003 and 2005, the US imposed punitive tariffs on imports of steel from Europe, Japan and many developing countries, and imports of textile and garments from China. The US justified these punitive tariffs on the basis of the 'strategic' importance of domestic producers in these sectors and the unfair 'cheap dumping' by exporting countries. By contrast, unlike the US' focus on regulating imports, the Asian newly industrializing economies (NIEs) explicitly engage in the strategic promotion of exports. For example, generous export subsidies and tax incentives have been offered to national champions such as Hyundai and Samsung from South Korea, and Acer 200 ACTORS IM ECONOMIC SPACE THE STATE 201 nation-states and national economies in today's global economy remains highly variegated, as we shall now move on to explain. 7.4 Types of states today While the last section outlined the key economic functions of modern nation-states in general, it is important for us to bear in mind die enormous range of state formations in the global economy. In recognizing the institutional and geographical diversity of nation-states, we are challenging the 'end of the nation-state' thesis championed by ultra-globalists. This recognition is highly important precisely because of the uneven nature of the global economy (see Chapter 3). The different historical-geographical circumstances from which each nation-state emerged have produced a variety of different states rather than a homogeneous group of similar states. As alluded to in Figures 7.3 and 7.4, two of the world's most powerful states today, the US and China, emerged from rather different historical-geographical contexts. The US obtained its democratic statehood from Great Britain after Thomas Jefferson's Declaration of Independence was adopted by a meeting of statesmen held on 4 July 1776 in the Independence Figure 7.3 Independence Hall, Philadelphia, the United States Source: The authors. Figure 7.4 The Forbidden City, Beijing, China Source: The authors. Hall in Philadelphia. The rise of the People's Republic of China (PRC) followed a bloody civil war and resulted in the inauguration of a drastically different communist political system at the Forbidden City in Beijing on 1 October 1949. Different states therefore engage in a wide range of power relations with firms, markets, and international organizations. Whereas some states are no doubt in control of their domestic economies through strict economic regulation, other states have delegated such economic control functions to private firms, markets, and international institutions. In other words, the kind of state in question is crucial in determining its capacity to control the economy and to resist and shape globalization processes. In this section, we review briefly six groups of nation-states in relation to their different political-economic governance and power relations: • neoliberal states in North America, Western Europe, and Australasia; • welfare states in Nordic countries and some European countries; • developmental states in Asia and South America; • transitional states in post-socialist countries in Eastern Europe, the former Soviet Union, China, and Southeast Asia (e.g. Vietnam, Cambodia, and Laos); THE STATE 203 o c o Q ft o Ö o « d o -c O -rt d OS M O cj) O TO .d ft 6 TO X W « t3 a y m & a a TO TO d u fi .d ° Tj h bo fi _ü bs o ft to ft -9 3 Pi B P P d < to1 ■S U o w> 2 3, S s g .5 ü s, s — 4j TO a. TO T3 to (_> -S -a a > ft o ft bO a 0 >- ts w D TO ■ß ^ ,H "SO bß .2 * d d TO d X! TO O d O o o u > S "2 o 5 s .a ft 03 Is d T3 d ft .3 v. to Ö "to d 3 •-' 3 K < 8 -o £ g (l> O 'B ^ 8 rt tu d (n o ß es cj d ft ni 2 @ a bp O m « 2 u ft o ft c d « oJ 3 ft -o Jl d ft o o d o ™ ö d ■B -o S 3 IS & * Ü -a bB « TO 2 a — tj o o to -Ö ft » -rl Ö S3 tS tn q a e O rj Ca d <*> O »J o « -a vd d M ni 3, H u ft ~ d 8 e o d TO O ft (lj ft _ o > 13 ^ 5 ft d o d o -d 6 TO u 'S T3 g d d £ p § .a •0 52 ft ft {J ■ o 4-" t3 ^ -R P TO O TO o s ft ^ bp © " " p .2 TS J3 0 U a TO tj 1> d o |1 TO Q, ^ O r/i i-^ d o "> K Sog o -a : bJD - O d P a, m T3 O S r-H WJ (U O O c!J h d ^ «> « o « a bo cq O .9 TO rd 3 t3 O T3 £ % 2 TD ■a